ChineseEconomicReform under Communist Rule Two years after the
death of Mao Zedong in 1976, it became apparent to many of China's
leaders that economicreform was necessary. During his tenure as
China's premier, Mao had encouraged social movements such as the
Great Leap Forward and the Cultural Revolution which had had as their
bases ideologies such as serving the people and maintaining the class
struggle. By 1978 "Chinese leaders were searching for a solution to
serious economic problems produced by Hua Guofeng, the man who had
succeeded Mao Zedong as CCP leader after Mao's death" (Shirk 35).
Hua had demonstrated a desire to continue the ideologically based
movements of Mao. Unfortunately, these movements had left China in a
state where "agriculture was stagnant, industrial production was low, and
the people's living standards had not increased in twenty years" (Nathan
200). This last area was particularly troubling. While "the gross output
value of industry and agriculture increased by 810 percent and national
income grew by 420 percent [between 1952 and 1980] average
individual income increased by only 100 percent" (Ma Hong quoted in
Shirk 28). However, attempts at economicreform in China were
introduced not only due to some kind of generosity on the part of the
Chinese Communist Party to increase the populace's living standards. It
had become clear to members of the CCP that economicreform would
fulfill a political purpose as well since the party felt, properly it would
seem, that it had suffered a loss of support. As Susan L. Shirk describes
the situation in The Political Logic of EconomicReform in China, restoring
the CCP's prestige required improving economic performance and raising
living standards. The traumatic experience of the Cultural Revolution had
eroded popular trust in the moral and political virtue of the CCP. The
party's leaders decided to shift the base of party legitimacy from virtue to
competence, and to do that they had to demonstrate that they could
deliver the goods. (23) This movement "from virtue to competence"
seemed to mark a serious departure from orthodox Chinese political
theory. Confucius himself had posited in the fifth century BCE that those
individuals who best demonstrated what he referred to as moral force
should lead the nation. Using this principle as a guide, China had for
centuries attempted to choose at least its bureaucratic leaders by
administering a test to determine their moral force. After the Communist
takeover of the country, Mao continued this emphasis on moral force by
demanding that Chinese citizens demonstrate what he referred to as
"correct consciousness." This correct consciousness could be exhibited,
Mao believed, by the way people lived. Needless to say, that which
constituted correct consciousness was often determined and assessed by
Mao. Nevertheless, the ideal of moral force was still a potent one in China
even after the Communist takeover. It is noteworthy that Shirk feels that
the Chinese Communist Party leaders saw economicreform as a way to
regain their and their party's moral virtue even after Mao's death. Thus,
paradoxically, by demonstrating their expertise in a more practical area of
competence, the leaders of the CCP felt they could demonstrate how
they were serving the people. To be sure, the move toward economic
reform came about as a result of a "changed domestic and international
environment, which altered the leadership's perception of the factors that
affect China's national security and social stability" (Xu 247). But Shirk
feels that, in those pre-Tienenmen days, such a move came about also
as a result of an attempt by CCP leaders to demonstrate, in a more
practical and thus less obviously ideological manner than Mao had done,
their moral force. This is not to say that the idea of economicreform was
embraced enthusiastically by all members of the leadership of the
Chinese Communist Party in 1978. To a great extent, the issue of
economic reform became politicized as the issue was used as a means
by Deng Xiaoping to attain the leadership of the Chinese Communist
Party. Mao's successor, Hua Guofeng, had "tried to prove himself a
worthy successor to Mao by draping himself in the mantle of Maoist
tradition. His approach to economic development was orthodox Maoism
with an up-to-date, international twist" (Shirk 35). This approach was tied
heavily to the development of China's oil reserves. "[W]hen [in 1978]
estimates of the oil reserves were revised downward[,] commitments to
import plants and expand heavy industry could not be sustained" (Shirk
35). Deng took advantage of this economic crisis to discredit Hua and aim
for leadership of the party. "Reform policies became Deng's platform
