Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 13 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
13
Dung lượng
56,98 KB
Nội dung
ChineseEconomicReformunderCommunist Rule
Two years after the death of Mao Zedong in 1976, it became
apparent to many of
China's leaders that economicreform was necessary. During his
tenure as China's
premier, Mao had encouraged social movements such as the Great
Leap Forward and
the Cultural Revolution which had had as their bases ideologies
such as serving
the people and maintaining the class struggle. By 1978 "Chinese
leaders were
searching for a solution to serious economic problems produced by
Hua Guofeng,
the man who had succeeded Mao Zedong as CCP leader after Mao's
death" (Shirk 35).
Hua had demonstrated a desire to continue the ideologically based
movements of
Mao. Unfortunately, these movements had left China in a state
where "agriculture
was stagnant, industrial production was low, and the people's
living standards
had not increased in twenty years" (Nathan 200). This last area
was particularly
troubling. While "the gross output value of industry and
agriculture increased
by 810 percent and national income grew by 420 percent
[between1952 and 1980]
average individual income increased by only 100 percent" (Ma Hong
quoted in
Shirk 28). However, attempts at economicreform in China were
introduced not
only due to some kind of generosity on the part of the Chinese
Communist Party
to increase the populace's living standards. It had become clear
to members of
the CCP that economicreform would fulfill a political purpose as
well since the
party felt, properly it would seem, that it had suffered a loss
of support. As
Susan L. Shirk describes the situation in The Political Logic of
Economic Reform
in China, restoring the CCP's prestige required improving
economic performance
and raising living standards. The traumatic experience of the
Cultural
Revolution had eroded popular trust in the moral and political
virtue of the CCP.
The party's leaders decided to shift the base of party legitimacy
from virtue to
competence, and to do that they had to demonstrate that they
could deliver the
goods. (23) This movement "from virtue to competence" seemed to
mark a serious
departure from orthodox Chinese political theory. Confucius
himself had posited
in the fifth century BCE that those individuals who best
demonstrated what he
referred to as moral force should lead the nation. Using this
principle as a
guide, China had for centuries attempted to choose at least its
bureaucratic
leaders by administering a test to determine their moral force.
After the
Communist takeover of the country, Mao continued this emphasis on
moral force by
demanding that Chinese citizens demonstrate what he referred to
as "correct
consciousness." This correct consciousness could be exhibited,
Mao believed, by
the way people lived. Needless to say, that which constituted
correct
consciousness was often determined and assessed by Mao.
Nevertheless, the ideal
of moral force was still a potent one in China even after the
Communist takeover.
It is noteworthy that Shirk feels that the Chinese Communist
Party leaders saw
economic reform as a way to regain their and their party's moral
virtue even
after Mao's death. Thus, paradoxically, by demonstrating their
expertise in a
more practical area of competence, the leaders of the CCP felt
they could
demonstrate how they were serving the people. To be sure, the
move toward
economic reform came about as a result of a "changed domestic and
international
environment, which altered the leadership's perception of the
factors that
affect China's national security and social stability" (Xu 247).
But Shirk feels
that, in those pre-Tienenmen days, such a move came about also as
a result of an
attempt by CCP leaders to demonstrate, in a more practical and
thus less
obviously ideological manner than Mao had done, their moral
force. This is not
to say that the idea of economicreform was embraced
enthusiastically by all
members of the leadership of the ChineseCommunist Party in 1978.
To a great
extent, the issue of economicreform became politicized as the
issue was used as
a means by Deng Xiaoping to attain the leadership of the Chinese
Communist Party.
