Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 73 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
73
Dung lượng
590,06 KB
Nội dung
Policy Diffusion in Incomplete Decentralized System:
The Case of Diffusions of Housing
Provident Fund (HPF) Policy in Urban China
CHEN TINGJIA
(B.Law, Nankai University)
A THESIS SUBMITTED
FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SOCIAL SCIENCES
DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE
NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE
2013
DECLARATION
I hereby declare that this thesis is my original work and it has been written by
me in its entirety.
I have duly acknowledged all the sources of information which have been used
in the thesis.
This thesis has also not been submitted for any degree in any university
previously.
__
___
Chen Tingjia
12 October 2013
i
To my parents,
who gave me the best of their love during the past 24 years
ii
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The topic of policy diffusion has interested me since my undergraduate. It is excited that
this research gives me an opportunity to make some contributions on the existing
knowledge of this topic. During my candidature, especially the period of thesis writing, I
have received numerous help from others.
First and foremost, I would like to express my deepest gratitude to my supervisor,
Professor Wang Cheng-Lung, without whom I could not even finish this paper. His
tremendous support, guidance, and encouragement stimulate me to concentrate on the
study and keep improving myself. The original idea of this thesis was conceived when I
did independent study on public policy with him. Also because of his guidance and
inspiration, I improved my argument more reasonable and much stronger. His
encouragement and intelligence have greatly prompted me to go further in academic
study. Luckily enough, I was just admitted by the University of Arizona to pursue my
Ph.D. in Public Policy. Besides the academic study, Professor Wang also gave me great
help on my life. As an international student without scholarship, I would have had a
much tougher time if he had not offered me the opportunity to be his research assistant.
But now I am so annoyed that my words are too thin compared with his vast support.
I also owe a debt of gratitude to Professor Naomi Aoki. Her course, decentralization
and local governance, has inspired me a lot in this thesis. Moreover, her comments on the
early draft of this thesis are greatly appreciated. I would also like to thank Professor Soo
Yoen Kim. Her training on research design allows this research to follow the scientific
method rigorously.
As the early version of this thesis has been presented in Mid-West Political Science
Association 2013 Conference, I also wish to thank Professor Jale Tosun, the discussant of
my paper. Her sharp questions have pushed me to have a further improvement on this
thesis.
iii
I thank my fellow graduate students at National University of Singapore, who have
enriched my life. The discussions with them always spark the ideas for my current and
future research. Among these individuals, I would like to mention two persons specially.
Li Xiang has introduced me several brilliant works on methodology which have
contributed a lot to this study. And the discussions with Zha Wen on the latest changes in
the judiciary system in China have stimulated both our interests. Thus, we would
collaborate on relative research in the near future.
Last but not the least, I am also grateful to my parents who give me the best of their
love all the time. I also want to thank my fiancé, Xu Chen, who is my dearest friend and
faithful companion. Whenever I encountered any difficulties, their warmest hands and
strongest support are always beside me. Nothing could compete with their support and
love.
iv
TABLES OF CONTENTS
SUMMURY ...................................................................................................................... vii
LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................... viii
LIST OF FIGURES ........................................................................................................... ix
Chapter 1
Introduction ..................................................................................................... 1
Chapter 2
Literature Review ............................................................................................ 3
2.1 General Discussion on Policy Diffusion ................................................................... 3
2.2 The mechanisms of policy diffusion and its conditions ............................................ 7
2.3 Policy innovation and diffusion in China.................................................................. 9
Chapter 3
Argument and Hypotheses ............................................................................ 13
3.1 Incomplete decentralization and its accountability locus ........................................ 13
3.2 Principal-agent theory and policy diffusion in incomplete decentralization........... 15
3.3 Central-local relations in China............................................................................... 16
3.4 Policy Diffusion of Housing Provident Fund in China ........................................... 19
3.4.1 Urban housing reform in China ........................................................................ 19
3.4.2 An explanation on the diffusion of the housing provident fund policy ............ 22
Chapter 4
Empirical Analysis ........................................................................................ 27
4.1 Data and measurement: the dependent variables .................................................... 27
4.2 Data and measurement: the independent variables ................................................. 28
4.3 Data and measurement: the control variables ......................................................... 29
4.4 Methodology ........................................................................................................... 33
4.4.1 Methodology for Binary Time-series Cross-Sectional Analysis ...................... 33
4.4.2 Methodology for Survival Analysis ................................................................. 34
4.5 Results ..................................................................................................................... 35
v
4.5.1 Results for Binary Time-series Cross-sectional Analysis ................................ 35
4.5.2 Results for Survival Analysis ........................................................................... 42
4.6 Discussion on the Statistical Results ....................................................................... 46
Chapter 5
Conclusion..................................................................................................... 49
Bibliography ..................................................................................................................... 52
Appendix ........................................................................................................................... 60
vi
SUMMURY
Most existing studies of policy innovations focus on the cases in which policy-making
process is decentralized. However, in many developing countries, such as China, the
extent of decentralization is limited. Thus, the determinants and mechanisms of
diffusions of policy innovations in such a less decentralized system could be different
from what has been established in the literature.
Since 1980s, China has launched a full aspect economic reform to transit its national
economy from a centrally planned system to a more market-based economy. Housing
reform, which was deigned to transform the welfare-oriented housing policy to a marketoriented one, was an important part of this policy transformation. This article specifically
analyzes how the housing provident fund (HPF) policy has been diffused in urban China
during 1990s.
