Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 122 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
122
Dung lượng
1,01 MB
Nội dung
FINANCING URBAN INFRASTRUCTURE:
A CASE STUDY OF XI’AN, CHINA
DONG XIN
(HT070173E)
A THESIS SUBMITTED
FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SCIENCE
DEPARTMENT OF BUILDING
NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SIN GAPORE
2009
Acknowledgements
I would like to express my greatest gratitude to my supervisor, Associate Professor
Willie Tan, for his valuable reviews, extensive guidance, and heartful
encouragement.
I would like to express my deepest appreciation to the government officials and
academic researchers in Xi’an who have given me great help in data collection
and valuable advice for my study.
Lastly, I would like to thank my family for their encouragement and support.
~i~
~ ii ~
Content
Summary ................................................................................................................vii
List of Tables ........................................................................................................... ix
List of Figures ......................................................................................................... xi
Chapter 1 Introduction ............................................................................................. 1
1.1 Research problem....................................................................................... 1
1.2 Scope .......................................................................................................... 2
1.3 Objectives .................................................................................................. 3
1.4 Organization of the study ........................................................................... 4
Chapter 2 Literature Review .................................................................................... 5
2.1 Provision of local infrastructure................................................................. 5
2.2 Financing options of local infrastructure ................................................... 8
2.2.1 Local taxes ...................................................................................... 8
2.2.2 Fees ............................................................................................... 11
2.2.3 Intergovernmental transfers .......................................................... 13
2.2.4 Debts ............................................................................................. 17
2.2.5 Private funds ................................................................................. 21
2.3 Hypothesis................................................................................................ 23
Chapter 3 Methodology ......................................................................................... 25
3.1 Research design ....................................................................................... 25
3.2 Data collection and processing ................................................................ 26
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City .............................................................................. 28
4.1 Political structure ..................................................................................... 29
~ iii ~
4.2 Economic development ............................................................................ 32
4.3 Social characteristics ................................................................................ 37
4.3 Level of infrastructure provision ............................................................. 38
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an ............................................. 41
5.1 Centrally planned model in Soviet economy (1949-1978) ...................... 41
5.1.1 Macroeconomic context ................................................................ 41
5.1.2 A centrally planned model ............................................................ 42
5.2 Public finance model in Socialist market economy (1978-2000) ............ 46
5.2.1 Macroeconomic context ................................................................ 46
5.2.2 Local taxes .................................................................................... 48
5.2.3 Fees ............................................................................................... 50
5.2.4 Intergovernmental transfers .......................................................... 52
5.2.5 Loans ............................................................................................. 55
5.2.6 A public finance model ................................................................. 58
5.3 Public corporation model in a marketized economy (2000- ).................. 64
5.3.1 Macroeconomic context ................................................................ 64
5.3.2 Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG)............................. 66
5.3.3 Local revenues and transfers to XIIG ........................................... 67
5.3.4 Intergovernmental transfers .......................................................... 72
5.3.5 Loans ............................................................................................. 74
5.3.6 Private participation ...................................................................... 77
5.3.7 Special districts and self-raised funds ........................................... 81
~ iv ~
5.3.8 A public corporation model ........................................................... 82
5.4 Issues and challenges ............................................................................... 88
5.4.1 XIIG’s debts, projects and government guarantees ...................... 88
5.4.2 Unstable revenue stream from land assignment ........................... 90
5.4.3 Private participation and policy risks............................................ 92
5.4.4 Lure and risks of other financing approaches ............................... 93
Chapter 6 Conclusion ............................................................................................. 96
6.1 Summary .................................................................................................. 96
6.2 Main findings ........................................................................................... 96
6.3 Limitations ............................................................................................... 98
6.4 Recommendations .................................................................................... 99
Appendix .............................................................................................................. 100
Reference ............................................................................................................. 103
~v~
~ vi ~
Summary
The purpose of this research is to examine how urban infrastructure is financed in
Xi’an City in China during the last 60 years since the People’s Republic of China
was founded in 1949. This issue is interesting because little is known about the
causes of new financial arrangements and their efficacy, particularly among inland
cities in China.
Based on the literature review, the study builds up urban infrastructure financing
models for different periods. Accordingly, three different periods may be
identified, namely,
•
1949 to 1978, where a centrally planned model based on the Soviet
experience was used;
•
1978 to 2000, where a public finance model was used during the experimental
stage with free market principles; and
•
2000 and after, where a public corporation model with private participation
was used in a market economy.
In the centrally planned model, the local government collected taxes and
enterprise profit and transferred them to the central government. In turn, the local
government received project specified funds from the central government to carry
out its infrastructure projects. The central government, rather than the local
government, was the main actor in urban infrastructure financing. There was no
~ vii ~
incentive and method for mobilizing private funds.
In the public finance model, the local government became the key initiator and
used a number of sources to finance urban infrastructure. These included
earmarked and general local taxes, public service and administration fees, funds
raised by local governmental agencies, inter-governmental transfers, domestic
loans, and on-lent sovereign loans.
In the public corporation model, Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG)
was established as the central actor to finance urban infrastructure using project
finance. It receives revenue transferred from the local government, obtains on-lent
concessional loans (with the repayment guarantee by the local government), raises
private capital, and enters into joint ventures or franchise BOT agreements with
private companies for infrastructure development.
This study focuses on the changing forms of financing urban infrastructure. It also
identifies a numbers of risks in the current public corporation model, namely,
excessive government guarantee on debt repayment, unsustainable revenue stream
from land assignment, a pricing policy that limits private participation, and
insufficient understanding of the risks in new financial instruments. Several
recommendations are made to mitigate these risks.
~ viii ~
List of Tables
Table 4-1: Natural conditions and resources of Xi’an
Table 4-2: Key economic indicators (Unit: billion CNY)
Table 4-3: 5 major industries’ output (2005)
Table 4-4: Major indicator comparison among cities
Table 4-5: Demographic feature of Xi’an
Table 4-6: Employment situation of Xi’an
Table 5-1: Local budget in the centrally planned economy (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-2: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic development
in centrally planned model
Table 5-3: Local fiscal contribution to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit:
million CNY)
Table 5-4: Contribution of fees to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit: million
CNY)
Table 5-5: Contribution of intergovernmental transfer to infrastructure finance
1996-2000 (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-6: Interest rate and repayment period of domestic loans
Table 5-7: Term and conditions of sovereign loans
Table 5-8: Contribution of loans to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit: million
CNY)
Table 5-9: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic development
1980-2000
Table 5-10: State-owned land assignment of Xi’an 2001-2005
Table 5-11: Transfer of local government revenue to XIIG (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-12: Contribution of local fiscal revenue to infrastructure finance
2001-2007 (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-13: National debt issuance and central budgetary investment in
infrastructure 2001-2008 (Unit: billion CNY)
~ ix ~
Table 5-14: Contribution of intergovernmental transfer to infrastructure finance
2001-2007 (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-15: Projects listed on bond issuance instruction (Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-16: Contribution of loans in infrastructure finance 2001-2007 (Unit:
million CNY)
Table 5-17: Contribution of self-raised funds to infrastructure finance 2001-2008
(Unit: million CNY)
Table 5-18: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic
development 2001-2007
Table 5-19: Level of infrastructure provision in selected years
~x~
List of Figures
Figure 2-1: Economic characteristics of various infrastructure sectors
Figure 2-2: Hypothesis of the study
Figure 4-1: Administrative region division of Xi’an
Figure 4-2: Structure of political hierarchy of China
Figure 4-3: Trends of GDP of three sectors in Xi’an (1952-2006)
Figure 5-1: Centrally planned model of infrastructure finance (1949-1978)
Figure 5-2: Public finance model of infrastructure finance (1978-2000)
Figure 5-3: Infrastructure investment in Xi’an (1996-2000)
Figure 5-4: Sources of funds of infrastructure finance structure in Xi’an
(1996-2000)
Figure 5-5: Trends of infrastructure finance composition in Xi’an (1996-2000)
Figure 5-6: Importance of revenue from land assignment for XIIG
Figure 5-7: Public corporation model of infrastructure finance (after 2000)
Figure 5-8: Scale of funds for infrastructure financing in Xi’an (2001-2007)
Figure 5-9: Sources of funds of infrastructure finance structure in Xi’an
(2001-2007)
Figure 5-10: Trends of infrastructure finance composition in Xi’an (2001-2007)
~ xi ~
~ xii ~
Chapter 1 Introduction
Chapter 1 Introduction
1.1 Research problem
The purpose of this study is to examine the mechanisms the city Xi’an has adopted
in financing its infrastructure since PR China was founded in 1949.
The importance of infrastructure provision in a locale to its overall development is a
tenet of all development theories (Ostrom Schroeder and Wynne, 1993). In an
increasingly integrated world, advanced power, water, and transportation services
are critical to sustain the growth and competitiveness of any economy (Aluko,
2005). According to the World Development Report (World Bank, 1994, p7), “the
adequacy of infrastructure helps determine one country’s success and another’s
failure – in diversifying production, expanding trade, coping with population
growth, reducing poverty, or improving environmental conditions.”
There are many constraints on the delivery of infrastructure, among which finance
is an important one. Generally, central governments only provide limited funds to
local government for the construction and maintenance of infrastructure, since the
main beneficiaries are within the local jurisdiction. Existing residents also resist
higher taxes in developing regions and areas (Savitch and Kantor, 2002). In China,
dramatic changes have occurred in the last half century. Urban areas have
developed from war-torn towns to modern cities. Still, little is known about the
changing forces of new financial arrangements and their efficacy, particularly
~1~
Chapter 1 Introduction
among inland cities in China. It is of great value to understand how urban
infrastructure is financed in different periods, what key variables are there in the
system, and how they evolve as the context changes.
Past studies of public finance in China (Holzer and Zhang, 2003; Qiao Jorge and
Xu, 2008) focus on the fiscal reform in 1994, which caused significant changes in
intergovernmental fiscal relations. Moreover, infrastructure finance researchers
(Lin, 2001; Zhu Liu and Chen, 2004; Qin, 2003; Bellier and Zhou, 2003) mostly
pay their attention to financing at the national level and in a short historical period,
mostly during the recent several years after 1998. This research examines
infrastructure finance at city level, and extends the exploration to include various
periods with distinct political, economic, and social contexts.
1.2 Scope
This study focuses mainly on urban infrastructure finance in Xi’an city in China
from 1949 to 2008. In a broad sense, infrastructure is defined as the facilities that
provide the society with services necessary to conduct daily life and to engage in
productive activities (Mody, 1997). In this study, the definition of urban
infrastructure is limited to the urban “lifelines” and networks, including water
supply,
sewers
and
storm
drainage,
solid
wastes,
energy
supply,
telecommunication, road and bridges, public transit, as well as waterfront
development. Other building-type capital facilities, such as schools, hospitals, jails,
~2~
Chapter 1 Introduction
and recreational facilities, although believed to belong to infrastructure by many
researchers (Miller, 2000), are not considered in this research. Moreover,
telecommunication and waterfront development are also not included in the study,
because telecommunication is nationally managed in China and waterfront
development does not exist in the inland city of Xi’an.
The financing of urban infrastructure in this study concentrates on the new
construction and system expansion. Costs associated with operation and
maintenance will not be considered. In developed countries, cities need vast
amounts of investment to prevent their existing infrastructure from deteriorating.
However, the major problem developing cities are facing is to provide essential
infrastructure of a certain quality that is financially accessible to the local
population. Indeed, in a few decades, the maintenance issue will be increasingly
significant as a result of the construction of many new infrastructure projects, but
this issue is beyond the scope of the study.
The political and economic contexts in the financing of the urban infrastructure
will be considered. The special Chinese political order and development pattern
have significant implications on the results of the study.
1.3 Objectives
The objectives of this study are:
~3~
Chapter 1 Introduction
•
to build models of infrastructure finance of Xi’an in different periods;
•
to understand why different models are adopted; and
•
to identify potential risks and challenges in the current model.
1.4 Organization of the study
Chapter 2 provides the literature review and develops the hypothesis. It focuses on
the characteristics of infrastructure provision and the various sources of funds that
can be mobilized by local governments to finance urban infrastructure. Chapter 3
describes the case study methodology used in this research and methods of data
collection. Chapter 4 and Chapter 5 are in-depth studies of the case city Xi’an, on
how infrastructure provision is financed. Chapter 4 introduces background of the
city, including its political structure, economic development, and social
characteristics. Chapter 5 builds structural models of infrastructure financing in
three different periods, analyzing the importance of variables in the models as well
as the political and economic forces behind their emergences and substitutions.
Chapter 6 summarizes the main findings, implications, limitations, and provides
suggestions for future research.
~4~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
Chapter 2 Literature Review
Capital infrastructure is crucial to a city – it affects the economic competitiveness
of its business and the living standards of its residents. Developing cities and
mature cities all face a formidable challenge in financing their capital expenditures,
because of the difficulty in balancing their significant capital requirements and
limited sources of financing (Brittain, 2002). This chapter reviews the literature on
the responsibility of urban infrastructure provision and its financing.
2.1 Provision of local infrastructure
This section mainly addresses two aspects. One aspect is the suitability of public
provision of local infrastructure. The other aspect is the responsibility of the local
government and central government in the provision of urban infrastructure.
The foremost characteristic of urban infrastructure is a mixture of public goods and
private goods. Private goods are individually purchased and consumed, suitable to
be provided in competitive markets, while public goods are non-rival and
non-excludable in their supplies and consumption. Being non-rival, serving
particular goods to an additional consumer only generates negligible marginal cost,
so that any positive price will exceed the marginal cost and therefore is inefficient.
Being excludable, it is difficult to exclude non-paying customers from consuming
the good or service. As a result, it is uneconomical for private sector to provide the
goods (Trebilcock and Daniels, 1993). As a hybrid of public and private goods,
~5~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
infrastructure could be provided by the public or private sectors.
Figure 2-1: Economic characteristics of various infrastructure sectors (World
Bank, 1994)
Another possible feature of infrastructure provision is that of a natural monopoly.
The provision of these networks involves economies of scale, where large scale
consumption could enhance quality and lower cost of providing such goods. The
introduction of competition leads to unnecessary duplication of network systems,
and this is considered a waste of resources. Public ownership of natural monopolies
is justified on the ground that a private monopoly would lead to exploitation of
consumers. However, a natural monopoly may be broken up for competition, such
as in telecommunications, power industries and some railroads that are owned and
operated privately, under the supervision of certain regulating agencies (Hulten
and Schwab, 1993).
~6~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
The public provision of infrastructure raises the issue of responsibility allocation
and distribution between tiers of governments. In practice, each level of
government receives a specific “block of responsibilities”, based on its fiscal
power and political status. In recent decades, a process of decentralization has been
implemented in many countries. Advocators stressed its merits of greater efficiency,
accountability, flexibility and innovation in local public service (Wolman, 1983).
Dissenters warned of the drawbacks of the arrangements such as inefficiency, waste
and corruption (Peterson, 1981).
Most public finance economists favor the decentralization of infrastructure
provision. Capital expenditure requires initial investment (normally intensive) and
subsequent maintenance, with continuous depreciate and eventual replacement.
They state that tastes and preferences differ among jurisdictions. Welfare gains are
achieved by decentralizing expenditure decisions to the level of government that
best incorporates a community of common or similar interests (Musgrave and
Musgrave, 1976). Decentralization can improve accountability by clarifying the
responsibilities of various units of governments, reducing the costs of constituent
participation, and increasing the likelihood that participation will influence
policies (Ostrom, Schroeder and Wynne, 1993). Therefore, it is reasonable to
assume that identifying local preferences is easier for local governments that are
close to the ground, so that a better match between supply and demand of
infrastructure can be expected (Oates, 1985; Oates, 1989). However, researchers
also point out that decentralization improves infrastructure service only if local
~7~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
governments enjoy sufficient political and financial autonomy and are
institutionally accountable (Bird, 1993). For infrastructure that cut across local
jurisdictions (e.g. rail transport), regional provision is more efficient because of
the need for coordination.
To sum up, it is possible for the public sector to mainly or at least partly provide
local infrastructure, because of its public goods and natural monopoly features.
With a natural monopoly, it is possible to carve out areas for competition and
private provision.
2.2 Financing options of local infrastructure
This section reviews the literature on various financial resources that local
government can utilize to finance infrastructure. They are categorized into five
types, namely, local taxes, fees, intergovernmental transfers, debts, and private
funds. The first three are used for a wide range of purposes including
infrastructure; the latter two are usually used especially for financing
infrastructure. Each resource is reviewed to clarify its attributes, classifications,
pros and cons, as well as its applications.
2.2.1 Local taxes
Local governments draw their own revenue from taxes, fees, and other forms of
incomes like fines or investment returns. Of the above resources, tax is the most
~8~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
relevant to the provision of public services, which also attracts public attention to a
large extent.
Taxes are generally divided into property tax, consumption tax, and income tax,
and is structured at federal (central), regional (state, provincial), and local levels. In
the developed countries, the most common form of direct local tax is property tax.
The tax normally imposes on various types of properties: residential, commercial,
industrial, and institutional properties. As the city develops, although property tax
remains the revenue mainstay at local level, consumption and income taxes are
increasingly relied upon as well.
All the for-and-against arguments on a particular tax item concern its level of
“efficiency” as well as “equity”. In an ideal tax system, interference with efficient
market economic decisions is minimized and private inefficiencies are corrected.
Tax contributions are made in line with the benefit received from public service and
according to their economic ability to achieve the redistribution function of the
public sector (Musgrave, 1976).