Mao's successor, Hua Guofeng, had "tried to prove himself a
worthy successor to
Mao by draping himself in the mantle of Maoist tradition. His
approach to
economic development was orthodox Maoism with an up-to-date,
international
twist" (Shirk 35). This approach was tied heavily to the
development of China's
oil reserves. "[W]hen [in 1978] estimates of the oil reserves
were revised
downward[,] commitments to import plants and expand heavy
industry could not be
sustained" (Shirk 35). Deng took advantage of this economic
crisis to discredit
Hua and aim for leadership of the party. "Reform policies became
Deng's platform
against Hua for post-Mao leadership" (Shirk 36). Given this
history of economic
reform, it is evident that "under the present system economic
questions are
necessarily political questions" (Dorn 43). Once Deng and his
faction had
prevailed, it was necessary for some sort of economicreform to
evolve. The
initial form the new economy took was not a radical one. China
was "still a
state in which the central government retain[ed] the dominant
power in economic
resource allocation and responsible local officials work[ed] for
the interest of
the units under their control" (Solinger 103). However, as time
passed, some
basic aspects of the old system were altered either by design or
via the process
of what might be called benign neglect. As Shirk points out, in
rural areas,
decollectivization was occurring: "decision making power [was
being transferred]
from collective production units (communes, brigades, and teams)
to the family"
(38); purchase prices for major farm products were increased
(39). In 1985,
further reforms were introduced. For example, long-term sales
contracts between
farmers and the government were established. In addition, in an
effort to allow
the market to determine prices, "city prices of fruit and
vegetables, fish, meat,
and eggs, were freed from government controls so they could
respond to market
demand" (Shirk 39). Most importantly, "a surge of private and
collective
industry and commerce in the countryside" (Shirk 39) occurred.
This allowed a
great percentage of the populace to become involved in private
enterprise and
investment in family or group ventures. The conditions also
allowed rural
Chinese to leave the villages and become involved in industry in
urban centers
(Shirk 40). The economy grew so quickly that inflation occurred
and the
government had to reinstitute price controls. China's economy
retains these
characteristics of potential for growth—and inflation—to this
day. Another
important aspect of Chineseeconomicreform was the decision of
China to join
the world economy. Deng Xiaoping and his allies hoped to effect
this 1979
resolution in two ways: by expanding foreign trade, and by
encouraging foreign
companies to invest in Chinese enterprises. This policy—denoted
the "Open
Policy" (Shirk 47) was a drastic removal from the policies of
Mao Zedong and,
in fact, from centuries of Chinese political culture. The Open
Policy, which
designated limited areas in China "as places with preferential
conditions for
foreign investment and bases for the development of exports"
(Nathan 99), was
extremely successful in the areas where it was implemented (Shirk
47). However,
it was looked upon by many Chinese as nothing less than an avenue
to "economic
dependency" (Nathan 50). Indeed, when the policy was first
implemented, many
Chinese seem[ed] to fear that Deng's policies [were] drawing
China back toward
its former semi-colonial status as a "market where the
imperialist countries
dump their goods, a raw material base, a repair and assembly
workshop, and an
investment center." (Nathan 51) It is interesting to note the
symptoms of a
national character that would subscribe to the above sentiment.
In an article
written in 1981, just two years after the Open Policy was first
proposed, Andrew
J. Nathan noted the almost pathological resistance to foreign
intervention in
the Chinese economy: "Some Chinese fear that reliance on imported
technology
will encourage a dependent psychology [Many] Chinese perceive
joint ventures
as a costly form of acquisition. 'Some people worry: Won't we be
suffering
losses by letting foreigners make profits in our country?'" (52).
The Chinese
were as vociferous about issues of sovereignty. Nathan maintained
that the Mao-
led revolution, which culminated in victory in 1949, had been
fueled by "an
intense patriotism: once China had 'stood up,' no
infringement on its
sovereignty, no matter how small, should be permitted" (53).
These feelings were
manifested in denying foreign businessmen long-term, multiple
entry visas,
resisting "increased foreign economic contacts" and alteration of
current ways
of doing things, and disinclination to become involved in
government-to-
government loans and joint ventures lest Chinese become exploited
in some way
(Nathan 53-55). Given these hesitancies on the part of the
Chinese society vis-
a-vis foreign relations, it is impressive that Deng and his
allies were able
initially to create and implement the Open Policy since many
members of the
society at large were resistant to becoming involved in a policy
so antithetical
to the Chinese national character. However, once the successes of
the Open
Policy were apparent, resistance to the plan by the populace
waned. Moreover,
given the confluence of politics and economics in China, it seems
apparent that
some members of the CCP would also not be in favor of the plan.