This study intends to answer the following questions: (1) what are the key factors that
determine the adoption of policy innovation concerning HPF among Chinese local
governments (cities)? (2) How do central and local governments influence diffusion of
policy innovations in this process? (3) Why are some local governments more likely to be
positively affected by the central government to adopt the policy innovations? Using a
revised theoretical framework which integrates both local political economy factors and
national policy priorities of the central government, this study contributes to explain more
systematically what factors determine the adoptions of new policies in the less
decentralized system of China. In addition, this study applies binary time-series crosssectional analysis and survival analysis to study the large data set concerning policy
innovations and diffusions in China. The findings suggest that local revenue and
enterprises’ economic performance which represent the local level capacity have a
significant positive influence on the adoption of HPF policy, and that the effects of the
national promotion on HPF policy innovation is significantly affected by the condition of
local revenue. However, contradict to the expectation, the average wages of workers and
staff that may reflect the interests of local residents have a negative impact on the
diffusion of HPF policy among Chinese local governments.
vii
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1 Summary Statistics for the Binary Time-series Cross-sectional Analysis .......... 32
Table 2 Summary Statistics for the Survival Analysis ..................................................... 33
Table 3 Maximum-Likelihood Estimation for HPF Policy Innovation ............................ 36
Table 4 Changes in the Predicted Probabilities of HPF Policy Innovation ...................... 37
Table 5 Estimated Hazard Rate of HPF Policy Innovation .............................................. 43
viii
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1 China's experimentation-based policy cycle ...................................................... 10
Figure 2 Local Revenue Increases HPF Policy Innovation .............................................. 38
Figure 3 Economic Performance Increases HPF Policy Innovation ................................. 39
Figure 4 Average Wage Decreases HPF Policy Innovation ............................................. 40
Figure 5 National Promotion Decreases HPF Policy Innovation ..................................... 41
Figure 6 Effect of Interaction on Probability of HPF Policy Innovation .......................... 42
Figure 7 Effects of Local Revenue on the Hazard rate of Innovation .............................. 44
Figure 8 Effects of Economic Performance on the Hazard rate of Innovation ................. 44
Figure 9 Effects of Average Wage on the Hazard Rate of Innovation ............................. 45
Figure 10 Effects of National Promotion on the Hazard Rate of Innovation ................... 46
Figure 11 Effects of Interaction Term on the Hazard Rate of Innovation ........................ 46
ix
Chapter 1
Introduction
Since 1980s, China has launched a full aspect economic reform to transit its national
economy from a centrally planned system to a more market-based economy, among
which housing reform was regarded as one of the three main reforms. However, the
Chinese government did experienced a difficult time to pull out the housing system from
the old institutions. Fortunately, the policy innovation of Housing Provident Fund (HPF),
which was borrowed from Singapore, initiated by Shanghai municipal government, and
quickly diffused after the first adoption, broke the impasse and promoted the housing
reform in China. It is a form of long time compulsory housing saving under the
employees’ personal account, through which both employees and employers should
contribute an equal percentage of the employees’ salary to the funds by month. More
importantly, the character of local initiation rather than central pilot selection of this
policy, presents the uniqueness of this policy.
Actually, not only in the case of HPF policy in this study, the diffusion of innovation
has been widely and deeply influencing the policy making process of the governments.
The political arrangement, social development, and policy practice in one region could
easily be observed, understood, and learned by another place. For decades, the practice of
the policy innovation and diffusion largely facilitated the relative researches in academia.
Most of these studies on policy diffusion among local governments are embedded in the
context of the U.S. (Baybeck, Berry, & Siegel, 2011; Berry & Berry, 1990, 1992;
Boehmke & Witmer, 2004; Cohen-Vogel & Ingle, 2007; Gilardi, 2010; Gray, 1973;
Grossback, Nicholson-Crotty, & Peterson, 2004; McLendon, Heller, & Young, 2005;
Shipan & Volden, 2008; Walker, 1969), where the decision making powers are usually
fully decentralized and suits the Tiebout model well. However, as Bardhan (2002) argued,
the assumptions for Tiebout model are too stringent for most developing countries.
According to this, the existing theories on policy innovation and diffusion should be
further revised and improved.
Thus, China, as the largest developing country in the world, should be a prefect
country for the study of policy diffusion in an “incomplete decentralization” system. Also,
1
since the reforms in China, especially the political reform, will still carry on, and local
policy innovation could be a breakthrough of further changing, it is important to deeply
understand how the reform carried forward in the past. Given the uniqueness and
importance of the HPF policy which have been briefly described at the beginning of this
chapter, it would be worth to explore the diffusion process, which could further inspire
other reform of China in the future. Therefore, this research applies binary time-series
cross-sectional analysis and survival analysis to study the large data of HPF diffusion in
China by answering the following questions: (1) what are the key factors that determine
the adoption of policy innovation concerning HPF among Chinese local governments
(cities)? (2) How do central and local governments influence the diffusion of policy
innovations in this process? (3) Why are some local governments more likely to be
positively affected by the central government to adopt the policy innovations? The
findings suggest that the local revenue and enterprises’ economic performance that
represent the local level capacity has a significant positive influence on the HPF policy
innovation, and that the effects of national promotion on HPF policy innovation is
significantly affected by local revenue. However, contradict to the expectation, the
average wage of local workers and staff that reflects the local interests has a significantly
negative impact on the HPF policy innovation. Detailed analysis and discussion will be
provided in the following chapters.
The organization of this paper is as follows. Chapter two reviews the literatures on
policy diffusion and positions the current research studies in the existing literatures. In
Chapter three, several hypotheses and related causal mechanisms are constructed by
analyzing the case of HPF policy innovation. Chapter four empirically tests the
hypotheses that have been raised. Chapter five concludes.
2
Chapter 2
Literature Review
This chapter reviews the main body of literature related to the current research. I first
focus on the general discussions on the topic of policy diffusion, especially the horizontal
and vertical diffusion. Then, I turn my attention to the mechanisms and conditions of the
diffusion of innovations. With a careful scrutiny, this research shows the necessity to
further explore the determinants and process of policy diffusion in an incomplete
decentralized system. Finally, as China, the largest developing country in the world, is
the main focus of this research, I present the existing studies which analyze the policy
innovation and diffusion in China. The previous literature has drawn a general picture on
the process of policy diffusion in China and emphasized the importance of the central
government; however, they ignore the active role of the local governments and the
interaction between the central and local governments during the diffusion process. This
research will contribute to the existing literature by studying the policy diffusion process
in a developing country and by examining the interaction between central and local
governments in the diffusion of innovations.