Property tax is a type of wealth tax, justified on the basis that surrounding public
services provide security to property and increase its value (Dunkerly, 1983;
Tideman, 1982). The valuation of properties and land, which determines the tax
being paid, is an important issue (Calhoun, 2001; Allen and Dare, 2002; Cooper,
1996). Consumption tax at the local level is studied from three aspects: resident
demand (Mullins and Wallance, 1996), taxable business transactions (Fryman,
~9~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
1969; Derrick and Scott, 1993), and visitor/commuter spending (Hawkins and
Murray, 2004). Local income tax in various countries is studied carefully and
compared comprehensively by the World Bank (Budina and Irwin, 2005).
Apart from the general allocation of property tax, income tax, and consumption
tax, earmarked tax is often used in financing infrastructure. Tax earmarking is the
allocation of certain tax revenues to a designated end use. Newbery and Santos
(1999) believe that earmarking taxes for dedicated capital expenditure is an
obvious application of the benefit principle of taxation which, properly applied,
should lead to a more efficient structure of local service provision. In the US, a
major source for transportation infrastructure finance is an earmarked tax – the
gasoline tax. Other supporters point out that assigning of receipts – from a
particular tax base or a proportion from a wide pool of revenue to specific end use
– reflects informed choices of taxpayers and more democracy (Wikinson, 1994).
Skeptical opinions (Dilnot, 1993) argue that public spending should be determined
by policy decisions, instead of amount of revenue raised by an earmarked tax.
They also state that earmarking reduce the flexibility of the fiscal system, because
excess revenues may accumulate somewhere while deficiencies occur somewhere
else simultaneously.
According to Stiglitz (1988), most items imposed on by local taxes are mobile in the
long run, especially capital. A community that increases capital tax will have to
either offer better public services or ultimately see an erosion of their tax base, such
~ 10 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
as when investors divest their properties or “vote with their feet” (Tiebout, 1956;
Winner, 2005). Therefore, local tax can hardly stand as the only source for local
infrastructure finance.
2.2.2 Fees
Fees are money paid by citizens to governments to support services they received.
They are distinguished from taxes for their voluntary purchase of particular
services. Usually, revenues from fees are used to cover the costs of the service
provisions. Theoretically, benefit taxes and earmarked taxes such as the gasoline
tax are mixtures of taxes and fees, since they are freely purchased and used for
particular expense purposes (Ulbrich, 2003).
Fees can be divided into two categories, permits and service charges. Permits are
authorizations to engage in certain kind of activities. Examples include business
licenses, driver licenses, and building permits. Fees for services are charges
incurred when a particular publicly provided service is ordered, such as park entry,
toll road passage, postal service, and sewer service.
In financing urban infrastructure, fees are often preferred, because it is considered
more equitable than taxes. Taxes are levied only on residents, while fees are
applicable to residents and nonresidents. Those who do not pay local taxes would
also contribute to the costs of services they are provided, which internalizes
positive externalities of public infrastructure services. Being a non-tax financing
~ 11 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
source, fees can be spent without incurring too much political implication to
voters as taxes would do. Moreover, many administrators believe that supporting
facilities through user fees leads to greater administrative efficiency (Porter and
Peiser, 1991).
Critics against imposition of fees come from the consideration of another aspect of
equity – “ability to pay”. Infrastructure is normally a basic service that is
consumed by rich and poor to a similar degree. Therefore, poor residents would
pay a larger portion of their income for the same amount of service, rendering fees
regressive and inequitable (Netzer, 1992). In principle, price discrimination for
different age, income group, and other factors could partially address this problem.
But the way to set rational prices for certain services, reflecting their marginal
costs for various users and areas, is still controversial.
In practice, fees related to public infrastructure are levied in most countries. User
charges of various public utilities and services are the most common forms of fees.
Publicly provided water, gas, and waste disposal are all subject to a certain level
of user charges. Sometimes, charges are levied on some services-related items
instead of the services themselves. For example, ordinary urban roads are not
charged, but vehicle registration fees, annual license fees, and fuel fees are levied
to finance the urban transportation system.
Other than user charges and services-related item fees, impact fee is commonly
used for infrastructure finance of new urban areas in developed countries. Impact
~ 12 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
fees are imposed on developers in the development process, and are designed to
provide infrastructure to the development or to ensure the development’s
contribution to larger scale infrastructure expansions (Levine, 1994). It shifts
payments from owners of existing property to parties associated with the new
developing property (Evans and Lawhon, 2003). It was first employed in the US
to overcome the fiscal gap arose from general revenue finance. By using impact
fees, new infrastructure becomes cost-free for public treasury, and might even
generate a higher tax base because of the rising price of the development.
However, it is also criticized that the costs would shift to new homeowners and
tenants at the market interest rate of mortgage repayment, rather than the less
costly interest of public debts (Jeong and Feiock, 2006).
Other local revenues include fines, payment for services to higher tiers of
government, interest income on invested cash, and other miscellaneous sources.
These constitute a small part of local revenue, and would not be included in the
study.
2.2.3 Intergovernmental transfers
Intergovernmental transfer refers to grants donated from one tier of government to
another, usually from senior governments to subordinate governments. Therefore,
local government is often considered as the recipient of transfers from central
government, or regional government. In some areas, local fiscal sustainability relies
heavily on intergovernmental transfers. As Lewis (2006) noted, central government
~ 13 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
transfer in Indonesia accounts for 92% of local fiscal resources, whereas taxes and
user charges only add 8% to total local revenue.
There are two basic types of intergovernmental transfers, general and earmarked. In
Canada, they are called unconditional transfer and conditional transfer; in the US,
they are called general-purpose grants and categorical grants. General
intergovernmental transfer does not put constraints on the expenditure area. It is
often distributed on a lump-sum basis automatically according to certain preset
criteria. The determination of transfer amount relies on several factors, for
instance, population, tax base, and poverty rate of a jurisdiction, etc. In contrast,
earmarked intergovernmental transfer must be spent for a designated use, such as
parks or disables, or on particular projects. Sometimes earmarked transfer is only
granted with an attached condition. For example, donor government may ask for a
proportional matching fund from the recipient government. Due to limited pool of
funds, these grants sometimes need several applying governments to compete for it
(Bergvall, et al., 2006).
In some countries like Denmark, there is an equalization transfer system between
local authorities directly. Equalization is achieved by taking resources from richer
local authorities to poorer authorities, thus making central fund unnecessary in the
system (Pedersen, 2002).
The literature justifies intergovernmental transfers to local governments on the
ground that it is more efficient to collect income taxes centrally to avoid capital
~ 14 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
flight across local areas or regions. These collected revenues are then transferred
to local and state governments according to some equitable formula.
A municipality, as a relatively small open economic system and a constitutional
creature of senior governments, has limited autonomy and monopoly ability to raise
revenue. In many countries, the income tax base and tax rate are determined
nationally by higher governments (Gerasimova, 2005). Therefore, a local
government has rather limited power to raise funds through income taxes. In other
countries where local tax policies are set by municipalities, local tax collection is
also restricted due to government’s concern about tax base variation. In the US, and
in Europe to a less extent, cities regard themselves as competitors fighting against
each other for high mobile labor and capital. A high level of local tax may distant
taxpayers from its jurisdiction (Tiebout, 1956). Since people are less likely to move
out of a state (province) and a country, it would be appropriate for the higher tier of
governments to raise money for local expenditures. Intergovernmental transfer,
especially unconditional transfer, is justified on this ground (Kitchen and Slack,
2005).
Transfers also have a horizontal equity purpose (Santiago, 2008). Cities,
constrained by geographic, historical, and demographic factors, may differ in their
taxable wealth (Bradbury, 1983). Transfers are collected from both rich and poor
areas. In many circumstances, transfers are allocated to reduce the revenue
disparities among local governments, so that low income municipalities could
~ 15 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
enjoy more redistribution benefits from grants (Break, 1967).
From a political perspective, intergovernmental transfers are granted as a steering
tool for higher tiers of governments, especially conditional transfers. High tiers of
governments may have different priorities compared to those of local governments
(Uguy, 2001; Copeland and Meier, 1984). Transfers would encourage local
government to provide services in areas where local government may prefer not to
provide on their own. Transfers are also means of gaining political support, such as
channeling funds away from anti-government areas.
Although
justified
from
both
economic
and
political
perspectives,
intergovernmental transfer also encounters critics for its impacts on local
accountability reduction, and unpredictability of local revenue (Sim, 2001).
The accountability issue arises from circumstances where more than two levels of
government share responsibility in providing certain services. In the case of
intergovernmental transfer, local governments perform partly on behalf of senior
governments who raise the funds. Less incentive towards efficiency would be
generated from an agent’s role than being the revenue raiser. Besides,
accountability is blurred with one government raising funds and another one
delivering services (Fisher, 1982).
Grants, especially those with selection and screening process, are not stable local
revenues, because they are discretionary. Various methods have been developed to
~ 16 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
advantage oneself in the competition of these funds (Caruson and MacManus,
2005). Due to fiscal status of donor government and variations of grant policies,
transfers received would vary from year to year. Therefore, heavy reliance on
transfers would generate high revenue instability and unpredictability.
2.2.4 Debts
Loans to local governments include government loans, commercial loans, and
sovereign loans. Government loans refer to loans granted by other tiers of
governments or funds, but differentiated from government transfers in terms of the
obligation for repayment. Commercial loans refer to loans granted by banks,
insurance companies, and other financial entities. Sovereign loans refer to loans
granted by multilateral development banks (MDBs) and foreign countries for
development purposes.
Higher governments may act as lenders to local government for financing
infrastructure. On the one hand, the payback period of an infrastructure project is
usually long. On the other hand, subsidized lending is often needed in the form of
low interest rate. Sometimes, higher governments do not lend directly, but set up a
revolving loan fund for urban authorities to borrow (Krishnan, 2007). Central
governments may also borrow on their own credit standing to get cheaper loans and
then onlend it to local governments.
Local governments may borrow from capital markets directly as well, especially in
~ 17 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
those profitable infrastructure areas. If being sponsored by higher government
guarantees against local default, local governments can obtain higher credit ratings
and borrow at lower interest rates (ADB, 2003).
Sometimes, commercial
financing agencies may receive tax reliefs in exchange for lending to the
government at lower interest rates.
International lending institutions usually provide long-term low interest or
interest-free loans and grants to developing counties to assist their development
(OECD, 2007). The major MDBs are the World Bank, African Development Bank,
Asian Development Bank, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development,
and Inter-American Development Bank Group. The central governments of many
developed countries, such as Denmark, Spain, Germany, and Japan also provide
similar loans and grants to developing countries. Compared with commercial
loans, interest rate of sovereign loans are normally much lower. Besides,
sovereign loans usually have a long repayment periods and several years of grace
period. The major risk in international borrowing is the foreign exchange risk,
because these loans are often denominated in international currencies.
Governments can also issue bonds to finance local urban development (Lai, 2007).
A bond is a transferable claim to repayment of the principal with interest at a time
and interest rate stated on its face. A municipal bond is the most widely used type of
public loans in the US, which can be bought on issuance or in secondary market.
Usually, the funds have to be spent on specific capital projects, with a repayment
~ 18 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
time from several months to 40 years or even longer. Interest income received by
holders of municipal bonds is often income tax exempt. Therefore, bond holders
would accept lower interest payment than other types of investment. Municipal
bonds may be general obligations bond which are backed by the full faith and credit
of the issuer; or revenue bonds which are secured by specified revenues, such as
revenue from a road project.
Debt financing is widely used in local infrastructure development. The most
frequently mentioned rationale for debt financing is the equity principle of public
finance, especially the intergeneration distribution of the tax and repayment burden.
If debt financing is used, especially if loans are amortized in tandem with physical
depreciation, the services citizens get would be closely connected with the amount
they pay. Therefore, classic public finance textbooks suggest that while current
expenses should be covered from current revenue, urban infrastructure and other
capital expenditures should be funded by loans (Musgrave and Musgrave, 1976).
Another justification for the use of debt is the fluctuating local revenue and
infrastructure expenditure. On the revenue aspect, local revenue is generated from
taxes and fees that are influenced by macro-economic conditions. As a rather small
economy, local government has a very limited impact on the market conditions that
generate fluctuating local revenue. On the expenditure side, capital investment need
fluctuates at the local level as well. It is much easier for central governments to even
out investments among regions and sectors to create a smooth expenditure stream
~ 19 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
(Mikesell, 1982).
However, debt financing is often seen as risky (Garbislander and Haas, 2002). It is
believed that politicians and/or citizens are myopic, and are unable to take future
generations into account when making investment decisions for debt financing.
Therefore, they tend to engage in costly investments, and the cumbersome debt
repayment would be left to future governments and citizens. Once a local
government falls into heavy debt burden, it has to raise tax rate or introduce new
taxes to generate more revenue. In the public choice theory, residents would
respond to this situation by moving, which drag local governments into a fiscal
crisis. Therefore, it is reasonable to set constraints to the total amount that debt
financing can be used (Myna, 2007).
In practice, Belgium, Australia, Denmark, France and many countries all divide
local budgets into ordinary budget which affords current public consumption and
capital budget which finance capital expenditures including infrastructure (Gilbert
and Guengant, 2002). Normally permissions are given to public utilities and some
other prioritized areas, with a ceiling on the aggregate value nationwide annually.
Other than these restrictions, detailed arrangements such as volume, interest rate,
loans duration, and identity of the lender can be freely chosen by local authorities
(Vanneste, 2002).
~ 20 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
2.2.5 Private funds
Project financing of infrastructure provides governments a financing alternative
from raising taxes or borrowing (Barr, 1998). These projects are normally financed
through non-recourse or limited recourse lending. A special purpose vehicle (SPV)
which owns the project is set up by sponsors who contribute equity and
management expertise, and it borrows money from capital markets. Revenues
generated from products produced or services provided by the project represent the
only or principal source of debt repayment. Should the project go into default, the
lenders have recourse only to the assets and cash flows of the project company,
without further recourse to the sponsors of the project (Tan, 2007). This
configuration is suitable for infrastructure project like toll roads, water supply
facilities, wastewater treatments, and natural gas, because they can generate stable
long-term revenue stream for debt repayment. However, sponsors are often
required to provide contingency funds up to a certain limit, such as when a project
incurs cost over-runs.
Public Private Partnership (PPP) refers to long-term co-operation between public
and private sectors in which the actors develop mutual products and services and in
which risks, costs, and benefits are shared (Klijn and Terisman, 2000). PPP is
frequently used in infrastructure project financing.
There are many ways in which PPP may be structured (United Nations, 1998).
“Contracting out” means that private sector simply provides management services
~ 21 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
to a facility for an agreed period and fee without relating to the ownership and
financing. “Joint venture” means that public and private sectors jointly finance,
own and operate a facility in the form of a jointly sponsored infrastructure
company. “Franchise” means that public sector grants a private firm an exclusive
franchise or monopoly privileges to supply a particular service within an area.
“Build-Operate-Transfer” is the most common form of it in which private sector
finances, builds, and operates the facility for a certain period (normally 25-30
years) in order to repay debts and earn returns, and then transfers the facility back
to the public sector. In this case, the government maintains formal ownership of the
project and certain degree of pricing control. “Private Finance Initiative” (Ball et
al., 2007) and “Leasing” (Colucci, 1999) means ownership of the facility remains
in private hands, with the public sector purchasing/leasing services provided by the
private company. In this case, substantial part of risks associated with financing
and operating the facility are allocated on the private sector.
PPPs have many advantages. In the finance aspect, the benefits of involving the
private sector are the transfer of risk, substitutes for public borrowing and up-front
costs, and the protection of users and tax-payers from the financing burden. In the
management aspect, the private sector contributes its expertise in specific
technical skills, sophisticated budgeting and accounting techniques (OECD, 1991).
Hodge (2000) reviews studies examining the cost issue in private provision and
finds a 10%-30% reduction in various areas. However, because of measurement
problems, such studies should not be viewed as conclusive.
~ 22 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
On the other hand, PPP is criticized as a maneuver of governments to avoid
immediate fiscal deficit or debt restriction, neglecting future fiscal risks and the
costs it poses. Complaints include complicated financing arrangements, cost
increases, less possibility of networks extension to the poor, adverse environmental
impact and more opportunities for corruption. It is argued that high profit sought by
private investors will inevitably increase the price of services. Besides, public
investment incurs a lower cost than private investment, because the government is
able to borrow at a lower cost.
The use of PPP in developing countries experienced significant growth in the 1990s.
Over 755 billion USD of investments flowed in nearly 2500 infrastructure projects
between 1990 and 2001. However, many of them led to renegotiation, discontent,
cancellation, and other disappointing results. Actually, PPP became less popular
after the Asian financial crisis of 1997-1998 (Harris, 2003). Some studies attribute
this problem to unrealistic pricing of infrastructure services, which challenged
many political concerns of local governments. To address this problem, the World
Bank (Irwin, 2007) proposed a comprehensive way to assess the overall fiscal
implications of PPP projects which includes estimation of true fiscal consequences
of financing publicly, and assessment of the cost of government’s commitment.
2.3 Hypothesis
Based on the literature review, it is seen that the appropriate structure of local
~ 23 ~
Chapter 2 Literature Review
infrastructure finance is the mixture of tax, fees, transfers, loans and private
capital. Each form of financing has pros and cons, potentials and constraints. The
appropriate choice of instruments one city choose would be impacted by national
guidelines and directives, cost of funds, as well as the internal characteristics of a
city (see figure 2-2). Therefore, the financing model of infrastructure in Xi’an can
be divided into three periods: 1949-1978, 1978-2000, and after 2000.