against Hua for post-Mao leadership" (Shirk 36). Given this history of
economic reform, it is evident that "under the present system economic
questions are necessarily political questions" (Dorn 43). Once Deng and
his faction had prevailed, it was necessary for some sort of economic
reform to evolve. The initial form the new economy took was not a radical
one. China was "still a state in which the central government retain[ed]
the dominant power in economic resource allocation and responsible
local officials work[ed] for the interest of the units under their control"
(Solinger 103). However, as time passed, some basic aspects of the old
system were altered either by design or via the process of what might be
called benign neglect. As Shirk points out, in rural areas,
decollectivization was occurring: "decision making power [was being
transferred] from collective production units (communes, brigades, and
teams) to the family" (38); purchase prices for major farm products were
increased (39). In 1985, further reforms were introduced. For example,
long-term sales contracts between farmers and the government were
established. In addition, in an effort to allow the market to determine
prices, "city prices of fruit and vegetables, fish, meat, and eggs, were
freed from government controls so they could respond to market
demand" (Shirk 39). Most importantly, "a surge of private and collective
industry and commerce in the countryside" (Shirk 39) occurred. This
allowed a great percentage of the populace to become involved in private
enterprise and investment in family or group ventures. The conditions
also allowed rural Chinese to leave the villages and become involved in
industry in urban centers (Shirk 40). The economy grew so quickly that
inflation occurred and the government had to reinstitute price controls.
China's economy retains these characteristics of potential for growth-and
inflation-to this day. Another important aspect of Chinese economic
reform was the decision of China to join the world economy. Deng
Xiaoping and his allies hoped to effect this 1979 resolution in two ways:
by expanding foreign trade, and by encouraging foreign companies to
invest in Chinese enterprises. This policy-denoted the "Open Policy"
(Shirk 47) was a drastic removal from the policies of Mao Zedong and, in
fact, from centuries of Chinese political culture. The Open Policy, which
designated limited areas in China "as places with preferential conditions
for foreign investment and bases for the development of exports" (Nathan
99), was extremely successful in the areas where it was implemented
(Shirk 47). However, it was looked upon by many Chinese as nothing less
than an avenue to "economic dependency" (Nathan 50). Indeed, when
the policy was first implemented, many Chinese seem[ed] to fear that
Deng's policies [were] drawing China back toward its former semi-colonial
status as a "market where the imperialist countries dump their goods, a
raw material base, a repair and assembly workshop, and an investment
center." (Nathan 51) It is interesting to note the symptoms of a national
character that would subscribe to the above sentiment. In an article
written in 1981, just two years after the Open Policy was first proposed,
Andrew J. Nathan noted the almost pathological resistance to foreign
intervention in the Chinese economy: "Some Chinese fear that reliance
on imported technology will encourage a dependent psychology [Many]
Chinese perceive joint ventures as a costly form of acquisition. 'Some
people worry: Won't we be suffering losses by letting foreigners make
profits in our country?'" (52). The Chinese were as vociferous about
issues of sovereignty. Nathan maintained that the Mao-led revolution,
which culminated in victory in 1949, had been fueled by "an intense
patriotism: once China had 'stood up,' no infringement on its
sovereignty, no matter how small, should be permitted" (53). These
feelings were manifested in denying foreign businessmen long-term,
multiple entry visas, resisting "increased foreign economic contacts" and
alteration of current ways of doing things, and disinclination to become
involved in government-to-government loans and joint ventures lest
Chinese become exploited in some way (Nathan 53-55). Given these
hesitancies on the part of the Chinese society vis-a-vis foreign relations, it
is impressive that Deng and his allies were able initially to create and
implement the Open Policy since many members of the society at large
were resistant to becoming involved in a policy so antithetical to the
Chinese national character. However, once the successes of the Open
Policy were apparent, resistance to the plan by the populace waned.