2.1 General Discussion on Policy Diffusion
The study of policy diffusion has emerged for decades long. Rogers (1962) gave a
comprehensive and systematic analysis on the general diffusion of innovations. In his
book, he presented the definition, elements, and process of diffusion. “Diffusion is the
process in which an innovation is communicated through certain channels over time
among the members of a social system.” (Rogers, 1962, p. 5) In terms of the diffusion in
the field of the political science and public policy, Walker defined the policy innovation
as “a program or policy which is new to the states adopting it” (Walker, 1969, p. 881),
meaning that it is still an innovation for the states who do not have such a policy before
no matter whether or not some other states have already adopted it. So it is different from
“policy invention”, which means the formation of original policy ideas (Berry & Berry,
2007). The spread of the innovative policy from the earlier adopters to the later ones is
called policy diffusion.
3
There are mainly two types of policy diffusion. One is horizontal; while the other is
vertical. The horizontal policy diffusion usually means the diffusion across nations or
among the local governments in a country. For this group of study, the existing literature
focuses on either the internal or external factors that lead to the policy diffusion.
Traditionally, the domestic conditions could strongly dominate the policy adoption within
its jurisdiction, so when people analyze the adoption of a policy innovation in a
jurisdiction, the internal factors are usually considered. In numerous empirical studies,
these internal factors, such as ideological position and prior beliefs (Gilardi, 2010;
Grossback et al., 2004), socioeconomic conditions (Walker, 1969) , election period
(Berry & Berry, 1990, 1992), the character or capacity of the leaders (Teodoro, 2009),
have been demonstrated their significant roles in the adoption of policy innovation.
However, the domestic determinants alone could not explain the story of policy diffusion
as a whole.
Walker opened a window to explore the diffusion of innovations from the external
factors, namely, the “regional reference groups”. In his pioneering study, Walker found
that in each of the regional clusters, the states usually followed the comparable leading
state to adopt a new program. Followed this study, Gray (1973) analyzed the adoption of
a new policy from the interaction between the adopters and the potential adopters. By
analyzing the cumulative frequencies of states adopting the law in the areas of civil rights,
welfare, and education, she pointed out that various issues could have different diffusion
patterns which had not revealed significant variations in Walker’s study, and a state may
adopt policies in various arenas with distinctive speeds. Even though Walker (1973)
criticized this article as its “completely intermixed population” did not take the regional
barriers (namely, whether there is an effective communication channel between two
states from different broader regions) into consideration and may not provide stable
feature of states’ innovative capacity, these two studies did pioneer the policy innovation
analysis from the perspective of the regional factor, namely, how the policy adoption of a
state is influenced by the regional leader or previous adopters. Influenced by their
valuable explorations, many following studies have emphasized the importance of the
neighbor’s policy adoption, either the neighboring state or local governments within a
country or the neighboring country (Baybeck et al., 2011; Berry & Berry, 1990, 1992;
4
Boehmke & Witmer, 2004; Chien & Ho, 2011; Clark, 2009; Cohen-Vogel & Ingle, 2007;
Linos, 2011; McLendon et al., 2005).
It is worth mentioning that Berry and Berry’s study (1990, 1992) on the diffusion of
state lottery and tax collection unified the internal determinants model and regional
diffusion model and combined the internal characters (i.e. the political, economic, and
social factors) and the regional influence together, by using the event history analysis
(EHA). Based on Mohr’s analysis of organizational innovation, they proposed that an
organization’s motivation to adopt an innovation is affected by its internal characters as
well as the information of other organizations, since the obstacle, namely, uncertainty,
that it may face can be overcome by the resources such as the information of relative
innovation practice by other organizations.
However, what should be noticed is that the influence of the neighbors may not always
be autonomous, the catalysis by the third party as a facilitator or a communication
channel is thus necessary for the diffusion. In terms of the cross national policy diffusion,
overwhelming studies have highlighted the function of international organizations in
policy diffusion because the international organizations convey valuable information
(Cao, 2009, 2012), and also the less-developed countries are more likely to rely on the
financial aid from the international organizations, such as the World Health Organization
(Clark, 2009). In additional to the international organizations, some transnational
corporations can also promote such diffusion by coercing the host country to adopt a
certain policy (Dolowitz & Marsh, 1996). These outside promoters have largely
accelerated the spread of innovative policies.
Surely, such outside promotions by the third parties not only exist in the cross-national
policy diffusion, but also exist in the domestic policy diffusion, which is the focal point
of this study, as well. Policy entrepreneurs play a significant role in the process of the
diffusion of innovation, since they are the people “who are willing to invest their
resources in pushing their pet proposals, are responsible for prompting important people
to pay attention and coupling solutions to problems” (Kingdon, 1984, p. 21). For instance,
Mintrom (1997) stated that the presence and action of policy entrepreneurs can
significantly increase the probability of the state legislative approval of school choice,
5
even consider the potential determinants, such as state politics, the choice in neighbor
states. As a brunch of policy entrepreneur, the behaviors of the bureaucrats have drawn
some scholars’ attention. Some empirical research shows that the governments which
tend to hire the chiefs from other organizations and the diagonal promoted bureaucrats
are more likely to make the policy innovations (Teodoro, 2009).