Central Guidelines
and Directives
Sources of Funds:
• Taxes
• Fees
• Transfers
• Private capitals
• Loans
Infrastructure
Financing Model
Cost of
Funds
Internal Characteristics
of the City
Figure 2-2: Hypothesis of the study
~ 24 ~
Chapter 3 Methodology
Chapter 3 Methodology
3.1 Research design
The case study approach is adopted in this research. A case study can be
categorized according to the number of cases, spatial variation, and temporal
variation. This research was the single case diachronic study, with little spatial
variation but substantial temporal variation.
The intent of the case study is to probe intensively into the way urban
infrastructure is financed in the city of Xi’an. In order to provide insight into a
broader phenomenon, a typical-case approach is adopted to select a city that is as
representative as possible of China’s inland urban infrastructure development.
Xi’an, the capital city of Shaanxi Province, was chosen. It is a city with 1)
temperate climate; 2) an average population, urbanization rate, economic
development compared to other parts of China; 3) diversified industries and social
sectors; 4) absence of any outstanding peculiarities or acute local problems.
The research is of an exploratory nature. The study holistically zooms in the
experience of the city using multiple sources of evidence. This encourages a
flexible research strategy since data are not restricted to any particular source (Tan,
2004).
Under investigation of the case, an in-depth insight of evolvement of urban
~ 25 ~
Chapter 3 Methodology
infrastructure finance model is gained. To be sure, although Xi’an is a typical
inland Chinese city, the conclusions are difficult to generalize based on a single
case.
3.2 Data collection and processing
The study is carried out in the field setting of the case city. Both quantitative and
qualitative data are collected and analyzed. Quantitative data come from internal
and external sources. Data are mainly taken from the following sources:
•
Statistical data;
•
Governmental report and information on their official websites/ databases;
•
Intermal governmental files;
•
Company profiles;
•
Published papers and research theses.
Qualitative data are both abstracted from reports and collected from discussions.
Interviews were organized with bureau officials from Xi'an Municipal Urban&
Rural Construction Commission, Xi’an Statistical Bureau, and researchers in
related social organizations. The purposes of these discussions are to better
understand causes and implications.
The preliminary data processing focuses on reliability and consistency of the data.
Most of the data come from government bureaus and their statistical publications.
~ 26 ~
Chapter 3 Methodology
It is not uncommon that data with the same name suggest different meanings, and
the same data vary in different government sources. Carefully comparison and
cross referencing eliminate some unreliable data. More importantly, organizing
discussions with the government officials help us to understand the exact meaning
of each term and to find the original document. Any inconsistency caused by
change of calculating method is adjusted or pointed out in the study.
~ 27 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
Xi’an, the capital of Shaanxi Province, is one of China’s key inland cities in
northwest from political, economic, and cultural perspectives. It lies in the centre of
Guanzhong Plain (107°14′E-109°15′E, and 33°14′N-34°14′N), bounded by the
Qinling Mountains in the south and the Loess Plateau in the north. The total area
within the city jurisdiction is 10,108 km2, in which 35.44% (3582 km2) is urban area.
The central urban area contains nine administrative districts, including Xincheng,
Beilin, Lianhu, Baqiao, Weiyang, Yanta, Yanliang, Lintong, and Chang’an. Four
peripheral counties, namely Lantian, Zhouzhi, Huxian, and Gaoling constitute the
other 6526 km2, showing predominantly rural characteristics (see Fig. 4-1).
Figure 4-1: Administrative region division of Xi’an
Xi’an has a semi-moist monsoon climate. The annual temperature is 14.9℃ on
average, with 541.4 mm precipitation including snow in winter time. Other detailed
~ 28 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
natural conditions and resources are listed in Table 4-1.
Average annual temperature/℃
14.9
Annual precipitation/mm
541.4
Total sunshine time/h
1949.4
Average wind speed/m*s-1
1.0
Area of cultivated land/1000 ha
266.8
Area of forestry/1000 ha
522.5
Inland water area/1000 ha
32.3
3
Total water resources/ billion m
2.7
Table 4-1: Natural conditions and resources of Xi’an
Source: Official website of Xi’an City People’s Government
4.1 Political structure
Since antiquity, China has been governed by multiple administrative levels;
because of its broad area, large population and varied ethnics. Currently, there are
six de facto tiers of governments: Central, Provincial, Prefectural, County,
Township and Village. Township and village only exist in rural areas. In urban areas,
a service committee called Administrative District functions similar to township,
but the administrative district does not act as a layer of official government
politically. Each layer has its own departmental structure. The six layers form a
mono-hierarchical system, where lower levels of governments are completely
subordinate to higher levels. The structure of political hierarchy in China is shown
in Figure 4-2.
~ 29 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
Figure 4-2: Structure of political hierarchy of China
The meaning of word “City” in Chinese is determined by context. It could refer to
provincial-level cities directly under the central government, like Beijing, Shanghai,
and Hong Kong. But more often it refers to prefecture-level city under provincial
governance or county-level city under prefectural governance. Normally, several
prefecture-level cities constitute a province. Each prefecture-level city contains
several counties, county-level cities, and urban administrative districts. By
definition, a prefectural city has to meet several criteria: more than 200,000
non-farming population, a relatively advanced tertiary sector that makes up more
than 35% of its GDP, and local government budget exceeding 200 million CNY.
Xi’an is a prefecture-level city. A special case in prefecture-level cities is
“sub-provincial” cities, which means they are actually given a higher level than a
normal prefecture politically but still lower than provincial level. These are
prefecture-level cities that enjoy a higher degree of autonomy and development
priorities. There are 15 cities in the country which rank at sub-provincial level.
Usually, they are provincial capitals and large prefectures in a province. Xi’an, as
~ 30 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
the capital city of Shaanxi province, is one of the sub-provincial cities.
The term “local government” in China refers to any sub-provincial level of
government. In the case of Xi’an, local government is a prefectural level
government, called Xi’an City People’s Government (XCPG). Although its
sub-provincial position gives it some special political advantages, the essential
attributes are the same as other prefectures. The local government reports their
work to the people’s congress and the standing committee at prefectural level. It
also reports its work to provincial government and accepts the unified leadership of
the State council from central government. It directs the economic, cultural, and
administrative work of the city. It also directs the administrative affairs of county
governments under its jurisdiction.
XCPG is composed of a mayor, vice mayors, secretaries-general and directors of
various official bureaus, commissions, and agencies. The mayor and vice mayors
are elected by the people’s congress, which is the organ local people exercise their
power stipulated by China’s Constitution. The People’s congress is comprised of
representatives voted by local residents, so only limited residents could participate
in the process of mayor election. The term of their services is five years. The
bureaucratic system is structured into local departmental agencies, central vertical
agencies, public institutions, public state-owned companies, and social
organizations. There are currently 28 local departmental agencies. Head officers of
these agencies are nominated by the mayor. But the nomination power of mayor is
~ 31 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
not as significant as it seems. In most cities in China, the power of Secretary of
Party Municipal Commission is at least as strong as the mayor. The Secretary who
represents the Communist Party will in practice impact the head officer
nomination extensively. There are another 22 vertical agencies under direct
leadership of individual central departmental ministries. Head officers of these
agencies are nominated by central ministries rather than local governments.
Development zones and industrial parks are special zones within prefectural
jurisdiction with economic and policy priorities. Public institutions or public
state-owned companies are established to manage the development of these parks.
They are given political autonomy; they are also given concessional land price, tax
rebate and other favored economic policies. They adopted experience from the US
to implement corporate management in the zone. They are responsible for
stimulating business and attracting investments, financing infrastructure inside the
zone, and implementing new patterns and mechanisms as pioneers.
4.2 Economic development
Xi’an has achieved considerable economic accomplishments in the last several
decades, especially in the last ten years. In 2006 its GDP reached 147.37 billion
yuan, which doubled the number five years before, and equals 780 times the
number when People’s Republic of China was founded in 1949. GDP per capita
increased to 17,825 CNY (2245 USD) in 2006, which is benchmarked as the first
~ 32 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
time exceeding 2000 USD. Foreign direct investment (FDI) also grows
exponentially after China joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001. In
2006, FDI was 825 million USD, an increase of 44% from the previous year. The
Consumer Price Index (CPI) stayed below 102 (compared with the data in previous
year) and Producer Price Index (PPI) below 104 in recent years, which represent
low inflation.
Item
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
GDP
64.61
73.49
82.67
94.67
110.24
127.01
147.37
GDP /capita1 /CNY
9484
10628
11831
13341
15294
15859*
17825
4.46
4.59
4.78
5.07
6.02
6.60
7.08
Secondary sector
27.71
31.29
35.36
40.74
47.69
53.96
63.89
Tertiary sector
32.43
37.61
42.53
48.86
56.53
66.45
76.40
Fixed asset
23.24
28.77
33.86
47.81
64.67
83.51
106.66
Primary sector2
CPI
100.2
99.9
98.6
100.5
102.3
100.3
101.6
PPI
99.4
99.3
98.2
101.5
102.7
103.9
103.2
256
276
571
825
FDI /mil.US$
156
177
203
1
Since 2005, GDP per capita is adjusted to residential population, instead of registered
population, because of the trend of increasing labor mobility.
2
China categorizes economy into three sectors. Primary sector refers to agriculture,
forestry, stock raising and fishing. Secondary sector refers to mining, manufacturing,
public utility (power, gas, and water) production and supply, as well as construction. Other
from these, the rest is categorized as tertiary sector, including transportation, IT, retail,
R&D, finance, real estate, education, sports, entertainment, social welfare, social
organization, and so on.
Table 4-2: Key economic indicators (Unit: billion CNY)
Source: Xi’an statistic yearbook.
Fig 4-2 shows the economic increase of primary, secondary and tertiary sectors in
Xi’an from the 1950s. Currently, the tertiary sector is the largest sector. In 2006,
GDP of the three sectors are 7.077 billion, 63.89 billion, and 76.40 billion CNY;
~ 33 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
which form 4.8%, 43.4%, and 51.8% of total GDP respectively. The share of the
secondary sector and tertiary sector started to rise in the 1990s after a relatively
sluggish development in the first forty years. The growth of tertiary sector is
slightly faster than the secondary sector. In contrast, the primary sector produces
relatively stable output every year with imperceptible increases.
160
GDP/billion CNY
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
1952
1957
1965
1970
1975
1978
1980
1983
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
0
Year
GDP
Primary Industry GDP
Secondary Industry GDP
Tertiary Industry GDP
Figure 4-3: Trends of GDP of three sectors in Xi’an (1952-2006)
Source: Xi’an Local Chronicles
The main industrial products of Xi’an include electricity, dairy, soft drink, beer,
yarn, paper, sewing machine, detergent, traditional Chinese medicine, cement,
shaped steel, industrial boiler, motor vehicle, AC motor, transformer, electric cable,
telecommunication cable, color kinescope, meters and instruments. The five major
industries are equipments manufacturing, high-tech industry, tourist industry,
cultural service industry, and modern service industry (Table 4-3):
~ 34 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
Industry
Output /CNY billion
Proportion to GDP/%
Equipment manufacturing
17.9
14.2
High-tech industry
10.0
7.9
Tourist industry
9.7
7.6
Cultural industry
6.4
5.1
24.7
19.5
Modern service industry
Table 4-3: 5 major industries’ output (2005)
Source: Xi’an statistic yearbook 2006.
As the capital of Shaanxi Province, Xi’an plays an essential role in provincial
economic development. In 2005, GDP, fixed assets investment, and export/import
of Xi’an made up 34.56%, 35.91%, and 85.23% of those of the province
respectively. It is estimated by the provincial government that in the future, Xi’an
would continue to be the main engine of provincial economic development, and
more resources would be provided by the provincial government.
From a parallel perspective, however, the development of Xi’an lagged behind that
of large coastal cities such as Shanghai and Qingdao. This is due to two main
reasons. Firstly, because of the distribution of central political power in the last
two decades, China’s reform policy has always concentrated on the coastal south
and east of the country, rather than cities in the inner west like Xi’an. Secondly,
inland cities are relatively insulated from the political, economic, and cultural
innovations of the dynamic coastal cities. In 2005, GDP per capita of Xi’an was
only 1/3 that of the two provincial-level cities Beijing and Shanghai, and 1/2 that
of the coastal cities like Qingdao and Hangzhou.
~ 35 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
City
GDP /billion CNY
Population /thousand
GDP per capital/CNY
Beijing
681.45
15380
44308
Shanghai
914.39
17780
51428
Shenyang
208.41
6986
29833
Qingdao
269.58
7409
36385
Wuhan
223.80
8014
27926
Nanjing
241.11
5958
40468
Jinan
187.66
5974
31413
Guangzhou
515.42
7505
68677
Hangzhou
294.27
6605
44553
Ningbo
244.93
5567
43997
Chengdu
237.08
10820
21911
Guiyang
52.56
3507
14987
127.01
8008
15859
Xi’an
Table 4-4: Major indicator comparison among cities
Source: Xi’an statistic yearbook 2006.
Although Xi’an is still behind the development pace of eastern Chinese cities, it
shows substantial growth and great potential after 2000 when China implemented
the new Western Development Program to develop urban areas in the western half
of the country. In the new development scheme, the Xi’an city planning authority
will use a 4-zone-1-base strategy. The four special development zones are
High-tech industry development zone, Economic-tech development zone, Chan-ba
ecological zone, and Qujiang new urban zone. The base is Xi’an aviation base, as
aviation hub of China. In 2005, fixed assets investment in these areas has already
reached 54 billion yuan. These districts will continually promote high-tech
industries, environmental friendly industries and foreign investments. They will be
the mainstream of future economic development of the city. The local government
is very confident about the future prosperity of the city.
~ 36 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
4.3 Social characteristics
Xi’an is one of the birthplaces of Chinese ancient civilization. In 2006, the
registered population was 7.531 million. China’s household registration (also
known as hukou) policy was implemented in the centrally planned economy to
control labor mobility. A person’s residence may be different from his hukou. But
the official statistics still report registered population. The natural population
increase in recent years is between 3‰ to 7‰ (Table 4-5). There is also a large net
immigration every year. Household registration also distinguishes urban hukou
from rural hukou. Urban population is calculated by counting the number of
people who hold urban hukou. This explains why the urban employment is much
more than urban population. Many people who work in the city hold hukou from
rural counties nearby or from other cities.
Item
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Population(registered)/million
6.95
7.03
7.17
7.25
7.42
7.53
Natural increase/‰
3.20
3.23
3.80
3.32
5.94
6.37
Net immigration/thousand
45.9
55.6
113.3
60.2
123.9
66.8
Urban population/million
2.93
3.00
3.13
3.19
3.33
3.44
Urban employment/million
3.89
3.97
4.05
4.10
4.16
4.22
Table 4-5: Demographic feature of Xi’an
Source: Xi’an Statistical Yearbook
Xi’an has been one of the most urbanized cities in China since ancient times. In
1957, the urbanization ratio of Xi’an had already reached 33.94%, exceeding most
prefectures in the country. After 50 years of gradual growth, the urbanization ratio
~ 37 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
increased to 45.6%. Unlike most cities in China, especially in the east and south,
Xi’an did not experience rapid congestion.
The employment structure in Xi’an shows a tendency from agriculture towards the
service sector. Employment in the primary sector keeps decreasing, while
employment in tertiary sector is increasing. Employment in secondary sector
fluctuates slightly in recent years. However, compared to the output GDP, there are
still a substantially large number of farmers producing low value-added products
and living with low income. 32.78% of labor force only generates 5.2% of GDP in
primary sector.
Year
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
6.91
6.24
5.78
5.36
5.46
5.20
37.79
37.27
36.02
36.22
34.62
32.78
Secondary GDP/billion CNY
sector
Employment/%
42.89
42.58
42.77
43.03
43.26
42.48
27.57
27.99
28.10
26.94
27.27
27.46
Tertiary
sector
GDP/billion CNY
50.20
51.18
51.45
51.61
51.28
52.32
Employment/%
34.65
34.74
35.88
36.84
38.11
39.76
Primary
sector
GDP/billion CNY
Employment/%
Table 4-6: Employment situation of Xi’an
Source: Xi’an statistic yearbook 2006.
4.3 Level of infrastructure provision
Local infrastructure is divided into several sectors in Xi’an, including road and
bridges, water supply, gas supply, sewage system and wastewater treatment,
greening, and central heating. Power supply and telecommunication are controlled
and provided by central government, so it is not considered by the city
~ 38 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
government.
In 2005, expenditure on infrastructure provision was 1481 CNY per capital. In the
water sector, water consumption per capita was 147.25L/d, and total water supply
was 357.76 million tons per day. Total length of piping network was 2315km,
which represented 99% level of centrally supply system connection. In road and
transportation sector, the length of road has reached 1382 km in 2005. The total
area of roads and bridges was 3021ha, and area of footpath was 827ha, which
generated an area of road per capita of 8.11m2. The number of mass transit buses
was 4762, which equaled to 1.238 buses per thousand people. In the wastewater
and sewerage system sector, wastewater generation was 232.43 million tons per
day, and the capacity of wastewater treatment plant was 90.35 million tons per day.
Only 38.9% of wastewater generated was appropriately treated before discharge.
Total length of sewerage system was 1618km, which were around two thirds that
of water supply system. In the gas supply sector, level of connection to central gas
system was 91.3%. In the central heat sector, area of central heat supply was
2113ha. In the greening sector, total area of public green space was 1569ha, or
5.63m2 green space per capita.
Compared to other cities in China, infrastructure provision of Xi’an has reached
the average level, in terms of percentage of coverage and amount of investment.
In the Annual Report of Urban Competitiveness of China, Xi’an ranked 33rd in the
200 cities reported. The infrastructure competitiveness of Xi’an was ranked 45th.