Moreover, given the confluence of politics and economics in China, it
seems apparent that some members of the CCP would also not be in
favor of the plan. Nevertheless, the Open Policy was implemented and
has become instrumental in the success of the burgeoning Chinese
economy. The implementation of the Open Policy was so successful that
by 1988 the leaders of the CCP were encouraged to create a new
program called the "coastal development strategy." In this program, even
more of the country was opened up to foreign investment-an area which,
at the time, included nearly 200 million people. Moreover, by involving
more overseas investors, "importing both capital and raw materials," and
"exporting China's cheap excess labor power," the new policy was one of
"'export-led growth' or 'export-oriented industrialization.' It [was] explicitly
modeled on the experiences of Taiwan and the other Asian 'small
dragons'" (Nathan 99). One analyst has maintained that "China now
stands at the threshold of the greatest opportunity in human history: a
new economic era promising greater wealth and achievement than any
previous epoch" (Gilder 369). Illustrative of this optimistic feeling is
Shanghai, an area that was designated for preferential conditions for
foreign investment and as a base for the development of exports in 1988.
This city and environs in the Yangtze Delta area have a population of
approximately 400 million people and the city has become the nation's
financial hub for international and national investors. For political reasons,
this area was excluded from the original Open Policy designation in 1978,
but is currently in the process of catching up with other areas so
designated. Indeed, the increase in foreign investments in the last two
years is striking. The area received 3.3 billion dollars in foreign
investments during the 1980s. The area received the same amount from
foreign investments in 1992 alone. In only the first ten months of 1993,
the area had received over six billion dollars worth of foreign investments
(Tyler A8). Western analysts have asserted that the Open Policy and the
coastal development strategy have allowed Deng to entrench his political
power (Shirk 47) and will allow his power to be sustained even after
death. If this is true, Deng should be very popular in Shanghai. With its
new designation, and with the billions of foreign dollars coming into the
area, it has become necessary to improve the city's facilities. To that end
forty billion dollars worth of public works projects have been allocated by
the central government for Shanghai within the last year (Tyler A1).
These public works projects include new sewers, a new water system,
new gas lines, a new bridge, and extensive roadwork. Future plans
include the construction of a second international airport, a container port,
a new subway system, and more roads and bridges (Tyler A8). The
financial district, which will feature a new stock exchange, is also being
rebuilt by China and foreign investors in a joint venture. By being
designated for preferential conditions, Shanghai received from the central
government tax exemptions for enterprises doing business with foreign
companies, tax holidays for new factories set up with foreign investments,
and a bonded zone-the largest in China-for duty free imports of raw
materials. Shanghai now has all the trappings of a modern city: discos,
construction projects, and conspicuous consumption. In short, where
"revered monuments and golden arches exist side by side" (Riboud 12),
the appearance of the new Shanghai does nothing less than signal "the
end of the ideological debate over China's free market experiments"
(Tyler A8). Shanghai has joined the ranks of the modern metropolis.
However, this is not necessarily a beneficial development. Inflation is
rampant: prices have doubled in the industrial zones in the last five years.
Nevertheless, the fact that Shanghai currently possesses the fifth most
expensive office space in the world demonstrates that demand is high
and that the prospects for future growth are promising (Tyler A8). Indeed,
Pudong, a free export manufacturing zone described as "the future sight
of Shanghai's Manhattan" (Tyler A8), boasts more than twenty factories
built or being built with names like Siemens and Hitachi prominent. This
area has become particularly attractive to foreign investors and
companies because of its tax concessions, duty free imports of raw
materials, and cheap labor. Shanghai stands to benefit, too, as it receives
ancillary technology and discretionary spending from the workers and
executives of the companies represented (Tyler A8). It is conditions like
these that have caused at least one analyst to predict that China will be
"the richest economy in the world within the next 25 years" (Gilder 372).
Shanghai is by no means unique to this growth. Additional foreign
investments have continued to pour into other areas of China. For
example, the Boeing Company recently announced its intention to "invest
$100 million in a plant in [Xian] China to make tail sections for 737
jetliners" ("Boeing" D4). In addition, E.I. du Pont recently predicted "that
its investments and business in China could increase as much as ten
times by the end of the century" ("Du Pont" D2). Tellingly, du Pont's
chairman attributed the company's negotiations of "as many as 28 new
projects in China" to the fact "that the country's financial changes,
improved infrastructure and rising disposable income has [sic]
encouraged the company to expand its business activities" ("Du Pont"
D2). The Chinese government has made conscientious attempts to
promote the strength of the country's economy while protecting its
citizens. Just a few weeks ago, the government instituted "tight-money
policies, intended to control inflation and slow what has been the world's
fastest growing major economy" (Shenon "China Halts" D1). However,
after doing so, China's Securities Regulatory Commission was forced to
stop the issuing of new issues on the Shanghai and Shenzhen Stock
Exchanges because the value of the markets had decreased so greatly.