Another important type of policy diffusion is vertical diffusion, which emphasize the
influence of the federal or superior governments on the state/local governments. Berry
and Berry (2007) maintained that national government plays the analogous role to the
“widely respected leader state”, while the former one has more instruments to intervene
the local policies. These instruments include administrative mandates and creating
financial incentives. Daley and Garand (2005) made a contribution on exploring the
determinants of variation in the strength of state hazardous waste programs. They
examined how the action of the federal government (i.e. financial support) as long as the
spillover effect between state governments and the internal determinants, such as problem
severity, the state political and economic conditions, and the interest group pressure, can
affect the policymaking in one state. Besides the financial incentive, Karch (2006)
examined how the national legislations affect the state-level enactment of policy
innovations under no coercive pressure or financial stimulation, which is called catalytic
control by him. He maintained that the influences of national intervention on the state
innovation are determined by whether the national intervention lowers, or raises, or has
no impact on the obstacle. And he continued to study whether the national activities, such
as the president’s national televised address and national wide debate, can significantly
increase the probability that states would introduce a relative agenda-setting (Karch,
2012). Interestingly, Shipan and Volden found that the release of the state law on
antismoking will decrease the probability that a city in that state to adopt a same law
(Shipan & Volden, 2008), which implies that centralization may become an obstacle for
the local policy innovation (Shipan & Volden, 2012).
Besides the research above, some other scholars pay attention to the bottom-up policy
diffusion (Clavier, 2010; Shipan & Volden, 2006). For example, Shipan and Volden
(2006) tested the city-to-state diffusion as well as the state-to-state and national-to-state
6
diffusion by examining the diffusion of antismoking laws passed between 1975 and 2000.
They maintained that the legislative professionalism of a state and policy advocates at the
state level would affect the probability of the statewide adoption of a local law. These
multilevel diffusion studies open up our minds in studying policy diffusion analysis.
However, when analyzing the influence of federal government, these limited studies
overlook the interaction between the national intervention and the internal factors of the
states government.
2.2 The mechanisms of policy diffusion and its conditions
The popular determinants discussed above provide a space to further detect the driving
force of policy diffusion. The scholars also endeavor to detect the mechanisms of policy
diffusion. They either use these mechanisms as independent variables to explain the
features of policy diffusion, such as the temporal or conditional diffusion (Shipan &
Volden, 2008), policy adoption and expansion (Boehmke & Witmer, 2004), or detect the
factors determining the diffusion or adoption of an innovation under a certain mechanism
(Baybeck et al., 2011; Berry & Berry, 1990; Gilardi, 2010). In general, as Shipan and
Volden (2008) presented, the mechanisms of policy diffusion include social learning,
competition, coercion, and imitation. Social learning always refers to that a policy in one
region or organization is adopted by another region or organization, since they meet
similar problems and difficulties, or the adopters admire to the success policy outcome of
others. Because of the limited time, intelligence, and information, just as Lindblom said,
the existing knowledge of the regarding issue is important for the decision makers
(Lindblom, 1959), so they tend to adopt the policy solving the similar issues as theirs. In
terms of the competition mechanism, it usually happens under the situation when two
regions or organizations compete for scarce resources. In this situation, the adoption of
policy innovation is tried to overcome the negative externalities (Shipan & Volden, 2008).
Boehmke and Witmer (2004) distinguished the mechanisms of social learning and
economic competition in the process of diffusion. They argued that the social learning
theory is usually suitable to those states which are searching for the solutions to the
problems that they encountered, while economic competition mechanism is always
7
related to the policies which are pushed by other states' pressure, such as lost business,
tax revenue. Moreover, the coercion mechanism states that a region or organization
adopts a policy coerced by another region or organization in exchange of acquiring
relative aid or avoiding the penalties. Finally, the pioneering members are likely to be
imitated and followed by other membership in a stable group. That is, the followers just
want to “copy the actions of another in order to look like other” (Shipan & Volden, 2008).
Most of these explanations on horizontal policy diffusion are under the conditions of
Tiebout model 1, while those vertical diffusions are analyzed under the federal system in
which there is a clear scope between the power of the federal and state governments. For
example, state governments learn new policy from other states to win votes from their
residents. Also, the competition is possible since the local residents could “vote by feet”
by freely moving from one state to another. This is a quite decentralized system which is
supposed that the governments at the lower tiers have better information on local
preference and conditions. Hence, the local governments could provide the public goods
reflecting the preferences of the local residents to achieve economic efficiency (Oates,
1972, pp. 11-12; Tiebout, 1956) and have a quick action on local affairs (Rondinelli,
Nellis, & Cheema, 1983) once they enjoy the decision-making and fiscal autonomy and
take the responsibility within the regions. This is based on the assumptions of high
political accountability and consistently aggregated preferences in a locality. However, as
Bardhan (2002) argued, the assumptions for Tiebout model, such as population mobility,
mechanisms of political accountability, similar administrative capacity across different
government tiers, are too stringent for the developing countries. Consequently, it is
necessary to
analyze
the diffusion
process
in
developing
countries
whose
decentralizations are usually incomplete. The practice in China, the largest developing
country in the world, may provide us a further understanding on the diffusion process in
an incomplete decentralized system.
1
Tiebout model is a model on local expenditure proposed by Tiebout in 1956. It argues that local
expenditure could be more adequately reflected the local preference than the national level based on the
following assumptions. They are: full mobility of the voters, full knowledge of the local issues of the voters,
large number of communities, no restrictions on employment opportunities, diseconomies between
communities, having and keeping optimum size of the communities. (Tiebout, 1956)
8
2.3 Policy innovation and diffusion in China
A sprawling literature on policy innovation in China has been published in Chinese
journals since 2000, which probably resulted from the initiation of the prize for the
innovation of the Chinese local governments. Compared with the empirical studies on
policy diffusion among the local governments in the U.S. and other different countries,
these researches lack the empirical analysis for the diffusion of a specific policy
innovation. However, they could provide some intuitionistic knowledge on the practice in
China. The motivations of the local governors, such as promotion (B. Wang, 2009;
Jiannan Wu, Ma, & Yang, 2007), the desire to innovate, and the pressure from the society
(G. Chen & Li, 2009; He, 2011; Jiannan Wu et al., 2007; X. Yang, 2008) are usually
mentioned. Also, the innovations could vary subject to geographical areas. Although the
proportion of innovations in one region is related to its level of economic development (B.