~ 39 ~
Chapter 4 Xi’an, the Case City
The report identified the infrastructure provision of Xi’an as “strongly improved,
especially in road and transportation sector”. Indeed, infrastructure provision of
Xi’an has improved greatly since 2000. Many of the indicators, such as length of
road and wastewater treatment capacity, have increased significantly from the
2000 level. In 2000, infrastructure expenditure per capita is only 234 CNY, which
results in infrastructure provision of Xi’an under average level in China. But as
the investment increases, the level of provision has reached an average level
among middle and large cities of China.
~ 40 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
5.1 Centrally planned model in Soviet economy (1949-1978)
5.1.1 Macroeconomic context
China ended its 3000-year-long emperor regime in the early 20th century. After
decades of war, the China Communist Party (CCP) seized power in 1949. In the
first 30 years of its administration, CCP implemented a centrally planned system. In
this system, resources were allocated predominantly according to national strategic
considerations, and implemented through administrative apparatuses. There was no
private sector in the country’s economy. State-owned enterprises (SOEs)
controlled every industry and produced specific products strictly according to
plans, at fixed numbers and fixed prices. The household registration (hukou)
system restricted the mobility of labor. Moreover, it was an extremely isolated
economy. Until economic reform in 1978, China’s export constituted less than 1%
of world trade. It was one of the exceptional economies which had neither
borrowing nor lending, either internationally or domestically, for decades.
Capitalist public finance and budget process did not exist in communist planned
economy, because there was no separation of public and private sectors. The
budget served as an accounting device for implementing planning programs. This
Soviet-type fiscal system drew revenue heavily from profit remittances of SOEs
rather than taxes (Wong, 1997). The central government maintained monopoly on
~ 41 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
tax and profit delivery policies and administrations, while local governments only
acted as subordinate collecting agencies. On the expenditure side, local
governments controlled little over their service programs and the way these
programs were financed. All programs were financed by the central budget
according to dictated instructions of the central planning authority.
After the PRC was founded, Xi’an played a strategically significant role in the
reconstruction of the country. The first and the second 5-year-plans (1952-1957,
1958-1962) of China contained 156 key proposed projects, of which 17 projects
were located in Xi’an. These crucial projects formed the industrial base of the city.
In the 1960s, the central planning authority organized many national defense and
military projects in the city, and many scientific and technological resources were
relocated here. Before the market reform in 1978, the GDP of Xi’an used to stay in
the first 6th in the country, with dominant advantages in several industries.
5.1.2 A centrally planned model
However, economic advances led to neither abundant fiscal revenue nor sufficient
funds for infrastructure finance. In the central-planned economy, nothing
belonged to an individual city or a company. The entire economy nationwide was
pooled together and then broken down again according to central government
dictates. Table 5-1 shows local listed budget incomes and expenditures of Xi’an in
the period.
~ 42 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Year
GDP
Income
1949
189
3.84
1952
337
1957
Expenditure
Income/GDP
/%
Expenditure
/Income /%
2.28
2.03
59.38
52.93
28.54
15.71
53.92
802
148.90
60.73
18.57
40.79
1965
1276
223.23
98.57
17.49
44.16
1970
1776
426.79
120.74
24.03
28.29
1975
2133
555.73
157.12
26.05
28.27
1978
2535
672.67
223.98
26.54
33.30
Table 5-1: Local budget in the centrally planned economy (Unit: million
CNY)
Source: Shaanxi Provincial Statistics Bureau
In the first 20 years, local budgeted income only represents less than 20% of the
local GDP. Most of the resources were directed to industrial expansion, especially
heavy industries and military, following the Soviet model.
The ratio between the budgeted expenditure and the budgeted income is also very
low. Since resources were nationalized and the local budget was only an
accounting device, balance at local level was neither necessitated nor existing.
Revenues were delivered to the central government, pooled, and then allocated
back to finance the planned expenditure. In the case of Xi’an, a large part of its
revenue was used by the central government in financing projects in other parts of
the country. In the 1970s, expenditure only represented 30% of local fiscal
revenue. Therefore, the capacity of infrastructure investment was rather limited.
~ 43 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Figure 5-1: Centrally planned model of infrastructure finance (1949-1978)
Source: author
The channel of infrastructure finance in the Soviet economy from 1949 to 1978 is
summarized in Figure 5-1. In the structure, rectangles represent institutions,
ellipses represent funds, and diamond represents infrastructure projects. In the
model, the local government collects revenues and transfers them to the central
government. According to mandatory planning and required budget appropriation,
the local government receives funds from the central government. Then it carries
out the plan and invests the funds to corresponding infrastructure projects. The
main features of the model are: 1) The role of the central government is more
critical than the local government. The infrastructure projects carried out are
subjected to central planning. 2) The general budget, which is mainly financed by
profit delivery instead of taxes, is the most important source of infrastructure
investment. 3) The investment is treated as ordinary current expenses rather than
~ 44 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
long-term financing activities. The investment is listed on general budget together
with any other current expenditure.
Unfortunately, urban infrastructure was not a favored expenditure area in the
planning agenda. In this period, local fixed assets investment was divided into
productive unit and living (non-productive) unit. Factories and equipment belonged
to the productive unit, and public services including urban infrastructure belonged
to the living unit. With the rule of “producing first, living last”, overwhelming
investments were directed to the productive unit. Table 5-2 shows local GDP,
investments in fixed assets and investments in infrastructure in this period. In the
first 10 years from 1952 to 1962, investment in infrastructure represented only
1-2% of GDP and about 7% of fixed assets investments on average. From 1963,
add-ons of public services, urban industry & commerce surtax, and urban real estate
tax were earmarked to infrastructure investment. However, the stable sources of
funds did not lead to sufficient infrastructure development. Because of the low rate,
problematic way of calculation, and continuous funding rearrangement, the actual
investment in infrastructure stayed at an extraordinarily low level. In 1970, it
reached the bottom at only 0.66% of total fixed assets investment of the city, which
contributed a minimal fraction of 0.07% to local GDP.
~ 45 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Year
GDP
/million
CNY
Infrastructure
investments
/million CNY
Infrastructure
investments/
GDP/%
Fixed assets
investments/
million CNY
Infrastructure
/fixed assets/%
1952
337
5.61
1.66
43.66
12.85
1957
802
18.78
2.34
342.37
5.49
1960
922
14.45
1.57
409.78
3.53
1965
1276
11.67
0.91
204.50
5.71
1970
1776
1.26
0.07
191.18
0.66
1975
2133
9.58
0.45
169.22
5.66
1978
2535
12.28
0.48
272.91
4.50
Table 5-2: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic
development in centrally planned model
Source: Xi’an Local Chronicles
This financing model is built on two bases: the absence of competition and the
special political hierarchy. In the centrally planned economy, government forbade
free competition domestically. As an economically closed country, international
competition did not exist, either. Therefore, there was no incentive to finance
infrastructure to attract business. Moreover, the political hierarchy was less
concerned about democratic issues, so that advanced public infrastructure services
for residents could easily be sacrificed without much political consideration.
5.2 Public finance model in Socialist market economy (1978-2000)
5.2.1 Macroeconomic context
PRC embarked on the “market oriented reform and openness policy” in 1978
towards a “socialist market economy” and “socialism with Chinese characteristics”.
~ 46 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
According to neoclassical economics, ownership does not matter as long as there
is competition. As a result, in the socialistic market reform, the state continually
held ownership of the majority in most sectors, while allowing competition among
all the entities in the market. Price was partially freed up to market forces, and the
economy was increasingly opened up to the outside world. China adopted a
“piecemeal” and pragmatic approach in this reform process, which generated a
mixture of planned economy and market economy. The reform was taken
gradually from coastal areas to inner cities, from large cities to small prefectures,
from commerce to industry, and from the capital market to the fiscal system.
In the transition period, as market exchanges gradually replaced plan directives, the
local government was faced with huge appetites for outlays in infrastructure to lure
business investment, and increased demands to support the growing population and
urban agglomeration. Increased budgetary allocations on infrastructure and new
sources of revenues were pursued to generate more funds for infrastructure
financing. The local government became the major initiator and key actor of the
urban infrastructure finance system in this period. The system includes the
following types of sources, which will be analyzed individually in the following
sections:
•
Local taxes;
•
Administrative fees;
•
Transfers from the central and the provincial government; and
~ 47 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
•
Loans from domestic banks and onlended sovereign debts.
5.2.2 Local taxes
The market reform abandoned the centrally pooled fiscal system and rearranged
the relationship between the central and the local government. Tax distribution
between the central and the local followed a policy of “lumpy fiscal contract”
implemented in 1980, which enhanced local fiscal autonomy substantially,
probably to an excessive extent. In the 1980s and the first half of 1990s, the local
government collected almost all taxes, remitted an agreed amount to higher levels
of governments, and kept the rest for its own. The tax submitted to central
government was on a lump-sum basis instead of proportional sharing. The
disbursement of the rest of the fund was almost fully determined by the local
government.
After the restructuring of the tax systems in 1994, taxes were collected in two
separate channels, namely the local tax system and the central tax system. Tax
revenues of the central government and the local government covered different
areas. Still, the local government drew its funds from broader tax items than many
other countries. The revenues of local government included business tax, income
tax of local state-owned enterprise, personal income tax, tax on the use of urban
land, tax on investment in fixed assets, tax on the use of vehicles and ships, contract
tax, 25% of value added tax, 50% of stamp tax, as well as tax on resources other
than marine petroleum.
~ 48 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
The tax item that is most related to infrastructure finance is the urban construction
&maintenance tax, which was first imposed in 1985 as an earmarked tax to
infrastructure. It was levied on all entities where value added tax and corporate
income tax applied. Along with its imposition, the previous 5% profit delivery
policy1 was abolished. It was an important step of fiscal reform in infrastructure
area, which turned the Soviet “profit delivery” to the new form of “tax payment”.
The urban construction &maintenance tax and add-ons of public utilities dating
back from 1960, became the two main sources of infrastructure funds in the 1980s.
In the 1990s, more administrative fees and other financial sources emerged, but
these two were still the major sources from local fiscal general budget until the
end 1990s. Table 5-3 shows local fiscal contribution to the investment on
infrastructure.
Sources of funds
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP2
Urban construction & maintenance
tax; Add-ons of public utilities
144
191
180
181
195
891
State-owned land assignment
50
61
39
62
230
442
Water resource tax
14
8
9
7
10
48
Other non-earmarked taxes
65
28
20
88
55
256
273
288
248
338
490
1637
Local taxes (total)
Table 5-3: Local fiscal contribution to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit:
million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
1
Before this, 5% of the profits of state-owned enterprises were submitted to sustain urban
infrastructure instead of imposing tax. From 1980s, China launched a variety of “profit
delivery to tax payment” policies for establishing the modern corporate system.
2
9FYP refers to the ninth five-year plan of China, launching from 1996 to 2000.
~ 49 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
In the 9th five-year plan from 1996 to 2000, over half of the allocation to
infrastructure area from local general budget was sourced from the two earmarked
taxes: urban construction &maintenance tax and add-ons of public utilities. Every
year, they were able to provide over 100 million CNY for infrastructure finance.
The water resource tax was earmarked to water supply system finance, and it only
formed a relatively minor fraction. State-owned land assignment was also used,
which will be explained in detail in section 5.3, because it is much further
developed after 2000. Infrastructure was also considered when general budgetary
expenditure was determined, but the amount from the non-earmarked general
budget was rather limited, due to other expenditure priorities.
5.2.3 Fees
Using taxes to finance infrastructure with the tax item, tax base, and tax rate
determined by the central government became insufficient for the local
government in the 1980s. As a result, the local government began to draw its
revenue from various fees, which were applied to much looser control from senior
governments. Xi’an started to levy public facility hookup fee since July 1988.
According to the instructions, all construction, extension, and renovation projects
were subject to the hookup fee to access public infrastructure systems. Different fee
levels, from 25 yuan/m2 to 90 yuan/m2, were applied according to location, land
ownership, and characteristics of the projects. Funds collected were earmarked to
support the financing of infrastructure.
~ 50 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
User charges of tap water, gas, central supplied heat, add-ons of road construction,
vehicle registration fee, and wastewater treatment fee were levied gradually in
1990s. These fees and user charges were not deposited to the general budget
account of the local government. Instead, they were held in separate accounts for
infrastructure finance and management. Table 5-4 shows their contribution to
urban infrastructure finance of the city.
Sources of funds
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP
Local administrative income
445
461
479
515
532
2432
Public facility hookup fee
88
91
111
162
115
567
User charge
64
58
175
187
157
641
Other incomes
293
312
193
166
260
1224
Self-raised funds
20
10
58
66
60
214
Table 5-4: Contribution of fees to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit:
million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
Local administrative income managed by the Fiscal Bureau but deposited to
special accounts was often called “extrabudget”. Self-raised funds were kept in the
account of various governmental agencies and not transferred to the Fiscal Bureau,
and they were sometimes called “extra-extrabudget”. Compared to local general
budget, different service charges and fees constituted a larger proportion of funds
for infrastructure financing. Public facility hookup fee generated about 100 million
CNY each year. User charges grew substantially in 1998 and, from then, exceeded
the hookup fee, mainly because of the imposition of the natural gas fee and the
rise of tap water fee. Other incomes comprised various registration charges,
~ 51 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
permissions, fines, commercial incomes, and facility rents.
5.2.4 Intergovernmental transfers
Before the fiscal reform in the late 1990s, grants from the central government
barely existed. Instead, the flow of revenue was in the opposite direction, in which
the local government transferred “contracted” amounts to the central government.
In public finance theory, intergovernmental transfer ensures equity by using
formulas to determine the amount to be transferred to each locality. However, this
approach was not applied in China. Instead, the central and local governments
signed periodic contracts according to the past expenditure of the local
government and the growth rate of the local tax revenues. This arrangement led to
budget deficit at local level and extensive tax hidden activities, which resulted in a
weak central fiscal capacity. The central government hardly had any capacity to
assist local infrastructure investment.
After the 1994 tax reform, the central government strengthened its fiscal capacity.
As a result, it started to be involved in local infrastructure financing. The
intergovernmental transfer from the central government to the local government
was realized by issuing national bonds. The central government is the only
government authority that can legally issue bonds, and infrastructure was one of
targeted areas for debt financing. Long-term development bond was first issued in
1998, distinct from previous deficit bond, key industry bond, indexed bond, and
special purpose bond. The issuance of this bond was to stimulate economic
~ 52 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
development and to increase domestic demand, even though it “crowds out” other
investments by raising interest rates. The fund raised was specially invested in
infrastructure development across the country. National debt issuances reached
CNY 100 billion in 1998, 110 billion in 1999, and 150 billion in 2000
respectively.
The central government has undertaken two investing mechanisms to utilize bonds
issued through long-term development national debt, namely, direct investment
and national debt on-lent. When using direct investment, the central government
allocates funding directly to specific local infrastructure projects. It is the central
government who bears the national debt repayment in future. Therefore, this
approach acts as a conditional intergovernmental transfer earmarked to special
infrastructure projects. The matching funds at local level are sometimes required,
but seldom happened in the case of Xi’an. In contrast, national debt on-lent is in
fact local debt. The local government claims the amount and the purpose of the
fund. Then it borrows from the central government on the same interest rate and
repayment period as the national debt. The burden of repayment lies with the local
government. Theoretically, the central government has higher credit standings
than the local government, so that national debt on-lent would incur lower cost of
financing than the local government’s own issuance. From central government’s
perspective, it obtains greater macro-economic control over local behaviors. In this
period, onlended national debt was mainly lent to coastal cities which have a
greater fiscal capacity. Most of the national debt allocated to Xi’an was through
~ 53 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
direct investment instead of on-lent.
Besides central transfer, the provincial government sometimes participated in local
infrastructure financing as well. However, funds from the provincial government
were rather limited every year, because the provincial government mainly focused
on cross prefectural infrastructures such as regional highways, railways, and
telecommunications. It would not be involved in any local infrastructure project
unless the project generated substantial direct regional impacts. Table 5-5
illustrates contribution of intergovernmental transfer from the central and the
provincial governments.
Sources of funds
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP
9
36
441
391
170
1047
Central transfer (National debt)
9
8
405
365
150
937
Provincial transfer
0
28
36
26
20
110
Central/Provincial transfer
Table 5-5: Contribution of intergovernmental transfer to infrastructure
finance 1996-2000 (Unit: million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
In the 9th five-year plan, intergovernmental transfer channeled over 1000 million
CNY to infrastructure finance in Xi’an. All of them are project specified transfers,
which belong to the “conditional” category. Over 90% of grants are from the
central government, and the rest (10%) were contributed by Shaanxi Provincial
Government. The disparity of central government investments is clearly seen
before and after the long-term development national debt issuance. In 1996 and
1997, central transfers were only 9 million and 36 million CNY respectively. But
~ 54 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
in 1998, it rocketed up to 441 million CNY. Thereafter, transfers started to
decrease moderately, because of the global recession and “only ongoing projects
would receive more national debt” (People’s Congress, 2000).
5.2.5 Loans
Loans are attractive financing sources because they allow the government to spend
without raising taxes immediately. Concerns regarding local borrowing relate to the
capacity of local governments to eventually repay them from future revenues. Thus,
local governments should be cautious with debt financing, in case they incur
unsustainable deficit or have to raise taxes substantially in the future. With this
consideration, debt financing should be restricted to the profitable infrastructure or
quasi-profitable infrastructure areas that will generate sufficient income streams to
repay the previous investment.