Nevertheless,
the Open Policy was implemented and has become instrumental in
the success of
the burgeoning Chinese economy. The implementation of the Open
Policy was so
successful that by 1988 the leaders of the CCP were encouraged to
create a new
program called the "coastal development strategy." In this
program, even more of
the country was opened up to foreign investment—an area which, at
the time,
included nearly 200 million people. Moreover, by involving more
overseas
investors, "importing both capital and raw materials," and
"exporting China's
cheap excess labor power," the new policy was one of "'export-led
growth' or
'export-oriented industrialization.' It [was] explicitly modeled
on the
experiences of Taiwan and the other Asian 'small dragons'"
(Nathan 99). One
analyst has maintained that "China now stands at the threshold of
the greatest
opportunity in human history: a new economic era promising
greater wealth and
achievement than any previous epoch" (Gilder 369). Illustrative
of this
optimistic feeling is Shanghai, an area that was designated for
preferential
conditions for foreign investment and as a base for the
development of exports
in 1988. This city and environs in the Yangtze Delta area have a
population of
approximately 400 million people and the city has become the
nation's financial
hub for international and national investors. For political
reasons, this area
was excluded from the original Open Policy designation in 1978,
but is currently
in the process of catching up with other areas so designated.
Indeed, the
increase in foreign investments in the last two years is
striking. The area
received 3.3 billion dollars in foreign investments during the
1980s. The area
received the same amount from foreign investments in 1992 alone.
In only the
first ten months of 1993, the area had received over six billion
dollars worth
of foreign investments (Tyler A8). Western analysts have asserted
that the Open
Policy and the coastal development strategy have allowed Deng to
entrench his
political power (Shirk 47) and will allow his power to be
sustained even after
death. If this is true, Deng should be very popular in Shanghai.
With its new
designation, and with the billions of foreign dollars coming into
the area, it
has become necessary to improve the city's facilities. To that
end forty billion
dollars worth of public works projects have been allocated by the
central
government for Shanghai within the last year (Tyler A1). These
public works
projects include new sewers, a new water system, new gas lines, a
new bridge,
and extensive roadwork. Future plans include the construction of
a second
international airport, a container port, a new subway system, and
more roads and
bridges (Tyler A8). The financial district, which will feature a
new stock
exchange, is also being rebuilt by China and foreign investors in
a joint
venture. By being designated for preferential conditions,
Shanghai received from
the central government tax exemptions for enterprises doing
business with
foreign companies, tax holidays for new factories set up with
foreign
investments, and a bonded zone—the largest in China—for duty free
imports of raw
materials. Shanghai now has all the trappings of a modern city:
discos,
construction projects, and conspicuous consumption. In short,
where "revered
monuments and golden arches exist side by side" (Riboud 12), the
appearance of
the new Shanghai does nothing less than signal "the end of the
ideological
debate over China's free market experiments" (Tyler A8). Shanghai
has joined the
ranks of the modern metropolis. However, this is not necessarily
a beneficial
development. Inflation is rampant: prices have doubled in the
industrial zones
in the last five years. Nevertheless, the fact that Shanghai
currently possesses
the fifth most expensive office space in the world demonstrates
that demand is
high and that the prospects for future growth are promising
(Tyler A8). Indeed,
Pudong, a free export manufacturing zone described as "the future
sight of
Shanghai's Manhattan" (Tyler A8), boasts more than twenty
factories built or
being built with names like Siemens and Hitachi prominent. This
area has become
particularly attractive to foreign investors and companies
because of its tax
concessions, duty free imports of raw materials, and cheap labor.
Shanghai
stands to benefit, too, as it receives ancillary technology and
discretionary
spending from the workers and executives of the companies
represented (Tyler A8).
It is conditions like these that have caused at least one analyst
to predict
that China will be "the richest economy in the world within the
next 25 years"
(Gilder 372). Shanghai is by no means unique to this growth.