Wang, 2009), it shows that the eastern area is the most active region in policy innovation
followed by the western provinces, while the middle region is surprisingly the least active
(He, 2011; Jiannan Wu et al., 2007). Besides, some scholars find that the governments in
city and county levels are more likely to have innovative policies (He, 2011; Jiannan Wu
et al., 2007). Nevertheless, little attention was paid to the diffusion of these innovations.
Fortunately, several recent studies could help us to draw a big picture on the diffusion
process in China.
Policy experimentation is an important policy practice in China. It defined as a policy
process “in which experimenting units try out a variety of methods and processes to find
imaginative solutions to predefined tasks or to new challenges that emerge during
experimental activity” (Heilmann, 2008). It differs from the traditional policy diffusion or
spontaneous policy diffusion that the scholars usually studied; Rather, just as Heilmann
said, it is “a purposeful and coordinated activity geared to producing novel policy options”
in which the local experiences or innovation is the important resources for the national
policy formulation (Heilmann, 2008). Even though with these discrepancies, however,
the studies of policy experimentations do contain the same attributes to the diffusion of
policy innovation. In Rogers (1962)’s definition, there are four key elements for diffusion:
an innovation, communicated channels, time, and social system. Since there is a sequence
of time for different jurisdiction to adopt a specific innovative policy in the social system,
9
and the propaganda of the central government is a strong communication channel, policy
experimentation should be regarded as a special kind of policy diffusion.
In his research, Heilmann argued that “experimentation under hierarchy”, the pattern
of experimental governance in China, did and do stimulate the socioeconomic and even
some political changes in China (Heilmann, 2008). His works contribute to the
explanation of how experimentation itself works in China. Three types of China’s
experimentation are given by him, which are experimental regulation, experimental
points, and experimental zones. And China’s experimentation-based policy cycle is as
follows.
Figure 1 China's experimentation-based policy cycle
Source: Heilmann, 2008
Heilmann’s finding in economic area has been verified by the research on policy
diffusion in other areas, such as public service and social welfare, in China. Foster (2004)
made a case study on the diffusion process of "Service Promise System" (fuwu chengnuo
zhi). Though it was initiated under the pressure of the masses, which is different from
Heilmann’s studies, it shows somewhat similar way of the spread of the policy. Namely,
local officials posit a new policy program through the way of policy learning; with a
10
good performance, such a policy program may further draw the attention of the provincial
leaders and even relative central officials. Hence, the higher levels of governments tended
to regard this policy innovation as a model, and promoted this policy to the governments
or agents in other areas or sectors, so that the policy diffusion could happen. Recently,
based on the interplay between central and local governments, Shi (2012) used three
types of diffusion in China, which are coercion, competition, and pre-emption diffusions,
to explain the local activism and national unification in the process of social policies
diffusion.
All the studies above emphasize the importance of local pioneering practice or
experiments and the general coordination and further promotion of the central
governments, yet the intervention of the central government was discussed in a general
way. In a newest research, it identifies two different mechanisms of this central-local
interaction, “mandatory policy diffusion” and “championship policy diffusion” (X. Zhu,
forthcoming). According to Zhu, these two mechanisms are determined by two
intervention methods of the central or superior government, which are called intervention
with administrative command, and the contest with performance evaluation. For the
former one, since under the unitary instruction of the central or superior government, all
the local governments should adopt the same innovative policy; while for the latter one,
the local governments tend to choose some different policy instrument with the same
policy goal, so that they would not lose the champion as followers.
These scholars’ researches provide us valuable knowledge and a way to study policy
diffusion in China. However, there are two major weaknesses for these studies. First, they
discussed the diffusion process in a general and more descriptive way that pointed out the
importance of local pioneering actions and national coordination. Nevertheless, the
general national factor cannot explain the variations of localities in adopting a new policy.
Therefore, with no analysis on the detailed conditions of the localities, we still cannot
understand why and how some regions adopt certain policy faster than the others. Second,
these studies overemphasize the central intervention in the diffusion process. The
interaction between the central and local governments is ignored. Despite a recent
research analyzing the driving force of the diffusion of police departments’
microblogging in China from the perspective of organization innovation (Ma, 2013), it
11
discusses the predominance of the upper government in general without paying attention
to the possible variations in the effect of the upper government influence depending on
the local conditions.
To fill the existing gaps, the research intends to answer the following questions. What
are the key factors that determine the adoption of policy innovation concerning HPF
among Chinese local governments (cities)? How do central and local governments
influence diffusion of policy innovations in this process? Why are some local
governments more likely to be positively affected by the central government to adopt the
policy innovations? By answering these questions, this study tries to explore the specific
factors that influence policy diffusion in China. Shipan and Volden (2012) has
hypothesized that decentralization may be more suitable for policy diffusion than
centralization; however, the meticulous conditions should be scrutinized.
12
Chapter 3
Argument and Hypotheses
In this chapter, I answer three questions First, what are the key factors that determine
the adoption of policy innovation concerning HPF among Chinese local governments
(cities)? Second, how do central and local governments influence diffusion of policy
innovations in this process? Third, why are some local governments more likely to be
positively affected by the central government to adopt the policy innovations? In the
nutshell, my answers to the above questions are as follows. Under the conditions of
incomplete decentralization, both national intervention and local level capacity and
interests determine the adoption of a policy innovation. In present-day China, the local
governments gain the autonomy to some extent that enable them to represent their
interests in local decision making process, while they still have strong accountability to
the central and upper level government which implies the national intervention is
important. As for the case of the Housing Provident Fund (HPF) policy, this chapter
hypothesized that the central government promotion and local level capacity and interests,
such as the local revenue, the performance of the enterprises, and the average income of
the employees, could together determine the diffusion of HPF policy. Furthermore, as the
localities have different interests, national intervention may have various influences on
these localities. For those localities which have stronger incentive to initiate the HPF
policy, they would be more likely to be affected by the promotion the central government.