In China, the central government forbids the issuance of municipal bond, so the
local government can only borrow from banks. Bank loans are borrowed solely
from local branches of the four state-owned commercial banks before the
development bank was established in China in 1994. In this period, loans were
mainly used for roads and bridges financing, and were repaid from tolls or vehicle
license fees. Both the loans and the repayments were channeled through accounts
separated from the general local government account. Being inexperienced in debt
recovery and project management, these loans are not well managed. For several
years in the 1990s, governmental agencies had to issue new loans only to repay
~ 55 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
their previous debts. This practice led to a costly remedy from the central
government in the late 1990s. Thereafter, new regulations are introduced to
prevent similar problems in the future.
The China Development Bank (CDB) was established in 1994. The Bank's primary
function was to foster economic development of China through financing of key
projects and initiatives in the government's national economic development plan
and industry policies. In this role, the bank directed its lending activities to
construction and technological renovation projects involving infrastructure
facilities, basic industries and pillar industries in China. Compared to commercial
banks, the interest rate of CDB was lower, and the repayment period was much
longer (see Table 5-6). The repayment could be even longer than national debt
on-lent, which made it suitable for infrastructure investment.
Name of institution
Interest rate /%
Repayment period /year
Grace period/ year
CDB
National debt
on-lent
Commercial bank
5.5-6.5
5-5.5
6-7
5-15
6-10
≤10
--
2
--
Table 5-6: Interest rate and repayment period of domestic loans
Source: CDB website, “Guidelines of national debt on-lent management”.
Sovereign debt is issued to the central government from multilateral development
banks (MDB)1 and other countries, with repayment guaranteed by the central
1
A multilateral development bank (MDB) is an institution, created by a group of
countries that provides financing and professional advising for the purpose of
development. MDBs have large memberships including both developed donor countries
and developing borrower countries. MDBs finance projects in the form of long-term loans
~ 56 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
fiscal revenue. In financing the development of Xi’an, the World Bank (WB),
Asian Development Bank (ADB), and Japan Bank for International Cooperation
(JBIC) are the major international actors. Since 1981, the International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) and the International Development
Association (IDA) had provided loans to China. While the IBRD provides loans
with a relatively low interest rate (comparable to LIBOR), the IDA’s "credits" are
interest-free. In 1999, China graduated from IDA – the institution that provides
loans to the poorest countries, and was only qualified to receive IBRD loans (Hu
and Hu, 2005). ADB started to provide loans to China’s projects after PRC
officially joined in ADB in 1986. Compared to WB, ADB had a clearer investment
emphasis on agriculture and transportation infrastructure. JBIC is a Japanese
governmental financial aid institution. The loans it provided to China projects are
mainly in the environmental related area, and are usually combined with
compulsory technical equipment purchase and training programs from Japan.
Table 5-7 illustrates terms and conditions of these international sovereign loans.
Name of institution
Interest rate /%
Repayment period/year
Grace period/ year
WB
ADB
JBIC
floating, 1-6
Floating, around 5
Before 1998: 2.1
Hard loan: 20
Soft loan: 35-40
10-30
Before 1998: 30
After 1998: 40
5
--
10
Table 5-7: Term and conditions of sovereign loans
Source: WB, ADB, JBIC official website
at market rates, very-long term loans (also known as credits) below market rates, and
through grants.
~ 57 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
The financial cost of the sovereign loans is less than that of domestic loans. Low
amortization is another advantage of sovereign loans, since these loans normally
have an unusually long repayment period and grace period. A disadvantage of
sovereign loans is that they are quite unstable and limited, because many cities are
waiting in line for such loans. Besides, local governments in China are unfamiliar
with the documentation the sovereign loans required. Moreover, there is always
exchange rate risk inherent with international debts, if they are denominated in
different currencies. In the 9th five-year plan, contribution of loans to
infrastructure finance in Xi’an is shown in Table 5-8. In 1999, loans dwindled
because of default. The loans recovered after stricter measures were imposed.
Sources of funds
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP
Domestic bank loans
108
65
198
10
204
585
50
145
227
0
74
496
Sovereign loans on-lent
Table 5-8: Contribution of loans to infrastructure finance 1996-2000 (Unit:
million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
5.2.6 A public finance model
Along with the termination of the old Soviet economy, centrally planned model
soon became ineffective as a tool for infrastructure finance in Xi’an. A public
finance model was gradually introduced. In this model, the local government
became the essential initiator of infrastructure projects. The structure of this public
finance model adopted between 1978 and 2000 is summarized in Figure 5-2.
~ 58 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Figure 5-2: Public finance model of infrastructure finance (1978-2000)
Source: author
Compared to the centrally planned model, financial instruments were more
complex in this period. Local fiscal system was created; public services and
administrations were charged; and loans from home and abroad were used. In this
model, the local government financed infrastructure through general local budget,
extrabudget, intergovernmental transfers, self-raised funds at local governmental
agencies, domestic loans, and on-lent sovereign loans. General budget allocation
was sourced from earmarked and general taxes. Extra-budget allocation was
supported by administrative fees including user changes. Self-raised funds were
provided by revenues of the local departmental agencies. Intergovernmental
transfers were both offered by the central government through national debt
issuance and by the provincial government through the provincial budget.
~ 59 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Domestic loans were borrowed from state-owned commercial banks and
development banks. International loans were on-lent by central government from
its sovereign loans borrowed from international development institutions.
Before 1990s, total infrastructure investment of Xi’an in the 42 years from 1949 to
1990 was only 1297 million yuan. This amount is less than infrastructure
investment in a single year of 1998, 1999, or 2000. This inadequate fiscal capacity
led to a large gap between development demand and infrastructure provision. It was
not uncommon that potential business investments from outside the region were
not realized because of inadequate urban infrastructure.
2000
million CNY
1600
1200
800
400
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
Year
Figure 5-3: Infrastructure investment in Xi’an (1996-2000)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
During the 1990s, Xi’an speeded up its infrastructure development. Figure 5-3
shows total investment in infrastructure annually from 1996 to 2000. The total
investment in the five years reached 6,812 million, or about 1,150 million yuan per
year on average. Investments in 1998, 1999, and 2000 were more than those in the
~ 60 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
earlier two years, mainly because of the increase of national debt transfer in urban
infrastructure.
7.3%
8.6%
Intergovernmental
transfers
Local general budget
15.4%
3.0%
Local administrative
income
Other sources
6.0%
24.0%
Self‐raised funds
Domestic bank loans
35.7%
Sovereign loans
Figure 5-4: Sources of funds of infrastructure finance structure in Xi’an
(1996-2000)
Source: see Appendix B
Financing structure
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
1996
1997
Year
1998
Intergovernmental transfers
Local administrative income
Self‐raised funds
Sovereign loans
1999
2000
Local general budget
Other sources
Domestic bank loans
Figure 5-5: Trends of infrastructure finance composition in Xi’an (1996-2000)
Source: see Appendix B
Figure 5-4 and Figure 5-5 illustrate the contributions of various sources in
~ 61 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
infrastructure finance from 1996 to 2000 and their variation in different years.
Funds from higher tiers of governments constituted 15.4% of the total investment,
and their contributions were volatile. In 1996 and 1997, their investments were
less than 5%, followed by a considerable increase to approximately 25% in 1998
and 1999, and then a plunge to around 10% again. The general local budget, local
administrative incomes from extrabudget, and self-raised funds from local bureau
accounts, formed 24.0%, 35.7%, and 3% of the total financing sources,
respectively. Fiscal and administrative revenues at local level stayed as the
mainstay of infrastructure financing, representing over 50% of financing sources
except in 1998 when central investment grew substantially. Domestic loans and
sovereign loans constituted 8.6% and 7.3% of the total finance amount. In 1999,
few bank loans were issued from home and abroad. Other than 1999, loans
represented 20% of finance sources every year, but the ratio between domestic
loans and international loans still varied extensively. In various sources,
administrative fees raised by local government ranked the first in its contribution
to infrastructure finance. Detailed numbers of each source and their annual
variation are shown in Appendix A.
From the expenditure side, 5.9% of the investment was used for office overhead and
salary of the management team. 11.5% of the fund was used for maintenance of
existing projects. 0.5% was spent in the preparation stage of the project. The
remaining shares were spent on infrastructure projects of road and bridges, water
supply, gas supply, wastewater treatment, greening, sewage system, and central
~ 62 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
heating (Details are presented in Appendix B).
Increased local revenue fostered the rapid growth of infrastructure stock. However,
infrastructure construction was still below the rate that was believed to be
necessary to sustain its regional growth. Table 5-9 shows infrastructure
investments as percentage of local GDP.
Year
Local GDP /million Infrastructure investments Infrastructure investments
CNY
/million CNY
as percentage of GDP/%
1980
3166
29
0.91
1983
3589
43
1.20
1984
4414
56
1.26
1985
5758
72
1.25
1986
6578
124
1.88
1987
8016
122
1.52
1988
9922
129
1.30
1989
10938
166
1.52
1990
11651
150
1.29
1996
40695
966
2.37
1997
48882
1075
2.20
1998
52585
1746
3.32
1999
57729
1412
2.45
2000
64613
1613
2.50
Table 5-9: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic
development 1980-2000
Source: Xi’an Local Chronicles
In 1980, it only represented 0.91% of the gross GDP. Although the percentage has
increased to 1%-2% in the 1980s and 2%-3% in the last five years, it was still
below the recommended level of 4% for developing countries (World Bank, 1994).
In fact, infrastructure construction mainly responds to bottlenecks, as rapid growth
~ 63 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
quickly outstripped the capacity of existing facilities. Therefore, new project
finance mechanisms are needed to mobilize more resources in the new century.
5.3 Public corporation model in a marketized economy (2000- )
The new century ushered in a new stage of infrastructure financing in Xi’an for
several reasons. The first justification is China’s entry into the World Trade
Organization (WTO) at national level in 2001; the second is the central
government’s new Western Development strategy at regional level; and the third is
the responsibility transfer to Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG) at local
level.
5.3.1 Macroeconomic context
China’s entry into the World Trade Organization is a significant step in its
economic transformation in the new century. According to the terms of Agreement,
China would regulate its various sectors according to international standards and
open them up to foreign and domestic private investors. The sectors included
finance, water, and transportation, which were crucial to infrastructure finance.
The changes paved an accessible way for project financing and private
participation in economic activities.
The Western1 Development Program commenced operation in Jan. 2000 under the
1
The Western China comprises 12 provincial districts, with a total area of 6850 km2.
Shaanxi Province, where Xi’an is located in, locates in the east part of this region.
~ 64 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
leadership of then-Premier Zhu Rongji. The objective of this program is to
minimize the imbalance of development between coastal regions of eastern China
and the western inner half. Xi’an, located at the entrance from the east to the west,
is in a leading role in this new development scheme. The main components of the
program strategy are:
•
development of infrastructure, especially transport, water supply, energy, and
telecommunication;
•
enticement of foreign investment with new approaches and mechanisms;
•
increased efforts on ecological protection such as reforestation; and
•
promotion of education and retention of talented people from flowing to
richer coastal regions.
Previous market reform emphasized development in southeast part of China
because of its geographic advantage and suitable industrial structure. Natural
resources from western China were used to support the development of the east,
especially the coastal cities. After 20 years of development, a large regional
disparity existed between the east and the west. Under the new development
scheme, many national policies favored the western regions. Concessional
taxation, national debt transfers, central budget investments, and cooperation with
multilateral banks all gave priority to western localities.
~ 65 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
5.3.2 Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG)
Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG) was founded in Jul. 2000. In 2005,
the local government transferred the ownership of 15 entities in the public areas to
XIIG, including water supply, gas supply, heat supply, wastewater treatment, public
transport and toll roads. Currently, XIIG is a fully state-owned company owned by
Xi’an People’s Government, with a registration capital of 8.5 billion CNY. The
function of XIIG is to develop infrastructure as an “agent” of the local government.
It is responsible for all infrastructure provision, from financing to construction,
operation, and management. It is the legal entity for public infrastructure projects,
responsible for fund raising, allocating, auditing, and debt repayment. It also
mobilizes and manages related state-owned assets under the authorization of the
city government.
XIIG fully owns 11 subordinate companies and 3 other entities. The 11 subordinate
companies are Xi’an Natural Gas Company, Xi’an Heat Supply Company, Xi’an
Water Supply Company, Xi’an Taxi Company, Xi’an Public Transit Company,
Xi’an Infrastructure Construction Company, Xi’an Third-ring Road Development
Company, Xi’an Elevated Expressway Company, Xi’an Wastewater Treatment
Plant, Xi’an Bei-shi-qiao Wastewater Treatment Center, Xi’an 3rd &4th Wastewater
Treatment Plant Preparation Office. The other three non-company entities are
Second-ring Road Construction Headquarter, Xiao-yan Pagoda Historical Park,
and Municipal Sewage System. The subordinate companies are all transformed
~ 66 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
into public corporations from previous public agencies. The comprehensive
organizational chart of the Group is shown in Appendix C.
Some of the subordinate companies are sectional companies with franchises to
operate certain natural monopoly infrastructure areas, such as tap water supply,
and public transit. Some subordinate companies are project companies, such as
Third-ring Road Development Company, Xi’an Elevated Expressway Company,
and Xi’an Bei-shi-qiao Wastewater Treatment Center. These projects are all
constructed using project finance. XIIG acts as the sponsor of these projects, and
onlends some low-cost government debts to them. The project companies may
draw capital from other resources or borrow from commercial banks.
5.3.3 Local revenues and transfers to XIIG
The distinctive features of local fiscal contribution to infrastructure finance are the
inclusion of administrative fees in general budget, the popularity of land
assignment, and the transfer of fiscal revenues directly to XIIG.
Many fees, instead of user charges for service consumption, were levied on
various “permits” and “authorizations”. The items were determined by the local
government and associated agencies. The exact size, source and distribution of
these funds were difficult to identify and regulate. The central authorities have
tried to regulate these fees several times in 1996 and 2001 to restrict the list of fee
items and bring them in the formal revenue-reporting system. Local governments
~ 67 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
in China were asked to include the administrative fees into the general budget
gradually from 2002. Until 2008, Xi’an has adjusted most administrative fee items
from the extrabudget to the general budget. These items include registration fees,
various add-ons, and fines. At the same time, user charges of water, gas and other
public services are separated from administrative fees and are managed by
individual public corporations. Wastewater treatment fee is shared between
wastewater treatment center and the local general budget, because currently
sewage system does not belong to any public corporation.
In order to improve management of state-owned land, strengthen land
administration and promote urban development, the Chinese government
implemented a law to regulate the right of state-owned land assignment and transfer
in 1990s. According to the law, ownership is separated from the using right of the
land. Therefore, the right to use state-owned land in urban areas could be assigned
and transferred, with the exclusion of the underground resources. The State as the
owner of the land assigns the right of using the land within the term of a certain
number of years to land users who shall in turn pay fees for the assignment thereof
to the Sate (State Council of PRC, 1994). The assignment may be carried out by
reaching an agreement, by invitation to bid or by auction. The revenues are
earmarked to develop urban infrastructure. In the 9FYP, Xi’an government only
assigned 1667 ha of state-owned land, generating a revenue of 422 million CNY.
After 2000, state-owned land assignment became a significant source of revenue
for infrastructure financing. Table 5-10 shows state-owned land assignment by the
~ 68 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
city government from 2001 to 2005.
Item
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
Land assigned/item
202
383
388
482
312
Agreement
200
376
358
416
241
Tender
0
0
1
0
0
Auction
2
7
7
6
8
Listed transaction
0
0
22
60
63
Total area assigned/ha
3115
1032
1367
1997
986
Total revenue/mil. CNY
384
1275
1496
1444
890
Table 5-10: State-owned land assignment of Xi’an 2001-2005
Source: 2006 Xi’an statistic year book
In the 10th five-year plan from 2001 to 2005, this revenue source expanded to
5,489 million yuan, more than 10 times of that in the 9th five-year plan. Local
governments “create” marketable land by expanding urban boundaries at the rural
fringe to provide land suitable for assignment. From 2006, the importance of land
assignment started to decrease again, because of the decline in the supply of land
available and stricter national regulation on land assignment.
The city government transfers revenues from vehicle passage fee1, assignment of
state-owned land, wastewater treatment, and outdoor media advertisement to XIIG.
These incomes are used to fund infrastructure projects (see Table 5-11). The
subordinate companies earn revenues from their operation of toll roads, heating
system, natural gas supply, mass transit, and tap water supply, and so on. These
revenues are used to cover the capital costs and to finance system expansions and
1
Vehicle charging policy was suspended in 2003, but resumed from 2008. It is levied on
vehicles registered in other cities.
~ 69 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
renovations.
Types of revenue
2003
2004
2005
2006
Wastewater treatment fee
55.71
67.69
132.59
154.49
State-owned land assignment
621.56
767.00
741.65
701.67
Outdoor media advertisement
16.77
18.45
19.37
20.07
694.04
853.14
893.61
876.23
Total
Table 5-11: Transfer of local government revenue to XIIG (Unit: million CNY)
Source: 2007 short term financing bills publication instruction
100%
89.90%
89.56%
83.29% 82.99%
80%
53.13%
60%
40%
41.56%
20%
0%
2003
2004
2005
XIIG's revenue from land assignment/Revenue from land assignment
XIIG's revenue from land assignment/XIIG's total revenue from the local
government
Figure 5-6: Importance of revenue from land assignment for XIIG
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
Among the three main revenue items transferred, land assignment is the most
significant one, which is illustrated in Figure 5-6. As promised by the local
government, an increasing percentage of revenues from state-owned land
assignment were transferred to XIIG, from 41.56% in 2003 to 83.29% in 2005. At
the same time, this is the predominant revenue source for XIIG, which constitutes
over 80% of its total revenue.
~ 70 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Table 5-12 illustrates the contribution of local fiscal revenue to infrastructure from
2001 to 2007. State-owned land assignment revenues and some revenues under
the “other income” category are transferred to XIIG, user charges are managed by
various public corporations, and the others are direct local budgetary investments.