This latter move was "meant to calm millions of first-time Chinese
investors who evidently went into the market believing that stock prices
could only go up" (Shenon "China Halts" D1). Might this policy show a
union of economic and moral concern? If so, it demonstrates the desire
on the part of the government to show some kind of responsibility, some
moral force, to its citizenry. At the very least, the strategy appears to
show a practical desire on the part of the government to take control over
what could have been a bad economic situation. Indeed, after these
measures were instituted, China's trade deficit decreased (Hansell D2)
and the stock markets' volume attained record highs ("Stocks Surge" D2).
To be sure, Chinese investors remain somewhat wary about the stock
market and, ironically enough, more control of the stock markets appears
to be necessary (Shenon "A Nail-Biting" D1). But, in discussing Chinese
attempts to control inflation, Philip J. Suttle, head of emerging markets
research at the investment firm of J.P. Morgan, has predicted that "[i]t
looks as though the Chinese are going to have the soft landing they are
aiming for" (quoted in Hansell D2). China's interest in stock markets is no
longer restricted to within its own boundaries. This month, Shandong
Huaneng Power Development Company, "the first mainland Chinese
company to have its primary listing on the New York Stock Exchange"
("China Stock" D5), began trading shares. The stock should be an
attractive one to investors: Chinese electrical "demand is expected to
grow by a whopping 17 million kilowatts a year until the turn of the
century" (Zuckerman D6). Moreover, China stands to gain from the
issue's sales. "The company plans to use the $311 million dollars it
received from the offering to retire $83 million in loans from Chinese
state entities. It also plans to expand its overall generating capacity"
(Zuckerman D6). Nor does this signify the only Chinese attempt of raising
capital from foreign sources on foreign soil. "Three more power
companies are expected to be listed in New York and Hong Kong in the
coming months" (Zuckerman D6). Given the apparent strength of the
Chinese economy as shown by huge public works projects, extensive
foreign investments, participation in the world economy, and a generally
higher standard of living by the populace, it would appear that China is
now ready to join the world as a modern capitalistic and democratic
society. However, this is not quite the case. The CCP retains vestiges of
those characteristics of insularity and intransigence as discussed by
Nathan. Because of its human rights record, the country's economic
growth is being impeded. That is, the politics of China, which have always
been allied with its economics, are now restricting international growth.
The United States, especially, has been concerned with China's
treatment of political dissidents. In May, President Clinton decided to end
linking China's trade status with the United States with its record on
human rights. The president has been criticized for this because of
situations like the following: trials for "'counterrevolutionary activities'
[including] plans to use a remote-controlled airplane to drop
pro-democracy leaflets over Tienenmen Square" ("China cracks" A13)
have recently begun for fifteen dissidents and labor organizers who were
involved in the Tienenmen Square protests. These trials have "been
delayed twice, first to avoid negative international reaction just before the
decision last September on China's failed bid to host the 2000 Olympics
and then this spring to avoid influencing Clinton's trade decision" ("China
cracks" A13). In addition, China has instituted "new laws effective in June
[which] give sweeping powers to China's State Security Bureau to clamp
down on dissidents" ("China cracks" A13). China is fully aware of United
States' concerns about its human rights record. Given the fact that the
United States has made it clear to China that that record will be allied with
trade status, China's timing of such restrictive activities has caused
United States legislators and administrators to question China's sincerity