Thus, national intervention could magnify the influence of the local level capacity and
interests.
3.1 Incomplete decentralization and its accountability locus
Last chapter has argued that the full aspects of decentralization, which is an important
condition for the existing policy diffusion analysis, may not be suitable for most
developing countries as the decentralization in the majority of them is incomplete.
Decentralization means “the transfer or delegation of legal and political authority to plan,
make decisions and manage public functions from the central government and its
13
agencies to field organizations of those agencies, subordinate units of government, semiautonomous public corporations, areawide or regional development authorities;
functional authorities, autonomous local governments, or nongovernmental organizations”
(Rondinelli, 1980, p. 137). Decentralization, which is a relative concept to centralization,
was raised to solve the problems in the later system (Schneider, 2003). It is a continuous
variable rather than a constant. That is, any points between the two ends (extreme
centralization and anarchy) of the continuum of decentralization could be regarded as
“decentralization”. On this continuum, there are mainly different degree of
decentralization, including deconcentration, delegation, and devolution (Rondinelli,
1980). Among these, deconcentration is the minimal degree of decentralization, while
devolution is the most substantial one. The World Bank (2004) makes a detailed
discrimination on these three degrees of decentralization. In a deconcentration system,
the officials at the local level are the employees of the central government rather than of
the local government itself (World Bank, 2004). Therefore, these officials should have
stronger upward accountability than the downward. As for the officials in the delegation
system, they could be the employees of central or local government; they have autonomy
to some extent, while they should also fully or partially be accountable to the center
(World Bank, 2004). Compared with the first two forms, devolution endows the localities
autonomy to the largest extent. The localities in this system could be regarded as an
independent or separate power with little or no direct control of the central government
(Rondinelli, 1980). This research calls the first two forms of decentralization as
“incomplete decentralization”.
As we can see, decentralization in the U.S. belongs to the forms of devolution. It has
the separation power between the federal and state government, high downward
accountability because of the political decentralization and local elections, and free
movement among the states. All these conditions are the foundation of the multitudinous
studies on policy diffusion. However, for most developing countries, local autonomy is
limited. Even with the process of decentralization, the local governments have to partly
or largely rely on their counterpart national government. For many of them, the local
officials are appointed by the central or upper level government, which may impair the
downward accountability in decentralization. Thus, for most of the developing countries,
14
the subnational governments “are not wholly controlled by the central government but are
ultimately accountable to it”, which could be characterized as principal-agent relationship
between the central and local government (Litvack, Ahmad, & Bird, 1998, p. 9). This
accountability locus, as an important premise, may significantly influence the diffusion
process in most of the developing countries.
3.2 Principal-agent theory and policy diffusion in incomplete decentralization
Principal-agent theory is an important branch of literature that focuses on organization
control. In his seminal article, Moe (1984) introduced the principal-agent theory in
political science studies. Since then, the principal-agent theory has been widely used to
discuss the organization control from various perspective, such as bureaucracy (e.g.
Gailmard, 2010; K. Yang, 2009), the relationship between politics and administrative
system (e.g. Worsham & Gatrell, 2005), and even the relationship between the states and
international organizations (e.g. Worsham & Gatrell, 2005). As what has just been talked
about, it also provides us an angle to analyze the central-local relations under the
conditions of “incomplete decentralization”.
According to this theory, principals and agents usually have distinct interests, since
they need to make the rational choice for themselves; Also, the agents have incentives to
hide the information from principals to maximize their own interests (Miller, 1992, p. 2;
Moe, 1984). Therefore, “information asymmetries” and “conflict of interest” are the two
main reasons for the “agency problem” (Moe, 1984). To reduce the “agency problem”,
the principals need to build monitoring devices and incentive structures to ensure the
agents work in a proper way.
In a decentralized system that locality has limited autonomy and high upward
responsibility, the central or upper level government and the local governments together
form a principal-agent relationship. On the one hand, because of the endowment of
autonomy through decentralization, the local governments would like to follow their own
interests when they make a decision. Also, the subordinates may not always behave as
what their superior expected. So whether adopting a new policy or not is highly likely to
15
be based on the local level capacity and interests. However, different from the
counterparts under the full decentralization that have strong downward political
accountability, the local interests here are not necessary to be the preferences of the local
resident. It is more likely that the local political elites and strong interest groups dominate
the local interests. On the other hand, the central government as the principal could use
the monitor system and incentive control to affect and adjust the local behaviors. It means
that the central government could promote the diffusion and adoption of a policy by
various instruments. It is interesting that the central government could also use the preemptive strategy to promote the adoption of a new policy among the localities.
Consequently, this research proposes that the local level capacity and interests and
national behavior would together affect the diffusion of policy innovation in such as
system.
However, even though these two factors could induce the adoption of innovation, it
does not necessarily mean that the national promotion has an equal effect on all the
localities. Since the local governments have information advantages, as the principalagent theory has argued, they could take advantage of the resources for their own
interests. Assuming that the central government uses similar instruments to control the
subnational governments, the localities having stronger local level capacity and interests
are more likely to be affected by the promotion of the central government.
3.3 Central-local relations in China
The following of this study will use the case of China, the largest developing country in
the world, to analyze how policies are diffused in such an incomplete decentralization
system. Therefore, this section will deploy a general picture of the central-local relations
in China from the political, fiscal, and administrative perspectives.