Source of funds
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Urban construction & maintenance
tax; Add-ons of public utilities
280
360
433
498
627
865
830
98
76
59
90
164
128
138
State-owned land assignment
384
1275
1496
1444
890
702
837
Public facility hookup fee
188
217
255
240
514
578
489
Other incomes
120
130
161
218
660
630
410
User charges
324
357
401
584
632
772
837
Non-earmarked taxes
Table 5-12: Contribution of local fiscal revenue to infrastructure finance
2001-2007 (Unit: million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
Compared to the 9th five-year plan, fiscal revenue investment in infrastructure
increased considerably. The expansion of urban area and new development
projects led to the increase of tax and add-ons. The boom of land assignment
created a new major source of funds for infrastructure investment. In 2005,
equivalent infrastructure hookup fee replaced the public facility hookup fee. The
new regulation adjusted the fee levels to 150 yuan/m2. Other incomes increased
along with the economic development as well. Outdoor media advertisement
income increased quickly. Vehicle registration fee also increased substantially
because of the growth of population and incomes.
Natural gas, wastewater treatment and centralized winter heating system were
~ 71 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
added to charged public infrastructure services after 2000. The systems keep
expanding, and the standard prices of user charges also have increased several
times. For example, more districts are now connected to centralized wastewater
treatment system and heating system, and they are subject to these charges.
Wastewater treatment income has been increasing at 20%~40% per year in the
recent 5 years. Water fee was adjusted in 2004 and 2007, and the prices were
raised by about 20% on average each time. Toll roads have also generated
substantial income after the construction of third ring road in 2004.
5.3.4 Intergovernmental transfers
Intergovernmental transfers in this period continued to be in the form of
conditional grants from the central and provincial governments. The central
government continues to issue long-term development national debt, which started
from 1998 under China’s “active fiscal policy”, to support basic capital
investments nationwide. However, under the new “prudent fiscal policy” since
2002, the central government has reduced the amount of the bond issuance
substantially, at the rate of 10-50 billions every year. In 2008, it declined to only
30 billion CNY, 1/5 of the amount in 2002. To partially compensate for the gap
caused by the fall in national debt issuance, the central government with increased
fiscal resources has, since 2003, allocated part of its general budget to local
infrastructure investments. The amount of general budgetary investment grew
every year and exceeded the amount of national debt in 2007. The amount of
~ 72 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
long-term development national debt and general budgetary investment are shown
in Table 5-13. It should be noted that the data are not investments to Xi’an city but
to infrastructure projects nationwide.
Year
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Long-term development
national debt
150
150
140
110
80
60
50
30
Central general budgetary
investment
0
0
30
35
45
55
80
122
150
150
170
145
125
115
130
152
Total
Table 5-13: National debt issuance and central budgetary investment in
infrastructure 2001-2008 (Unit: billion CNY)
Source: Government Work Report 1998~2008 (published annually)
The distribution of central government transfer after 2000 differs from the
previous years. With the implementation of Western Development program,
national debt prefers to invest in projects in western regions in terms of amount
and approval criteria. According to the Government Work Report (GWR) 2001, all
national
debt
investments
in
Western
projects
are
categorized
as
intergovernmental transfer, while investments in other parts are mixtures of
transfer and on-lent. In 2002, the Report underscores that all national debt
transfers to Western projects do not require matching funds locally. However,
western cities did not enjoy a large fund increase, because national transfer also
prioritized rural development, cross regional mega projects, and projects in
progress.
~ 73 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Source of funds
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
79
180
220
382
461
410
354
National transfer
69
170
200
310
346
186
187
Provincial transfer
10
10
20
72
115
224
167
Central/Provincial transfer
Table 5-14: Contribution of intergovernmental transfer to infrastructure
finance 2001-2007 (Unit: million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
Table 5-14 shows the funds received by Xi’an government from the central and
the provincial government to finance infrastructure. It can be seen that national
transfer reached the bottom in 2001 and then increased from 2001 to 2005,
followed by a sharp decrease afterwards to the level of 150-200 million CNY now.
The Western Development Program did benefit Xi’an in several years, but more
and more national funds are directed away to the surrounding poor regions in the
province. In contrast, the provincial government contributed more to the
infrastructure finance in recent years. It is mainly because of the expansion of the
city, which enclosed more public provincial lands within Xi’an jurisdiction.
Besides, national investment partially relieved the poverty reduction liability of
the provincial government, so that it was willing to support key projects in the
city1.
5.3.5 Loans
One of the features in infrastructure financing after 2000 is bond issuance.
1
The provincial government transfers 150 million/year to XIIG to support the subway
system development from 2006. It is the major target project of provincial transfer
currently.
~ 74 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Although local/municipal bond is proscribed in China, corporate bond is allowed.
Therefore, the establishment of XIIG paved a way for bond financing. The
composition of various public corporations, the ownership transfer of these
corporations to XIIG, and the contracted revenue transfers from the local
government further qualified XIIG for bond issuance, which required certain asset
and profitability criteria.
XIIG started to use bond financing since 2007. By the end of Sep. 2008, it has
issued one short-term bill and one long-term bond. The short-term financing bill
was issued in Sep. 2007, with an interest rate of 4.57%. The issuing scale was 800
million CNY, and the repayment period was 365 days. Previously, short term funds
were borrowed from commercial banks, which incurred higher financing costs (see
section 5.2.5).
In 2008, XIIG issued its first long-term corporate bond. A fixed discount rate of
6.7% with 5-year repayment period was used. The interest was paid annually; while
the principal would be paid at the end. The total amount issued was 1.5 billion CNY.
All funds raised would be used in the three infrastructure projects shown in Table
5-15. All the three projects, which were initiated in the recent five years, used
diversified financing sources in the design of their project finances. The Xi’an
urban transport project was a joint effort of XIIG and ADB, and the Xi’an
environmental project acquired half of its total funding from Japanese loans. They
are pioneer projects in terms of financing mechanisms for the local government
~ 75 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
and XIIG.
Project
Total
General
budget
Bond
Bank
loans
Self-raised
fund
Xi’an 3rd-ring road project
6.258
2.321
0.700
3.237
0
Xi’an environmental project
3.141
0.979
0.700
1.462
0
Taihua centralized heating system
0.327
0
0.100
0.129
0.098
Total
9.726
3.300
1.500
4.828
0.098
Table 5-15: Projects listed on bond issuance instruction (Unit: million CNY)
Source: 2008 long-term corporate bond publication instruction
Before the issuance of XIIG bond, the local government has already agreed to build
a special reserve to guarantee of the bonds and other loans borrowed by XIIG for
the purpose of financing infrastructure. The debt will be repaid by future revenues
of XIIG. But if XIIG fails to fulfill its payment obligation, it will receive fund
transfer from the reserve built by the local government for the due debts. The local
government guarantees increased the credit rating of the XIIG bond, which
yielded a relatively low interest rate.
Domestic loans in this period are mainly government credit loans from China
Development Bank. From 2003-2007, debts from China Development Bank
reached 6,000 million CNY. In the next 5 years from 2008, debts will be 21,188
million CNY. In 2005, there are 100 million CNY national debt on-lent included
in domestic loans. The local government and XIIG rarely borrow directly from
commercial banks in this period. But when project finance is employed,
commercial loans are borrowed by the SPVs based on the profitability of the
specific project.
~ 76 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Onlended sovereign loans increased extensively in the new century. The Xi’an
Comprehensive Urban Transportation System Improvement Project1 is the first
World Bank project in infrastructure area in Xi’an, which acquired 150 million
USD to the finance of urban infrastructure. Other active international partners
include ADB, JBIC, the Spanish government, and so on. Table 5-16 shows various
types of loans involved in infrastructure finance of Xi’an in this period.
Source of funds
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Domestic bank loans
747
990
1620
3000
3960
2110
1420
Sovereign loans
110
0
320
520
920
1360
1150
Corporate bonds
0
0
0
0
0
0
1300
Table 5-16: Contribution of loans in infrastructure finance 2001-2007 (Unit:
million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
5.3.6 Private participation
Xi’an also started to adopt public private partnership arrangements after 2000.
Being politically sensitive about the term “privatization”, China used the word
“marketization” to describe the trends of mobilizing capitals from private sector to
finance infrastructure. Similarly, it used the term “social sector”, “social
resources” to substitute the words related to “private”. The first step of
marketization is the land assignment, which appeared in the end of 1990s.
Entering the 21st century, Xi’an also started other forms of marketization reforms.
1
Total investment is 2,975 million CNY. The project commences in 2008 and will finish
in 2012.
~ 77 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
In 2001, an “Instruction of promoting and assisting social capital investment” was
released by the central government. This guideline stated that the government
encouraged and would assist private participation in the area of infrastructure
construction and public welfare, in the forms of CJV (contractual joint venture),
EJV (equity joint venture), WOS (wholly-owned subsidiary), and concessional
franchised operation. In 2002, the central government published report titled
“Index of industries for foreign investments”. In this report, areas like gas, heat,
water supply, and sewer system, which were regulated to prohibit private and
foreign participation, are now open to competition. In 2004, the central
government further endorsed preferential tax treatment and specific measures to
promote private participation. The methods being experimentally used in Xi’an
are equity joint venture (EJV) and Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) franchise
arrangements.
Natural gas is the first area experimenting joint venture operation between a
public and a private corporation. Xi’an Gas Supply Company was founded in
1994, with registered assets of 524 million CNY and a total asset of 1,605 million
CNY in 2005. It operated the natural gas supply system for Xi’an, with pipeline
network of more than 2000 km. Ratified by Xi’an People’s Government and
National Asset Supervision &Management Commission, XIIG started to launch the
reform of this subsidiary company in 2005. The private investor is the Hong Kong
and China Gas Company Limited (Towngas). It is the first public utility company
in Hong Kong, founded in 1862, with a pipeline network of over 3000 km. Its core
~ 78 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
business comprises the production and distribution of gas, the marketing of gas
and appliances and comprehensive after-sale services. Cooperating with Towngas,
a new joint venture company with 1.6 billion CNY registered assets was set up in
2006, named Xi’an Qin-hua Natural Gas Supply Company. Xi’an Gas Supply
Company owns 51% of the stock and Towngas has 49% of the ownership. The city
government guaranteed a franchise right of gas supply to the company, and the
company should carry out their activities and service provisions under “Franchise
Operation Agreement” and related regulations. The privatization brought 540
million up-front funds for natural gas infrastructure finance.
After the successful operation of marketization of natural gas sector, XIIG turned
its efforts to the water supply area. It published an announcement inviting
investment from domestic and oversea capital markets to Xi’an Water Supply
Company. The company was founded in 1952, with registered capital of 411.8
million CNY, and is fully owned by XIIG. Its main business is urban tap water
production, supply, as well as piping network design and construction. In 2006,
water sales of the company were 250 million m3, generating a revenue of 500
million CNY and a profit of 15.85 million CNY. The amount of investment
required was determined by net assets of current water company and the funds
needed in the new water supply system extension and renovation projects. A joint
venture company will be similarly set up, with XIIG accounting for 51% of stock
ownership and the investor for 49%. The city government guarantees a franchise
right of tap water supply to the company. This deal is still in process.
~ 79 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
BOT is a form of project financing where a private entity receives a concession
from the private or public sector to finance, design, construct, and operate a
facility for a specified period, usually about 20-30 years. After the concession
period, control is transferred back to the granting entity. During the concession,
the project proponent is allowed to charge tolls, fees, and rentals subject to
approval. This enables the project proponent to recover its investment, operation
and maintenance expenses in the project. There is no successful experience of
BOT transaction in Xi’an yet, but the local government and XIIG are strongly
promoting this arrangement.
In 2007, Xi’an Elevated Expressway Company – another subsidiary company of
XIIG – published BOT invitation for the second stage of Xi’an Expressway
Project. The project is the toll road system around the urban area which connects
to the airport. The first stage of this project has been completed in 2004 with a
total investment of 979 million CNY, including 360 million in bank loans. It is
now being operated by Xi’an Elevated Expressway Company, who draws
revenues from tolls, gas station operation, and adjacent land development. The
second stage of this project is estimated at a cost of 1958 million CNY. XIIG is
looking for investors who are willing to finance and operate the second stage of
the project in the form of Build-Operate-Transfer on a long-term basis. Another
option that investors can choose is to purchase the right to operate the first stage
of the project for certain years, and then transfer it back to the government, which
is actually a Transfer-Operate-Transfer (TOT) contract. With the funds paid by the
~ 80 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
investor for operation right purchasing, the public corporation will be able to
finance the second stage by itself1. In 2008, the wastewater area also started to
invite BOT investments. The companies involved in are Xi’an Wastewater
Treatment Plant, Xi’an Bei-shi-qiao Wastewater Treatment Center, and Xi’an 3rd
&4th Wastewater Treatment Plant Preparation Office.
5.3.7 Special districts and self-raised funds
Most administrative and service charges at local agencies have been regulated
through general fiscal budget, but the “self-raised funds” still contribute to the
urban infrastructure finance. The concept of the term has changed, because
sub-prefectural level entities are granted substantial fiscal capacity in the new
century. It now refers to funds raised by the county level governments and special
district management committees.
Following a further decentralized process, some fiscal power was transferred to
the county level. When infrastructure is located in its jurisdiction, the county is
responsible for financing it collaboratively. “County self-raised funds” refers to
the contribution of infrastructure financing at the county government level.
Special development districts (see Chapter 4.2) were founded after 2000 in the
expanded urban area. Management committees were established to manage the
development of the districts. They attract economic investments and provide
1
The project is also open to joint venture finance for the second stage.
~ 81 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
infrastructure for business investors. The committees raise funds mainly by
assigning using right of lands in the new urban area within the districts. They also
collect hookup fees and other administrative charges in the districts. “Special
district self-raised funds” are used to finance infrastructure within these districts.
Table 5-17 shows self-raised fund at the county level and special district to finance
infrastructure. The remarkable increase in 2003 is mainly due to the setup of Xi’an
Economic & Technological Development District.
Source of funds
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Self-raised funds
133
55
2225
2447
2156
2800
2964
106
0
1183
1301
1131
1700
1980
27
55
1042
1146
1025
1100
984
Special district self-raised funds
County Self-raised funds
Table 5-17: Contribution of self-raised funds to infrastructure finance
2001-2008 (Unit: million CNY)
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
5.3.8 A public corporation model
The rapid economic development of China and the new scheme of inner land
development policy changed the economic context of urban infrastructure
provision. The acute financing problem forced the local government to pursue
new mechanisms in the newly developed socialist market economy, which
encourages international competition and private participation. As a result, the
public sector corporatized itself and invited private partners in infrastructure
delivery. By using both public finance and project finance, a new model of
infrastructure finance – the public corporation model – has evolved from the
~ 82 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
public finance model. XIIG, the public corporation, became the key initiator in this
model. The structure of the public corporation model employed after 2000 is
summarized in the Figure 5-7.
Figure 5-7: Public corporation model of infrastructure finance (after 2000)
Source: author
Compared to the public finance model, financial instruments are further
diversified in the public corporation model. XIIG is founded as the agent company
of the local government to finance infrastructure. It receives revenue transfers
from the local government, obtains on-lent concessional loans with the repayment
guarantee of the local government, raises capital to build SPVs, enters into joint
ventures or BOT franchise agreements with private companies for infrastructure
~ 83 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
development, and oversees the services delivered by the infrastructure assets it
owns. China Development Bank loans, on-lent national debts, on-lent sovereign
loans will be provided only to XIIG, while commercial loans are lent to project
SPV directly. The local government also invests in infrastructure projects directly
and obtains intergovernmental transfers from higher levels of governments.
Repayment reserve is set up to assist XIIG with on time by payment of various
loans.
12000
10000
million CNY
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
Year
Figure 5-8: Scale of funds for infrastructure financing in Xi’an (2001-2007)
Source: see Appendix D
As a result of the enhanced fiscal capacity of the local government as well as the
diversified financing sources introduced, the scale of funds for infrastructure
finance has increased dramatically after 2000 (Figure 5-8). From 2001 to 2005, the
total amount grew from 2,463 million to 10,985 million yuan. After that, the
amount of funding stayed at around 10,000 million in 2006 and 2007.
~ 84 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
8.0%
2.4% 3.8%
Intergovernmental
transfers
Local general budget
14.9%
User charges
7.1%
25.3%
State‐owned land
assignment
Private capitals
Self‐raised funds
Domestic bank loans
12.8%
2.4%
23.3%
Sovereign loans
Bonds
Figure 5-9: Sources of funds of infrastructure finance structure in Xi’an
(2001-2007)
Source: see Appendix D
Financing structure
100%
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
Year
Intergovernmental transfers
Local general budget
State‐owned land assignment
User charges
Private capitals
Self‐raised funds
Domestic bank loans
Sovereign loans
2007
Figure 5-10:Trends of infrastructure finance composition in Xi’an (2001-2007)
Source: see Appendix D
Figures 5-9 and 5-10 illustrate the sources of funds that are used in infrastructure
finance in the period from 2001 to 2007 and their respective changing patterns.
Compared with the year from 1996 to 2000 in Figure 5-4, the composition of
~ 85 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
infrastructure finance has changed. Bonds and private capitals appear; and user
charges and state-owned land assignment are separated from general fiscal
revenue as outstanding sources. Self-raised funds from special districts and county
levels form 23.3% of the total funds, showing an exceptional strong financial
autonomy at sub-prefectural level after 2003. Combining taxes and administrative
fees together, local general budget is responsible for only 14.9% of the funds,
which is especially low in the year 2003, 2004, and 2005. State-owned land
assignment controlled by XIIG represents 12.8% of the total funds, while user
charges controlled by other public corporations represent 7.1% of the total.