in its desire to have a favored trade status with the United States. Indeed,
just in the past few days, it took a last-minute lobbying campaign by
President Clinton and his Cabinet [to head off a] potentially embarrassing
vote by the House of Representatives to restrict trade with China as a
way to punish Beijing for reported human rights violations. (Bradsher A7)
But China's problems in joining the community of the world market have
more to do than with its political ethos and practices. China appears not
to understand or to be able to follow through on fundamental modern
economic practices. For example, the United States has recently
complained that "China has not complied with international rules on
access to its markets and protection of copyrights and patents" (Gargan
14). Such non-compliance could make it difficult for China to become a
founding member of the World Trade Organization, the successor to the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and the body that is intended to
promote global free trade by lowering tariffs and other barriers, [which]
will be formally constituted on January 1, 1994. (Gargan 14) The specific
nature of the United States' complaint has to do with China's pirating of
musical compact disks, video laser disks and computer software. In fact,
it is estimated that such pirating costs American companies a billion
dollars a year. This phenomenon seems to have to do with the Chinese
psychology as described by Nathan. In his 1981 essay he noted that
China did not wish to become a "technological client of the west. The
preferred solution is to buy one item and copy it" (Nathan 52). Clearly,
this is not the way trade works today. It is the United States' position that
China must adhere to the rules of trade before it can be included in a
trade organization. Needless to say, exclusion from WTO would be
disastrous for any country, but particularly for an emerging market such
as China. Even on a day to day basis, China's economic leaders seem
unable to understand how some aspects of a market economy work. In
discussing the status of the Shanghai Stock Market, for example, one
stock dealer referred to it as "crazy" ("Stocks Surge" D2). Moreover,
American analysts have been amazed to discover in the Shanghai market
"the lack of regulation and the poor disclosure requirements. Some
companies have been listed for two or three years and have not issued
an annual report" (Hansell D2). It is no wonder that Chinese investors
become anxious about their investments. The issuance of shares in the
Shandong Huaneng Power Development Company also demonstrates
the lack of expertise on the part of the Chinese in the modern world
market. In fact, according to one Hong Kong investment analyst, "'[t]he
company wasn't really a company. It was just a bunch of discrete plants
that they tied a bow around and wrote a prospectus on'" (Zuckerman D6).
The prospectus guaranteed a fifteen percent annual return on
investments. In fact, the return will no doubt be less than that because of
prevailing currency exchange rates and debt that the company will have
to assume. To be sure, the problems of the Shandong Huaneng Power
Development Company and the Shanghai Stock Exchange may
demonstrate only the problems of an immature economy. Nevertheless, if
China wishes to become a viable member of the world economic
community, such shortcomings will have to be eliminated quickly. These
apparent problems may also be the result of an economic system that is
run by the state. Certainly, one thing that the CCP has attempted to do is
create a market economy while retaining a state controlled system. This
structure may be possible but it does have its critics. Steven N.S.
Cheung, in an essay written in 1989, argued for the "creation of private
property by mandate" (31), feeling that privatization in China would lead
to necessary additional investment in the society's infrastructure and the
establishment of a "judicial system that is based firmly on the principle of
equality before the law" (Cheung 32). Echoing Cheung's sentiments,
James Dorn saw problems in the areas of Chinese banking and finance.