First, little political autonomy has been given to the localities. In Bland’s definition,
political decentralization refers to that the local governments could get the autonomy
through local election and pluralism party system (Bland, 2010, p. 48). However, in
China, the Communist Party of China (CPC) has the “political leadership (zhengzhi
16
lingdao)” towards the People’s Congress at each level. Most candidates of the important
officials, such as the mayors or the head of each department, need to be nominated and
recommended by the Party Committee at each jurisdiction; based on the list of
nomination provided by the Party Committee and discussion of the deputies of People’s
Congress, the presidium of the corresponding People’s Congress determines the formal
list of the candidates; at last, the deputies of the People’s Congress “elect” nearly every
candidate within the list (G. Zhu, 2008, pp. 130-131). Hence, the “election” at each unit
was under the control of the Party Committee, which is to say that there is little political
autonomy at the localities in China. As such, the local government has limited downward
political accountability to their residents.
Such an institution of “election” is directly influenced by the basic personnel principle
in China, namely “party controls the cadres” (G. Zhu, 2008, p. 127). It could further
affect the administrative autonomy of the localities. Human resources management is
usually an important angle to analyze the division of administrative autonomy between
the central and local governments. Many scholars believe that China's centralized power
have been even strengthened through the nomenklatura system or the cadre management
system (Edin, 2003; Huang, 1996; Landry, 2008; Sheng, 2005). The implementation of
performance measurement, which uses political integrity (de), competence (neng),
diligence (qin), and performance (ji) as four main criteria to judge a cadre's achievement,
is one of the most influential methods for the central government to control the actions of
the local officials. This judgment may influence the career path of the cadres further.
According to Edin, the key elements in these four criteria are political integrity and
performance. As for political integrity, it emphasizes the cadres' political loyalty to the
CPC. This criterion has the veto power on the cadres' achievement. That is to say, if a
cadre does not accomplish this criterion, which are usually related to the political issues,
he will not be promoted or could even be punished no matter how well he did to achieve
the other three criteria (Edin, 2003). In contrast, a well performance, especially the
economic performance, will earn bonus and political benefits for the cadres (Caulfield,
2006; Landry, 2008), while poor economic performance does not have a strong negative
influence on a cadre though that will be hard for him to climb higher in the bureaucratic
hierarchy (Landry, 2008). As a consequence, with strictly obeying the central instructions
17
on certain coercive policy arenas such as “birth control”, the cadres actively participate in
the promotion tournament through the way of facilitating local economic development
(Zhou, 2007). Besides the promotion system, cyclicality, administrative uniformity,
tenure length and correlations, and governance types are also used to demonstrate the
high degree of central control (Huang, 1996). Despite some scholar argued that the
provincial cooperation is important for the implementation of nomenklatura system 2, it
cannot be denied that the cadre management system is an effective central control over
the local officials and improve the upward accountability of the local governments.
However, the performance competition has to be based on the certain degree of local
autonomy. Also, the localities have to gain some discretion to fully develop their
comparative advantages. After 1979, the local governments began to acquire some fiscal
and decision-making autonomy. Many scholars regard this decentralization as an
important driving force for China’s economy (Caulfield, 2006; Montinola, Qian, &
Weingast, 1996; Oi, 1992), since this changing encourages the local governments to carry
major functional responsibilities on economic affairs and to aim at promoting economic
development. Hence, it encourages the local governments not only to play an active role
on those local affairs without the coercion instruments from the central government
(Zheng & Wu, 1995), but also to take more responsibility within its jurisdiction (Li,
1998). Even though there is a significant tendency of fiscal recentralization after the tax
reform in 1994 3, the local governments still have the expenditure autonomy which can
reflect the preference of the localities. For example, in 2010, the ratio of the expenditure
of the central and local governments is 17.8% to 82.2% (National Bureau of Statistics of
China, 2011) and the local governments and people’s congress play the main role in local
budgeting.
2
For this point, please see Zheng (2007, pp. 98-105). By illustrating the procedure of cadre selection, he
pointed out the importance of provincial leaders in the process of selecting leading cadres, as they play the
role of providing information.
3
The 1994 taxation reform in China was a strong recentralization on the fiscal autonomy of the provincial
governments. It established the Tax Assignment System (fenshuizhi) (TAS) which specifies the way that
revenues are shared between the central and provincial governments. As a result of the 1994 reforms,
Beijing dramatically increased its share of tax revenue, and this ratio has kept increasing during the last two
decades.
18
In sum, the central-local relations in China just match the principal-agent relationship
in an incomplete decentralized system that has been analyzed in last session. On the one
hand, the local governments enjoy the decision-making and fiscal autonomy and take the
responsibility within the regions. Thus, the localities have opportunities to follow their
own interest when they are making decisions. However, because of the lack of effective
local election, the downward accountability is low and the local interests are more likely
to be captured by the local political elites and relative interest groups. On the other hand,
strong political and cadre control may play as effective instruments to affect and adjust
the behaviors of the local officials. Therefore, local governments would follow the
instructions of the central government.
3.4 Policy Diffusion of Housing Provident Fund in China
Based on the discussion above, this research intends to provide an explanation of the
diffusion of the Housing Provident Fund (HPF) policy among the municipalities in China.
However, before focusing on the case of HPF policy, we need to take a look at the large
context of urban housing reform in China during the 1980s and early 1990s.
3.4.1 Urban housing reform in China
Since 1980s, China launched a full aspect economic reform to transit from centrally
planned economy to a market economy. The arenas of agricultural operation system in
rural area, state-owned enterprises system, banking system, and fiscal and taxation
system all experienced such a transformation (Jinglian Wu, 2005). Housing reform was
unfolded against this background.
Before 1978, China, like many other socialist countries, carried out the centrally
planned socialist economies. The national government had the overall power on resources
allocation and economic development. Under the slogan of “production first, living
conditions second”, Chinese government carried out a development model of high saving
and low consumptions to promote the industrialization (Cheng, 1999, p. 4; Zang, 1994, p.