Intergovernmental transfers only accounts for 3.8% of the funds, with an
increasing share from the provincial government. The sharp decrease of
intergovernmental transfer in this period is replaced by the strong increase of debt
financing. Domestic loans and sovereign loans represent 25.3% and 8% of the
total, respectively. Private capital involvement and bond financing form a small
proportion of 2.4% and 2.4%, because they have just emerged since 2005 and
2007. Detailed numbers of each source is recorded in Appendix D.
Adopting the public corporation model, infrastructure investments increased
rapidly, as is seen in Table 5-18. Compared with the previous 2%-3% in the public
finance model, the level of investment has reached 6%-8%, achieving the rate of
7%-11% that found in developed countries (World Bank, 1994).
~ 86 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Year
GDP/million CNY
Infrastructure investments Infrastructure investments
/million CNY
as percentage of GDP/%
2001
73486
2463
3.35
2002
82668
3640
4.40
2003
94666
7190
7.59
2004
110239
9422
8.55
2005
127014
10985
8.69
2006
147370
10355
7.03
2007
173710
10729
6.18
Table 5-18: Level of infrastructure investment compared to economic
development 2001-2007
Source: author
The achievements can also be reflected from the increased level of infrastructure
provision. Table 5-19 shows infrastructure provision conditions in terms of gas
supply, water supply, central heat supply, roads, public transit, wastewater and
solid waste in year 1949, 1978, 1990, 2000 and 2005. For example, the length of
urban roads increased 371 km from 1990 to 2000, and further increased 407 km in
the following five years. Along with the increase of roads, the number of public
buses rose by about 1,700 and 2,200 in the respective periods. In 1990, the length
of the sewer piping system was only 691 km, with 17% centralized wastewater
treatment capacity. In 2000, the length of sewer system increased to 835 km,
which and reached 1,618 km in 2005. The wastewater treated by treatment plant in
2000 represented 23.1% of the total amount discharged, and in 2005 has reached
nearly 40%.
~ 87 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Item
Unit
1949
1978
1990
2000
2005
Gas supply rate
%
--
1.1
31.2
81.5
91.3
Tap water system
km
30
567
1074
2237
2315
Area of central heat supply
Ha
--
--
246
854
2113
Buses
--
17
332
875
2573
4762
Length of urban roads
km
59
278
604
975
1382
Area of urban roads
Ha
57
312
675
1263
3021
Sewer system
km
25
317
691
835
1618
Wastewater treatment rate
%
--
--
17
23.1
38.9
Safe disposition of solid waste
%
--
--
--
90.89
90.36
Table 5-19: Level of infrastructure provision in selected years
Source: Statistical year book, Xi’an Local Chronicles
5.4 Issues and challenges
Although the public corporation model in the market economy successfully
mobilized more resources to finance infrastructure, which resulted in a higher
level of investment in proportion to GDP and a higher level of infrastructure
provision, potential risks still exist in the current model. Four issues are identified
risky for future financing activities, namely, excessive government guarantee on
debt repayment, cyclic revenue stream from land assignment, a pricing policy that
limits private participation, and insufficient understanding of the risks in new
financial instruments.
5.4.1 XIIG’s debts, projects and government guarantees
As a public-owned infrastructure company, XIIG is fully guaranteed by the local
government in terms of its debt repayment. The projects financed by XIIG, its
~ 88 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
subordinate companies, and its joint venture companies are also guaranteed by
purchase contracts, on-lent public credit loans and other agreements with the local
government. Even if commitment is not provided, the government is still likely to
bail out the projects from financial distress, if any. Although issuing a guarantee
requires no instant cash, the government bears insolvency risks of the projects,
explicitly or implicitly.
One of the reasons why government engages in guarantees voluntarily is that if
one company goes bankrupt, the service it provides will be suspended. Since the
service is vital to the city, even a small chance of disruption would be beyond the
acceptance of the local government. More importantly, the failures of the projects
are politically unpalatable. It would, no matter whether it is true, be seen as a
failure of the government and its policies. It would also damage the personal
political lives of the decision makers. Therefore, they would rather increase
service prices, offer grants, and provide concessional loans, than invite political
embarrassments.
Insolvency risk, or unpredictable variation in value and its distribution, will rise
with the increase of the company/project’s leverage (Irwin, 2007). It will be a
mismatched risk allocation if the government that bears insolvency risks is unable
to control the leverage of the company. However, leverage control is not feasible,
because it contravenes the local government’s intention of transferring
responsibilities of infrastructure assets and liability management to the hands of the
~ 89 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
professional enterprises. It is also irrational if the government who is trying to use
project finance to insulate recourse at the same time guarantees all the debts
incurred. Therefore, further unbundling of XIIG, other public corporations, and the
local government is required.
It is difficult for the government to avoid guarantees, because of the political
implications discussed above. But it is possible to undertake some measures to
mitigate the possible risks caused by the vague financial relationship and
guarantees. Firstly, the local government should separate revenues granted to XIIG
from other fiscal revenues clearly. Currently, on local budget statement, one cannot
distinguish the income items transferred to XIIG and items deposited into the debt
repayment reserves from other general purpose incomes. Secondly, profitable
infrastructure, quasi-profitable infrastructure and non-profitable infrastructure
should be financed with different mechanisms. The local government’s decision to
bear debt repayment, offer guarantees, or provide subsidies should be based on the
nature of the infrastructure area. Thirdly, decision makers should be aware that
guarantees incur costs. A mechanism to estimate the value or the cost of a
guarantee should be established. Last but not least, decision makers should try to
avoid reaching implicit agreements on guarantees. In this way, guarantees are
documented clearly for all stakeholders.
5.4.2 Unstable revenue stream from land assignment
Currently, land assignment is the most important revenue stream of XIIG. In
~ 90 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
another word, it is the mainstay to enable the capital investment of XIIG into
infrastructure finance. It is also a key factor to keep a good corporate performance
on the balance sheet, so that the company is able to attract capital in the bond
market. However, land assignment as a powerful revenue source is an unstable
alternative in future.
The role of state owned land in fact extends beyond direct assignment. Some loans
borrowed from domestic banks are secured by these lands. Debt is repaid by selling
using rights of parcels of land whose value has been enhanced by the infrastructure
projects financed by the debt (for example, third ring road, land appreciation). The
local government keeps expanding the urbanized area according to its master plan.
When the government acquires land from rural communes, only minimal subsidy is
paid. After turning into urban land, the value of the land can increase as much as 10
times according to the market value. Another novel way to acquire land for
commercial assignment is moving the city hall and administrative buildings of
municipality to new developed area outside the urban center. On the one hand, it
creates a new urban center where municipal offices is relocated with up-valued
surrounding land; on the other hand, it frees up highly valued land for assignment at
the existing urban center. This type of land marketing activities is criticized as
aggressive profit-maximizing monopolizing. Besides, the supply of land available
for leasing will eventually run out, rendering land assignment a transitional
infrastructure-financing strategy. In some other cities, their public assets
management companies have already exhausted potential lands within the
~ 91 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
jurisdictions and started to organize land transactions in other regions as
consultants.
5.4.3 Private participation and policy risks
It is quite clear that the local government is promoting private participation in
infrastructure provision and management. However, currently policy risks as
perceived by investors are still significant obstacles for private participation,
especially the risks related to pricing of services.
When user fees were first levied in China, they were controlled by the central
government at a level far below the financial costs of providing the services. The
central government restricted the level of user charges on the ground of
redistribution and macroeconomic control. Some researchers argue that subsidy for
service is inefficient for redistributional purpose since it benefits higher income
users as well. They also believe that holding down user charges to control inflation
is treating a symptom rather than the cause. Moreover, if subsidy to the service is
financed by deficit, it may even fuel inflation (Dillinger, 1995). Lately, the central
government has encouraged the use of user charges for local infrastructure like
water supply, refuse disposition, and wastewater treatment to be priced at the level
which can cover their costs. Since 2002, Xi’an government has begun gradual price
reform in public service areas. However, in 2005, the government implemented
another regulation prohibiting any price increase including the above areas to
control inflation.
~ 92 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
Such price control may introduce more policy risks in the future, thus would
divert investments from infrastructure. Similar risks could also arise from the
possibility of the government’s unexpectedly changing quality standards,
creating/abolishing franchise, cutting subsidies, or expropriation without sufficient
compensation. In a heavy capital-sunk area which is especially vulnerable to risks,
infrastructure companies consider policy risks conservatively. Therefore, Xi’an
local government has to prepare more effective mechanisms to assure investors of
stable policy with compensation. One solution is to include the effects of policy
changes into contracts.
5.4.4 Lure and risks of other financing approaches
As noted in the study, Xi’an is not the infrastructure financing pioneer in China.
Other financing approaches have been implemented in other cities. However, the
decision whether these mechanisms should be adopted in the future must be made
carefully.
BOT is the most widely used innovative financing method in China’s infrastructure
provision. There have been dozens of such projects in operation now. The central
government has already provided a model and relevant regulations for BOT
projects. A relatively new development is the raising of funds from securities
backed by a pool of infrastructure assets. For example, in 1996 the Guangdong
Provincial Expressway company raised HK$477.9million (US$62 million) through
issuing B shares on the Shenzhen exchange, backed by stakes in completed revenue
~ 93 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
generating toll expressway and bridge. The money raised was used to finance the
new expressway. $100 million is raised by the Anhui Expressway Company in a
similar way (World Bank, 1997a).
Current studies in China promote various new financing methods. Advocators of
local bond finance have campaigned for the use of municipal bonds for a long time
(Su and Zhao, 2007; Wang, 2005). Based on the analysis of the successful
operation of municipal bonds in America and Japan, they introduced many
suitable specific designs for China in their studies. Government funds for
particular infrastructure areas (Chen, 2007) and Asset-backed securities backed by
existing infrastructure (Quan, 2004) are also suggested. It is of course beneficial
that more successful mechanisms of infrastructure finance could be tailored to
application in China. But equally important is that the economic and political
prerequisites and potential risks are identified. Currently, the domestic research
area is focusing on novelty of financing mechanisms. Nevertheless, studies often
ignore or underrate the risks associated with the new approaches.
The proponents of bonds argue that central injunction and restriction come from
fear of inability to control the local economy. However, in most countries, local
public finance is also strictly limited, especially in terms of borrowing. In urban
politics, theory states that government officers stay shorter in office than the
lifetime of a project. In this case, they tend to overspend to gain more votes. So the
restriction is to stabilize the long-term financial capacity and repayment ability of
~ 94 ~
Chapter 5 Financing Urban Infrastructure for Xi’an
the local government.
The new financing tools all require a mature financial market, which China is still
struggling its way towards. Shares, bonds, trusts, funds, derivatives, and a credit
rating system are in different developing stages. The legal system and economic
policies on these issues are still inadequate. These new mechanisms are risky until
a mature capital market system is built and stable policies are implemented.
Expertise and skills are required in the government to manage the tools as well.
Many officials in the current government are more familiar with the traditional
fiscal system than the other financial mechanisms in the capital market. On this
ground, it is a good step to transfer infrastructure financing to public corporations
which could hire professionals. If dedicated funds are established for each
infrastructure area, the management of these funds could be challenging. It is very
important to avoid a possible bias in favor of new mechanisms simply because
they involve new financing approaches.
~ 95 ~
Chapter 6 Conclusion
Chapter 6 Conclusion
6.1 Summary
This thesis examines how urban infrastructure has been financed in Xi’an City in
China since PRC was founded in 1949. Based on literature review and field
investigation, data were collected and processed. The study divides mechanisms
of infrastructure finance into three periods, where different structural models are
built. The important variables in each model are analyzed and compared to reflect
their emergence, evolvement, and substitutions. Potential risks and challenges are
identified for the current model.
6.2 Main findings
1. Structural model of infrastructure financing
The research divides infrastructure finance of Xi’an into three different periods,
where structural models are established accordingly. The infrastructure financing
models built are
•
a centrally planned model based on the Soviet experience, from 1949 to 1978;
•
a public finance model during the experimental stage with free market
principles, from 1978 to 2000; and
•
a public corporation model with private participation in a market economy,
~ 96 ~
Chapter 6 Conclusion
from 2000 and after.
2. Emergence and substitutions of variables
In the centrally planned model, the local government collected taxes and
enterprise profit and transferred them to the central government. In turn, the local
government received project specified funds from the central government to carry
out its infrastructure projects. The central government, rather than the local
government, was the main actor in urban infrastructure financing. There was no
incentive and method for mobilizing private funds.
In the public finance model, the local government became the key initiator and
used a number of sources to fund urban infrastructure. These included earmarked
and general local taxes, public service and administration fees, funds raised by
local governmental agencies, inter-governmental transfers, domestic loans, and
on-lent sovereign loans.
In the public corporation model, Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group (XIIG)
was established as the central actor to finance urban infrastructure using project
finance. It receives revenue transferred from the local government, obtains on-lent
concessional loans (with the repayment guarantee by the local government), raises
private capital, and enters into joint ventures or franchise BOT agreements with
private companies for infrastructure development.
3. Potential risks of current model
~ 97 ~
Chapter 6 Conclusion
The current public corporation model, although advantaged in the market
economy, suffers from several risks. The study identifies four potential risks,
namely, excessive government guarantee on debt repayment, unstable revenue
stream from land assignment, a pricing policy that limits private participation, and
insufficient understanding of the risks in new financial instruments. Several
recommendations are made to mitigate these risks.
6.3 Limitations
The research design of case study may be inherently biased. The result is
restricted by specific characteristics of the case. Xi’an, as a city in China, is
essential different from New York or London. It is suddenly exposed to an
industrialized and globalized economy after 1978. It is facing old problems which
have been experienced by western cities, and also new problems that have just
emerged. Moreover, it is located in a socialist market country controlled by a single
political party. Investigation of this single case does not allow much board
generalization.
Another limitation of the study is the relatively fewer qualitative data available in
the first period from 1949 to 1978. In the first several decades after independence,
budgetary, statistical and documentation systems were not as well developed as
the recent years, especially at prefectural level. Therefore, more qualitative data
are used to illustrate the financing mechanisms in this period. These data are
~ 98 ~
Chapter 6 Conclusion
acquired through cross disciplinary search and interviews.
6.4 Recommendations
The first recommendation to future research is undertaking studies in a larger
temporal scope. Most previous studies in China have been focusing on either the
1990s or the most recent several years. Although this research has already
extended the temporal scope to 1950s, it still does not cover the war period and
earlier periods.
It is also recommended that comparative studies be carried out based on previous
cases. A multi-case comparison study would assist a more broad generalization of
the conclusions.
~ 99 ~
Appendix
Appendix
Appendix A: Infrastructure financing sources 1996-2000 (Unit: million CNY)
Sources of funds
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP
Central/Provincial transfer
9
36
441
391
170
1047
National debt investment
9
8
405
365
150
937
Provincial transfer
0
28
36
26
20
110
Local general budget
273
288
248
338
490
1637
Urban construction & maintenance
tax; Add-ons of public utilities
144
191
180
181
195
891
State-owned land assignment
50
61
39
62
230
442
Water resource fees
14
8
9
7
10
48
Other non-earmarked taxes
65
28
20
88
55
256
Local administrative incomes
445
461
479
515
532
2432
Public facility hookup fees
88
91
111
162
115
567
User charges
64
58
175
187
157
641
293
312
193
166
260
1224
Other sources
61
80
95
92
83
411
Local agency self-raised funds
20
10
58
66
60
214
108
65
198
10
204
585
50
145
227
0
74
496
966
1075
1746
1412
1613
6812
Other incomes
Domestic bank loans
Sovereign loans on-lent
Total
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
~ 100 ~
Appendix
Appendix B: Infrastructure construction expenditures 1996-2000 (Unit: mil CNY)
Items
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
9FYP
60
70
85
90
95
400
100
133
168
170
215
786
2
6
10
9
10
37
804
866
1483
1143
1293
5589
Water supply
225
248
557
343
348
1721
Road and bridges
358
281
322
397
513
1871
Sewage system
16
22
85
43
75
241
Central heating
17
16
30
62
11
136
103
203
351
120
61
838
Wastewater treatment
68
78
93
91
140
470
Greening
17
18
45
87
145
312
966
1075
1746
1412
1613
6812
Salary and office overhead
Maintenance
Project preparation
Project construction costs
Gas supply
Total
Source: Xi’an urban &rural construction and development commission
Appendix C: Organizational chart of Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group
Source: Xi’an Infrastructure Investment Group
~ 101 ~
Appendix
Appendix D: Infrastructure finance sources 2001-2008 (Unit: million CNY)
Source of funds
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
79
180
220
382
461
410
354
National debt
69
170
200
310
346
186
187
Provincial transfer
10
10
20
72
115
224
167
Local general budget
1010
1140
1309
1630
2057
2473
2454
280
360
433
498
627
865
830
Other non-earmarked taxes
98
76
59
90
164
128
138
Public facility hookup fees
188
217
255
240
514
578
489
User charges
324
357
401
584
632
772
837
Other incomes
120
130
161
218
120
130
160
384
1275
1496
1444
890
702
837
0
0
0
0
540
500
250
Self-raised funds
133
55
2225
2447
2156
2800
2964
Special district self-raised
funds
106
0
1183
1301
1131
1700
1980
County Self-raised funds
27
55
1042
1146
1025
1100
984
Domestic bank loans
747
990
1620
3000
3960
2110
1420
Sovereign loans on-lent
110
0
320
520
920
1360
1150
0
0
0
0
0
0
1300
2463
3640
7190
9422
10985
10355
10729
Central/Provincial transfer
Urban cons.&maint. tax;
Add-ons of public utilities
State-owned land assignment
Private capitals
Bonds
Total
Source: Xi'an Municipal Urban and Rural Construction Commission
~ 102 ~
Reference
Reference
ADB (2003), Local Government Finance, Private Resources and Local Credit
Markets in Asia. Manila: Asian Development Bank.