In this arrangement, Dorn argued, "the state controls the bulk of
investment resources. The lack of a private capital market has
handicapped economic development in China and hampered rational
investment decisionmaking" (43). In order to become a modern economic
state Dorn argued for the necessity of circumventing "China's ruling elite
who oppose the dismantling of state monopolies and who benefit from
price fixing and nonprice rationing" (51). Xu Zhiming also saw the
necessity for a revamping of the Chinese system: "We must throw off the
traditional system completely" (249) in order for economicreform to
thrive. Communist Party members, of course, articulate a different
position. In a recent interview that appeared in the Beijing Review, Feng
Bing, Deputy Secretary General of the State Commission for
Restructuring the Economic System, spoke to the issue of economic
reform in China. It is striking that Feng spoke of the benefits that the
populace has received as a result of the economicreform now occurring
in China. That is, his comments appeared to demonstrate the
beneficence, or the moral force, of the Chinese Communist Party
vis-a-vis economic reform. He noted that such reform involves the
essence of socialism: "to liberate and develop productive forces; to
eradicate exploitation; to remove polarization; and to attain the goal of
common prosperity" ("Official" 12). Thus, CCP leaders still appear to see
their roles as representatives of a moral force. CCP members and
leaders wish economicreform not to be judged on just its practical merits,
but also as an effect of the moral force of the leadership. Economic
reform, then, becomes nothing less than a moral crusade and it is thus
easy to see why, for example, China "has staked its national prestige on
becoming a founding member of the World Trade Organization" (Gargan
14). Will China succeed in taking its place among the nations of the world
market? Will the CCP succeed in retaining its political power given the
drastic changes in the societal makeup of China that are occurring due to
the changing economic realities? I would suggest that the chances are
better for the former than for the latter. Once the Chinese attain more
sophistication relative to international and national markets, institute a
more manageable banking system, and make a good faith effort to insure
acceptable human rights, the country may well become "the richest
economy in the world within the next 25 years" (Gilder 372). However,
whether or not these conditions can occur without a weakening of the
state controlled system is problematic. The most impressive and
far-reaching display of moral force by the CCP may well have to be a
voluntary reduction of its power over the people. Paradoxically, by
weakening itself politically, the party may demonstrate its true moral force
by liberating, politically and economically, one billion Chinese
citizens.WORKS CITED"Boeing Planning to Invest $100 Million for China
Plant."New York Times: 9 August 1994, D4.Bradsher, Keith. "Bill to
Restrict China's Imports Loses inHouse." New York Times: 10 August
1994, A7.Cheung, Steven N.S. "Privatization vs. Special Interests:The
Experience of China's Economic Reforms."Economic Reform in China:
Problems and Prospects. Ed. James A. Dorn and Wang Xi. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1990. 21-32."China cracks down on dissent
after trade threat lifted,report says." Hartford Courant: 29 July 1994,
A13."China Stock Is Most Active." New York Times: 5 August1994,
D5.Dorn, James A. "Pricing and Property: The ChinesePuzzle." Economic
Reform in China: Problems and Prospects. Ed. James A. Dorn and Wang
Xi. Chicago:University of Chicago Press, 1990. 39-61."Du Pont Plans
Increase In Chinese Investment." New YorkTimes: 10 August 1994,
D2.Gargan, Edward A. "U.S. May Thwart China's Trade Goal."New York
Times: 24 July 1994, 14.Gilder, George. "Let a Billion Flowers Bloom."
Economic Reformin China: Problems and Prospects. Ed. JamesA. Dorn
and Wang Xi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990.
369-374.Hansell, Saul. "Chinese Stock Markets Bounce Back,
Rising30%." New York Times: 2 August 1994, D2.Nathan, Andrew J.
China's Crisis. New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press, 1990."Official on
Economic Reform." Beijing Review: 27 June-3 July 1994, 11-15.Riboud,
Marc. "China Leaps Upward." New York Times Magazine: 27 December
1992, 12-15.Shenon, Philip. "A Nail-Biting Ride in Shanghai." NewYork
Times: 6 August 1994, 33, 41.Shenon, Philip. "China Halts Listing of New
Stock." NewYork Times: 1 August 1994, D1, D4.Shirk, Susan L. The
Political Logic of EconomicReform in China.Berkeley: University of
California Press,1993.Solinger, Dorothy J. China's Transition from
Socialism:Statist Legacies and Market Reforms, 1980-1990.Armonk, NY:
M. E. Sharpe, 1993. "Stocks Surge in China As Volume Sets Record."
New YorkTimes: 9 August 1994, D2.Tyler, Patrick E. "Economic Focus in
Shanghai: CatchingUp." New York Times: 22 December 1993, A1, A8.Xu,
Zhiming. "The Impact of China's Reform andDevelopment on the Outside
World." EconomicReform in China: Problems and Prospects. Ed. James
A. Dorn and Wang Xi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990.
247-253.Zuckerman, Laurence. "A Foreign Offering's UnsurePedigree."
New York Times: 11 August 1994, D6.
. Chinese Economic Reform under Communist Rule Two years after the
death of Mao Zedong in 1976, it became apparent to many of China's
leaders that economic. and
leaders wish economic reform not to be judged on just its practical merits,
but also as an effect of the moral force of the leadership. Economic
reform, then,