Additional foreign
investments have continued to pour into other areas of China. For
example, the
Boeing Company recently announced its intention to "invest $100
million in a
plant in [Xian] China to make tail sections for 737 jetliners"
("Boeing" D4). In
addition, E.I. du Pont recently predicted "that its investments
and business in
China could increase as much as ten times by the end of the
century" ("Du Pont"
D2). Tellingly, du Pont's chairman attributed the company's
negotiations of "as
many as 28 new projects in China" to the fact "that the country's
financial
changes, improved infrastructure and rising disposable income has
[sic]
encouraged the company to expand its business activities" ("Du
Pont" D2). The
Chinese government has made conscientious attempts to promote the
strength of
the country's economy while protecting its citizens. Just a few
weeks ago, the
government instituted "tight-money policies, intended to control
inflation and
slow what has been the world's fastest growing major economy"
(Shenon "China
Halts" D1). However, after doing so, China's Securities
Regulatory Commission
was forced to stop the issuing of new issues on the Shanghai and
Shenzhen Stock
Exchanges because the value of the markets had decreased so
greatly. This latter
move was "meant to calm millions of first-time Chinese investors
who evidently
went into the market believing that stock prices could only go
up" (Shenon
"China Halts" D1). Might this policy show a union of economic and
moral concern?
If so, it demonstrates the desire on the part of the government
to show some
kind of responsibility, some moral force, to its citizenry. At
the very least,
the strategy appears to show a practical desire on the part of
the government to
take control over what could have been a bad economic situation.
Indeed, after
these measures were instituted, China's trade deficit decreased
(Hansell D2) and
the stock markets' volume attained record highs ("Stocks Surge"
D2). To be sure,
Chinese investors remain somewhat wary about the stock market
and, ironically
enough, more control of the stock markets appears to be necessary
(Shenon "A
Nail-Biting" D1). But, in discussing Chinese attempts to control
inflation,
Philip J. Suttle, head of emerging markets research at the
investment firm of
J.P. Morgan, has predicted that "[i]t looks as though the Chinese
are going to
have the soft landing they are aiming for" (quoted in Hansell
D2). China's
interest in stock markets is no longer restricted to within its
own boundaries.
This month, Shandong Huaneng Power Development Company, "the
first mainland
Chinese company to have its primary listing on the New York Stock
Exchange"
("China Stock" D5), began trading shares. The stock should be an
attractive one
to investors: Chinese electrical "demand is expected to grow
by a whopping
17 million kilowatts a year until the turn of the century"
(Zuckerman D6).
Moreover, China stands to gain from the issue's sales. "The
company plans to use
the $311 million dollars it received from the offering to retire
$83 million in
loans from Chinese state entities. It also plans to expand
its overall
generating capacity" (Zuckerman D6). Nor does this signify the
only Chinese
attempt of raising capital from foreign sources on foreign soil.
"Three more
power companies are expected to be listed in New York and Hong
Kong in the
coming months" (Zuckerman D6). Given the apparent strength of the
Chinese
economy as shown by huge public works projects, extensive foreign
investments,
participation in the world economy, and a generally higher
standard of living by
the populace, it would appear that China is now ready to join the
world as a
modern capitalistic and democratic society. However, this is not
quite the case.
The CCP retains vestiges of those characteristics of insularity
and
intransigence as discussed by Nathan. Because of its human rights
record, the
country's economic growth is being impeded. That is, the politics
of China,
which have always been allied with its economics, are now
restricting
international growth. The United States, especially, has been
concerned with
China's treatment of political dissidents. In May, President
Clinton decided to
end linking China's trade status with the United States with its
record on human
rights. The president has been criticized for this because of
situations like
the following: trials for "'counterrevolutionary activities'
[including]
plans to use a remote-controlled airplane to drop pro-democracy
leaflets over
Tienenmen Square" ("China cracks" A13) have recently begun for
fifteen
dissidents and labor organizers who were involved in the
Tienenmen Square
protests. These trials have "been delayed twice, first to avoid
negative
international reaction just before the decision last September on
China's failed
bid to host the 2000 Olympics and then this spring to avoid
influencing
Clinton's trade decision" ("China cracks" A13). In addition,
China has
instituted "new laws effective in June [which] give sweeping
powers to China's
State Security Bureau to clamp down on dissidents" ("China
cracks" A13). China
is fully aware of United States' concerns about its human rights
record. Given
the fact that the United States has made it clear to China that
that record will
be allied with trade status, China's timing of such restrictive
activities has
caused United States legislators and administrators to question
China's
sincerity in its desire to have a favored trade status with the
United States.