Allen, M.T. and Dare W.H. (2002), “Identifying Determinants of Horizontal
Property Tax Inequity: Evidence from Florida.” The Journal of Real Estate
Research, 24(2), 153-164.
Aluko, B.T. (2005), “Building Urban Local Governance Fiscal Autonomy through
Property Taxation Financing Option.” International Journal of Strategic
Property Management, 9(4), 201-214.
Ball, R., Heafey M., and King D. (2007), “The Private Finance Initiative in the
UK: a Value for Money and Economic Analysis.” Public Management Review,
9(2), 289-310.
Barr, M. (1998), “Project Finance.” International Financial Law Review, Jun, p21.
Bellier, M and Zhou Y.M. (2003), Private Participation in Infrastructure in China:
Issues and Recommendations for the Road, Water, and Power Sector,
Washington D.C.: the World Bank.
Bergvall, D. et, al. (2006), “Intergovernmental Transfers and Decentralized Public
Spending.” OECD Journal on Budgeting, 5(4), 111-155.
Bird, R.M. (1993), “Threading the Fiscal Labyrinth: Some Issues in Fiscal
Decentralization.” National Tax Journal, 46, 207-227.
Bradburry, K.L. (1983), “Examining Fiscal Distress in Cities.” Impact, 2(1/2), 1-8.
Break, G.F. (1967), Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in the United States.
Washington, D.C.: the Brookings Institution, p107-164
Brittain, L.S. (2002), “Financing Capital Expenditures.” Canadian Tax Journal,
5(2), 552-564.
Budina, N., Brixi H.P. and Irwin T. (2005), Public-Private Partnerships in the
New EU Member States: Managing Fiscal Risks. Washington, D.C.: the World
Bank, p5-12.
Bureau of Legislative Affairs of the State Council of People’s Republic of China
(1991), Laws and Regulations of the People’s Republic of China Governing
Foreign-related Matters. Beijing: China Legal System Publishing House.
Calhoun, C.A. (2001), “Property Valuation Methods and Data in the United
States.” Housing Finance International, 16(2), 12-23.
~ 103 ~
Reference
Caruson, K. and MacManus S.A. (2007), “Structuring Homeland Security Grants:
Florida’s Local Finance Officials Evaluate the Funding Process.” Public
Finance & Management, 7(2), 191-226.
Chen, Q. (2007), Urban Wastewater Infrastructure Construction Financing Gap
Analysis and Governmental Investment and Financial Mode Design. A master
thesis: Tsinghua University, Beijing, China (in Chinese).
Colucci, D.M. (1999), “Is Leasing the Key to European Projects?” International
Financial Law Review, 18(8), 18.
Cooper, K.W.P. (1996), “The Adequacy of Property Tax Valuation Procedures.”
Journal of Property Valuation & Investment, 14(3), 71.
Copeland, G.W. and Meier K.J. (1984), “Pass the Biscuits, Pappy: Congressional
Decision Making and Federal Grants.” American Journal of Political Science,
Aug., 479-502.
Derrick, F.W. and Charles E.S. (1993), “Business and the Incidence of Sales and
Use Taxes.” Public Finance Quarterly, 21, 210-226.
Dillinger, B. (1995), “Decentralization Politics and Public Services”, in Estache A.
(ED) Decentralizing Infrastructure: Advantages and Limitations. Washington,
D.C.: the World Bank discussion papers 290.
Dilnot, A.W. (ED) (1993), Options for 1994: The Green Budget. London: Institute
for Fiscal Studies.
Dunkerley, H.B. (1983), Urban Land Policy: Issues and Opportunities, a World
Bank Publication. New York: Oxford University Press.
Evans, C.J. and Lawhon L. (2003), “The Effects of Impact Fees on the Price of
Housing and Land: a Literature Review.” Journal of Planning Literature, 17(3),
351-359.
Fisher, R.C. (1982), “Income and Grant Effects on Local Expenditure: the
Flypaper Effect and Other Difficulties.” Journal of Urban Economics, 12,
324-345.
Fryman, R.F. (1969), “Sales Taxation of Producers’ Goods in Illinois.” National
Tax Journal, 22, 273-281.
Gerasimova, V. et, al. (2005), “Land Value Taxation for Russian Local
Governments: Evidence from Saratov Oblast.” Proceedings of the Annual
Conference on Taxation, p372-379.
Gerring, J. (2007), Case Study Research: Principles and Practices. Boston:
Cambridge University Press, p38.
Gilbert, G. and Guengant A. (2002), “The Public Debt of Local Government in
~ 104 ~
Reference
France”, in Bernard D. (ED) Local Public Finance in Europe: Balancing the
Budget and Controlling Debt. MA: Edward Elgar, p115-133.
Goodspeed, T.J. (1998), “The Relationship between State Income Taxes and Local
Property Taxes: Education Finance in New Jersey.” National Tax Journal, 51,
219-238.
Gramkhar, S. and Sim S.C. (2001), “The Impact of Federal Alcohol and Drug
Abuse Block Grants on State and Local Government Substance Abuse Program
Expenditures: the Role of Federal Oversight.” Journal of Health Politics, Policy
&Law, 26(6), 1261-1290.
Harris, C. (2003), Private Participation in Infrastructure in Developing Countries:
Trends, Impacts, and Polity Lessons. Washington, D.C.: the World Bank, p3-15.
Hawkins, R.M. and Murray M.N. (2004), “Explaining Interjurisdictional Variation
in Local Sales Tax Yield.” Public finance review, 32(1), 82-104.
Holzer, M. and Zhang M.Z. (2003), “China’s Fiscal Reform: the Issue of Extra
Budgeting.” Journal of Public Budgeting, Accounting &Financial Management,
16(1), 19-39.
Hu, A.G. and Hu G.Y. (2005), Aids and Development: Efficiency and Effect
Evaluation of Loans from International Financial Institutions to China
(1981-2002). Beijing: China Legal System Publishing House.
Hulten, C.R. and Schwab R.M. (1993), “Infrastructure and Economic
Performance: What the Data Really Show” in Mintz J.M. and Preston R.S. (ED)
Infrastructure and Competitiveness. Canada: John Deitsch Institute for the
Study of Economic Policy.
Irwin, T.C. (2007), Government Guarantees: Allocating and Valuing Risk in
Privately Financed Infrastructure Projects. Washington, D.C.: the World Bank.
Jeong, M. and Feiock R. (2006), “Impact Fees, Growth Management, and
Development: a Contractual Approach to Local Polity and Governance.” Urban
Affairs Review, 41(6), 749-768.
Kitchen, H.M. and Slack E. (2003), “Special Study: New Finance Options for
Municipal Governments.” Canadian Tax Journal, 51(6), 2216.
Klijn, E.H. and Terisman G.R. (2000), “Governing Public-private Partnerships:
Analyzing and Managing the Process and Institutional Characteristics of Public
Private Partnerships,” in Osborne S.P. (ED) Public Private Partnerships:
Theory and Practice in International Perspective. London: Routledge.
Krishnan, L. (2007), “Tamil Nadu urban development fund: public-private
partnership in an infrastructure finance intermediary”. In Peterson G.E. and
Annez P.C. (ED) Financing Cities: Fiscal Responsibility and Urban
~ 105 ~
Reference
Infrastructure in Brazil, China, India, Poland and South Africa. Delhi: Sage
Publications, p238.
Lai, L.F. (2007), “Bond’s return.” International Financial Law Review, April: p1.
Levine, J.C. (1994), “Equity in Infrastructure Finance: When are Impact Fees
Justified?” Land Economics, 70(2), 210-222.
Lewis, B.D. (2006), “Local Government Taxation: an Analysis of Administrative
Cost Inefficiency.” Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 42(2), 213-233.
Lin, S.L. (2001), “Public Infrastructure Development in China.” Comparative
Economic Studies, 43(2), 83-109.
Mikesell, J.L. (1989), Fiscal Administration Analysis and Application for the
Public Sector. Chicago: the Dorsey Press.
Miller, J.B. (2000), Principles of Public and Private Infrastructure Delivery.
Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pxxx.
Mody, A. (1997), Infrastructure Strategies in East Asia: the Untold Story.
Washington, D.C.: the World Bank.
Mullins, D.R.and Sally W. (1996), “Changing Demographics and State Fiscal
Outlook: the Case of Sales Taxes.” Public Finance Quarterly, 24, 237-262.
Musgrave, R.A. (1959), The Theory of Public Finance, New York: McGraw-Hill,
p5-6.
Musgrave, R.A. and Musgrave P.B. (1976), Public Finance in Theory and
Practice. Tokyo: McGraw-Hill, p187-213.
Myna, A. (2007), “Local Government Investments and Financial Liabilities-the
Example of Mid-eastern Poland.” Economic and Business Review for Central
and South-Eastern Europe, 9(2), 111-127.
Neenan, W.B. (1981), Urban Public Economics. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth Inc.,
p105-130.
Netzer, D. (1992), “Differences in Reliance on User Charges by American State
and Local Governments.” Public Finance Quarterly, 20(4), 499-512.
Newbery, D.M. and Santos G. (1999), “Road Taxes Road User Charges and
Earmarking.” Fiscal Studies, 20(2), 103-132.
Oates, W.E. (1985), “Searching for Leviathan: an Empirical Study.” American
Economic Review, p748-757.
Oates, W.E. (1989), “Fiscal Decentralization and the Size of the Public Sector:
Some Further Reflections.” American Economic Review, p579-583.
OECD (1991), Urban Infrastructure: Finance and Management. Paris:
~ 106 ~
Reference
Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, p10.
OECD (2007), Investment Strategies and Financial Tools for Local Development.
Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development.
Ostrom, E., Schroeder L. and Wynne S. (1993), Institutional Incentives and
Sustainable Development. Boulder: Westview Press.
Peterson, P.E. (1981), City Limits. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Porter, D.R. and Peiser R.B. (1991), Financing Infrastructure to Support
Community Growth. Washington, D.C.: the Urban Land Institute, p19.
Qiao, B.Y. Jorge M.V. and Xu Y.S. (2008), “The Tradeoff between Growth and
Equity in Decentralization Policy: China’s Experience.” Journal of
Development Economics, 86(1), 112-128.
Qin, H. (2003), “Financing Status and Reform Orientations of Public
Infrastructure in China.” Urban and Rural Construction, 13 (7), 47-54.
Quan, G.H. (2004), Application of Assets-backed Securities in Urban
Infrastructure Financing. A master thesis: Central South University, Changsha,
China (in Chinese).
Santiago, L.P. (2008), “Local Governments’ Asymmetric Reactions to Grants.”
Public Finance Review, 36(2), 219.
Savitch, H.V. and Kantor P. (2002), Cities in the International Marketplace: the
Political Economy of Urban Development in North America and Western
Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press, p19-20.
Shaanxi Provincial Statistics (2000), Shaanxi Statistical Data Collection:
from1949 to 1990. Xi’an: Shaanxi Statistics Press (in Chinese).
Stiglitz, J.E. (1988), Economics of the Public Sector, 2nd edition. New York: W.W.
Norton.
Su, M. and Zhao Q.H. (2007), “China: Fiscal Framework and Urban Infrastructure
Finance”, in Peterson G.E. and Annez P.C. (ED) Financing Cities: Fiscal
Responsibility and Urban Infrastructure in Brazil, China, India, Poland and
South Africa. Delhi: Sage Publications, p101.
Tan, W. (2004), Practical Research Methods, 2nd edition. Singapore: Pearson, p79.
Tan, W. (2007), Principles of project and infrastructure finance. London: Taylor
&Francis.
Thoni, E., Garbislander S. and Haas D.J. (2002), “Local Budgeting and Local
Borrowing in Austria”, in Bernard D. (ED) Local Public Finance in Europe:
Balancing the Budget and Controlling Debt. MA: Edward Elgar, p45-73.
~ 107 ~
Reference
Tideman, N. (1982), “A tax on Land is Neutral.” National Tax Journal, 35,
109-111.
Trecilcock, M.J. and Daniels R.J. (1993), “Choice of policy instruments in the
provision of public infrastructure”, in Mintz J.M. and Preston R.S. (ED)
Infrastructure and Competitiveness. Canada: John Deitsch Institute for the
Study of Economic Policy.
Uguy, L.S. (2001), Intergovernmental Transfers in Indonesia: An Analysis of
Local Conditions and Their Effects on Central Grants Received. A Ph.D. thesis:
Virginia Commonwealth University, the US.
Ulbrich, H.H. (2003), Public Finance: in Theory and Practice. Ohio: Thomson
Learning.
United Nations (1998), Public Private Partnerships: A New Concept for
Infrastructure Development. United Nations Publications ECE/Trade/262, p3.
Vanneste, J. (2002), “Local Public Finance in Belgium: Structure, Budgets and
Debt”, in Bernard D. (ED) Local Public Finance in Europe: Balancing the
Budget and Controlling Debt. MA: Edward Elgar, p75-91.
Wang, H.B. (2005), Research on the Bond Finance of the Urbanization and
Corporation Governance in China – Study on Large Engineering Project. A
PhD dissertation: Tongji University, Shanghai, China (in Chinese).
Wilkinson, M. (1994), “Paying for Public Spending: Is There a Role for
Earmarked Taxes?” Fiscal Studies, 15(4), 119.
Winner, H. (2005), “Has Tax Competition Emerged in OECD countries? Evidence
from Panel Data.” International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 667-687.
Wolman, H. (1983), “Understanding Local Government Strategies Responses to
Fiscal Pressure.” Journal of Public Policy, 3, 245-264.
Wong, C.P.W. (1997), Financing Local Government in the People’s Republic of
China. New York: Oxford University Press, p27.
World Bank (1994), World Development Report: Infrastructure for Development.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Zhu, S., Liu Y. and Chen A.Y. (2004) “Financing Sources of Urban Infrastructure
Construction in China.” Theory Guidelines, (8), 22-23 (in Chinese).
~ 108 ~
[...]... responsibility of urban infrastructure provision and its financing 2.1 Provision of local infrastructure This section mainly addresses two aspects One aspect is the suitability of public provision of local infrastructure The other aspect is the responsibility of the local government and central government in the provision of urban infrastructure The foremost characteristic of urban infrastructure is a mixture of. .. company In this case, substantial part of risks associated with financing and operating the facility are allocated on the private sector PPPs have many advantages In the finance aspect, the benefits of involving the private sector are the transfer of risk, substitutes for public borrowing and up-front costs, and the protection of users and tax-payers from the financing burden In the management aspect,... transfer and conditional transfer; in the US, they are called general-purpose grants and categorical grants General intergovernmental transfer does not put constraints on the expenditure area It is often distributed on a lump-sum basis automatically according to certain preset criteria The determination of transfer amount relies on several factors, for instance, population, tax base, and poverty rate of a. .. earmarking is the allocation of certain tax revenues to a designated end use Newbery and Santos (1999) believe that earmarking taxes for dedicated capital expenditure is an obvious application of the benefit principle of taxation which, properly applied, should lead to a more efficient structure of local service provision In the US, a major source for transportation infrastructure finance is an earmarked... fiscal sustainability relies heavily on intergovernmental transfers As Lewis (2006) noted, central government ~ 13 ~ Chapter 2 Literature Review transfer in Indonesia accounts for 92% of local fiscal resources, whereas taxes and user charges only add 8% to total local revenue There are two basic types of intergovernmental transfers, general and earmarked In Canada, they are called unconditional transfer... the main beneficiaries are within the local jurisdiction Existing residents also resist higher taxes in developing regions and areas (Savitch and Kantor, 2002) In China, dramatic changes have occurred in the last half century Urban areas have developed from war-torn towns to modern cities Still, little is known about the changing forces of new financial arrangements and their efficacy, particularly... local tax is property tax The tax normally imposes on various types of properties: residential, commercial, industrial, and institutional properties As the city develops, although property tax remains the revenue mainstay at local level, consumption and income taxes are increasingly relied upon as well All the for-and-against arguments on a particular tax item concern its level of “efficiency” as well... income taxes centrally to avoid capital ~ 14 ~ Chapter 2 Literature Review flight across local areas or regions These collected revenues are then transferred to local and state governments according to some equitable formula A municipality, as a relatively small open economic system and a constitutional creature of senior governments, has limited autonomy and monopoly ability to raise revenue In many countries,... (Kitchen and Slack, 2005) Transfers also have a horizontal equity purpose (Santiago, 2008) Cities, constrained by geographic, historical, and demographic factors, may differ in their taxable wealth (Bradbury, 1983) Transfers are collected from both rich and poor areas In many circumstances, transfers are allocated to reduce the revenue disparities among local governments, so that low income municipalities... Local governments may borrow from capital markets directly as well, especially in ~ 17 ~ Chapter 2 Literature Review those profitable infrastructure areas If being sponsored by higher government guarantees against local default, local governments can obtain higher credit ratings and borrow at lower interest rates (ADB, 2003) Sometimes, commercial financing agencies may receive tax reliefs in exchange ... carried out in the field setting of the case city Both quantitative and qualitative data are collected and analyzed Quantitative data come from internal and external sources Data are mainly taken... categorized according to the number of cases, spatial variation, and temporal variation This research was the single case diachronic study, with little spatial variation but substantial temporal variation... general allocation of property tax, income tax, and consumption tax, earmarked tax is often used in financing infrastructure Tax earmarking is the allocation of certain tax revenues to a designated