Indeed, just in the past few days, it took a last-minute lobbying
campaign by
President Clinton and his Cabinet [to head off a] potentially
embarrassing vote
by the House of Representatives to restrict trade with China as a
way to punish
Beijing for reported human rights violations. (Bradsher A7) But
China's problems
in joining the community of the world market have more to do than
with its
political ethos and practices. China appears not to understand or
to be able to
follow through on fundamental modern economic practices. For
example, the United
States has recently complained that "China has not complied with
international
rules on access to its markets and protection of copyrights and
patents" (Gargan
14). Such non-compliance could make it difficult for China to
become a founding
member of the World Trade Organization, the successor to the
General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade and the body that is intended to promote
global free trade
by lowering tariffs and other barriers, [which] will be formally
constituted on
January 1, 1994. (Gargan 14) The specific nature of the United
States' complaint
has to do with China's pirating of musical compact disks, video
laser disks and
computer software. In fact, it is estimated that such pirating
costs American
companies a billion dollars a year. This phenomenon seems to have
to do with the
Chinese psychology as described by Nathan. In his 1981 essay he
noted that China
did not wish to become a "technological client of the west. The
preferred
solution is to buy one item and copy it" (Nathan 52). Clearly,
this is not the
way trade works today. It is the United States' position that
China must adhere
to the rules of trade before it can be included in a trade
organization.
Needless to say, exclusion from WTO would be disastrous for any
country, but
particularly for an emerging market such as China. Even on a day
to day basis,
China's economic leaders seem unable to understand how some
aspects of a market
economy work. In discussing the status of the Shanghai Stock
Market, for example,
one stock dealer referred to it as "crazy" ("Stocks Surge" D2).
Moreover,
American analysts have been amazed to discover in the Shanghai
market "the lack
of regulation and the poor disclosure requirements. Some
companies have been
listed for two or three years and have not issued an annual
report" (Hansell D2).
It is no wonder that Chinese investors become anxious about their
investments.
The issuance of shares in the Shandong Huaneng Power Development
Company also
demonstrates the lack of expertise on the part of the Chinese in
the modern
world market. In fact, according to one Hong Kong investment
analyst, "'[t]he
company wasn't really a company. It was just a bunch of discrete
plants that
they tied a bow around and wrote a prospectus on'" (Zuckerman
D6). The
prospectus guaranteed a fifteen percent annual return on
investments. In fact,
the return will no doubt be less than that because of prevailing
currency
exchange rates and debt that the company will have to assume. To
be sure, the
problems of the Shandong Huaneng Power Development Company and
the Shanghai
Stock Exchange may demonstrate only the problems of an immature
economy.
Nevertheless, if China wishes to become a viable member of the
world economic
community, such shortcomings will have to be eliminated quickly.
These apparent
problems may also be the result of an economic system that is run
by the state.
Certainly, one thing that the CCP has attempted to do is create a
market economy
while retaining a state controlled system. This structure may be
possible but it
does have its critics. Steven N.S. Cheung, in an essay written in
1989, argued
for the "creation of private property by mandate" (31), feeling
that
privatization in China would lead to necessary additional
investment in the
society's infrastructure and the establishment of a "judicial
system that is
based firmly on the principle of equality before the law" (Cheung
32). Echoing
Cheung's sentiments, James Dorn saw problems in the areas of
Chinese banking and
finance. In this arrangement, Dorn argued, "the state controls
the bulk of
investment resources. The lack of a private capital market has
handicapped
economic development in China and hampered rational investment
decisionmaking"
(43). In order to become a modern economic state Dorn argued for
the necessity
of circumventing "China's ruling elite who oppose the dismantling
of state
monopolies and who benefit from price fixing and nonprice
rationing" (51). Xu
Zhiming also saw the necessity for a revamping of the Chinese
system: "We must
throw off the traditional system completely" (249) in order for
economic reform
to thrive. Communist Party members, of course, articulate a
different position.
In a recent interview that appeared in the Beijing Review, Feng
Bing, Deputy
Secretary General of the State Commission for Restructuring the
Economic System,
spoke to the issue of economicreform in China. It is striking
[...]...that Feng spoke of the benefits that the populace has received as a result of the economicreform now occurring in China That is, his comments appeared to demonstrate the beneficence, or the moral force, of the ChineseCommunist Party vis-a-vis economicreform He noted that such reform involves the essence of socialism: "to liberate and develop productive forces; to eradicate exploitation;... liberating, politically and economically, one billion Chinese citizens WORKS CITED "Boeing Planning to Invest $100 Million for China Plant." New York Times: 9 August 1994, D4 Bradsher, Keith "Bill to Restrict China's Imports Loses in House." New York Times: 10 August 1994, A7 Cheung, Steven N.S "Privatization vs Special Interests: The Experience of China's Economic Reforms." EconomicReform in China: Problems... and Property: The Chinese Puzzle." EconomicReform in China: Problems and Prospects Ed James A Dorn and Wang Xi Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990 39-61 "Du Pont Plans Increase In Chinese Investment." New York Times: 10 August 1994, D2 Gargan, Edward A "U.S May Thwart China's Trade Goal." New York Times: 24 July 1994, 14 Gilder, George "Let a Billion Flowers Bloom." EconomicReform in China:... prosperity" ("Official" 12) Thus, CCP leaders still appear to see their roles as representatives of a moral force CCP members and leaders wish economic reform not to be judged on just its practical merits, but also as an effect of the moral force of the leadership Economic reform, then, becomes nothing less than a moral crusade and it is thus easy to see why, for example, China "has staked its national prestige... 1994, D1, D4 Shirk, Susan L The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993 Solinger, Dorothy J China's Transition from Socialism: Statist Legacies and Market Reforms, 1980-1990 Armonk, NY: M E Sharpe, 1993 "Stocks Surge in China As Volume Sets Record." New York Times: 9 August 1994, D2 Tyler, Patrick E "Economic Focus in Shanghai: Catching Up." New York... Problems and Prospects Ed James A Dorn and Wang Xi Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990 369-374 Hansell, Saul "Chinese Stock Markets Bounce Back, Rising 30%." New York Times: 2 August 1994, D2 Nathan, Andrew J China's Crisis New York: Columbia University Press, 1990 "Official on Economic Reform. " Beijing Review: 27 June-3 July 1994, 11-15 Riboud, Marc "China Leaps Upward." New York Times Magazine:... Record." New York Times: 9 August 1994, D2 Tyler, Patrick E "Economic Focus in Shanghai: Catching Up." New York Times: 22 December 1993, A1, A8 Xu, Zhiming "The Impact of China's Reform and Development on the Outside World." Economic Reform in China: Problems and Prospects Ed James A Dorn and Wang Xi Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990 247-253 Zuckerman, Laurence "A Foreign Offering's Unsure Pedigree."... the CCP succeed in retaining its political power given the drastic changes in the societal makeup of China that are occurring due to the changing economic realities? I would suggest that the chances are better for the former than for the latter Once the Chinese attain more sophistication relative to international and national markets, institute a more manageable banking system, and make a good faith . Chinese Economic Reform under Communist Rule
Two years after the death of Mao Zedong in 1976, it became
apparent to many of
China's leaders that economic. China even after the
Communist takeover.
It is noteworthy that Shirk feels that the Chinese Communist
Party leaders saw
economic reform as a way to regain