2). In this process, the wages of the workers and staff was squeezed to an extremely low
level. To compensate the low wage system, the government has provided the state
19
employees with high social welfare, such as housing, medical care (Zang, 1994, p. 3). In
other words, the subsidy for housing that should be included in the salaries of the
employees was used by the state to finance new house building and then freely
distributed to the state employees (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 157). Therefore, under the
old system, housing was primarily a social welfare and income subsidy rather than a
commodity in China (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 6). The governments and work units
(danwei) were the main suppliers for the housing. Usually, “the central government
appropriated funds, and local governments and state-owned enterprises constructed the
housing units” (Huque, 2005, p. 53). More specifically, the central government took in
charge of the general housing plan and funds allocation; the city government took the
responsibilities of providing housing and allocated house funding within its jurisdiction;
and the government-owned institutions (shiye danwei) and enterprises directly controlled
the distribution and management of housing within their public housing stocks (Y. Wang
& Murie, 1999, p. 7). As for the residents, they only needed to pay an extremely low rent
of 0.13 yuan/sq (Fong, 1989, p. 34). The rents on average “accounted for some 1 percent
of a worker’s annual income” (Huque, 2005). However, the beneficiary of the public
housing could only be “the officially registered urban residents and public sector
employees”, while other “unofficial migrants, rural farmers and the young unemployed”
were excluded from the system (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 8).
In the initial period of time, this system was geared to the economic system of China
(Cheng, 1999, p. 4). However, the problems became obvious and severe with its further
development. First, it brought a severe financial burden to the government and negatively
influenced the efficiency of the state owned enterprises (SOE). Statistics show that before
1978 the government spent about RMB 35 billion on housing construction and
maintenance while only received RMB 1 billion from rents (J. Chen, Hao, & Stephens,
2010). The rent income was even not enough for the simple maintenance and repairs (Y.
Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 120), let alone to establish a sustainable cycle for housing
development. Second, the boomed urban population intensified housing shortage. By
1978, housing shortage had reached 1billion in all major cities (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999,
p. 101). According to the national housing survey conducted at the end of 1985, “25.6
percent of the urban households (105.4 million households) still had difficult housing
20
problems” (Zang, 1994, p. 10). Moreover, there was a severe unequal distribution of
housing among different work units. The large and well-performed work units can
usually provide relative sufficient housing for their employees than those smaller ones (Y.
Wang & Murie, 1999, pp. 108-109, 118-119). And corruption often happened in the
distribution process (Zang, 1994, p. 6).
According to this, in 1978 and 1980, Deng Xiaoping subsequently made two speeches
on housing issues regarding house provision pluralism, especially the sale and rent
increasing of housing, which is regarded as the preclude of housing reform (Jia & Liu,
2007). Based on the speech, in June of 1980, the CPC Central Committee and the State
Council endorsed and relayed the “Report Outline of the National Working Meeting on
the Capital Construction” (quanguo jiben jianshe gongzuo huiyi huibao tigang). In this
document, housing commercialization has been firstly mentioned, which indicates the
launching of the housing reform (Asia-Pacific Finance and Development Center, 2011).
It is worth to notice that the housing reform is more like an economic reform rather than
solely welfare reform, as it concentrated on the distorted economic and distribution
system. It was one of the three major economic reform programs for 1980s China (Zang,
1994, p. 1).
Unlike the radical changes of housing institution in socialist East Europe, China’s
housing reform experienced an incremental process with repeated policy experiments,
adjustments, and further promotions (Lee, 2000). The initial exploration of the
affordability of households for commercialization was practiced in Xi’an, Nanning,
Liuzhou and Wuzhou in 1979 (Huque, 2005). Later, four cities, Zhenzhou, Changzhou,
Shashi, and Siping, initialized a pilot program of sale of new housing units (shidian
shoufang) in 1982, which intended to sell a small number of new housing units to the
individuals (Fong, 1989). In this experimentation, individuals only needed to pay onethird of the total price, while the city government and the work units had to equally pay
the other two-third of the price (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 144). In 1986, Yantai,
Tangshan, Bengbu, Changzhou, and Jiangmen implemented a pilot project to increase the
housing rent by issuing special housing coupon, which could be used as a subsidy of the
increased rent (Huque, 2005). These programs have been further promoted to other cities
21
after the initial experiments. However, even though a lot of endeavor has been put on
housing reform, state work units continued to dominate urban housing provision in China
until 1990s (Junhua Chen, Guo, & Wu, 2011). Also, because of the generally low wages,
the experiments of rent increasing in 1980s were not entirely successful (Lee, 2000).
Based on the experience of the pilot points, in 1988, the State Council promulgated
“Implementation Plan for Gradual Reform of the Urban Housing System” (guanyu zai
quanguo chengzhen fenqi fenpi tuixing zhufang zhidu gaige de shishi fang’an) in the first
national working conference of housing reform. The objective of this reform was to
increase housing rent, to establish housing fund, to sell the public housing, and to
establish housing finance. More importantly, this document states that the following
housing reform should be led by the provinces themselves, while the central government
mainly takes responsibility to guide the general reform direction and promote the
successful experiences rather than direct the specific pilot projects and cities. Thus, the
localities gained the autonomy to choose their own policy instruments. The innovation
and diffusion of housing provident fund policy was born against this background.
3.4.2 An explanation on the diffusion of the housing provident fund policy
Because of the high pressure of inflation from 1988 and political unrest in 1989, the
housing reform experienced a slower pace shortly (Cheng, 1999, p. 9; Y. Wang & Murie,
1999, p. 150). In February of 1991, Shanghai produced its own implementation plan for
housing reform which was soon approved by the General Office of State Council. In this
proposal, housing provident fund is raised as one of the core content 4. It is a form of long
time compulsory housing saving shared by employees and employers together: both
parties should contribute an equal percentage of the employees’ salary to the funds by
month, which are under the employees’ personal accounts; and the HPF only could be
withdrawn when the employees purchase or build their own housing, or when they get
retired (Shanghai Municiple Government, 1991). In October of the same year, the
Steering Group of Housing System Reform promulgated the “Opinions on
Comprehensive Reform of the Urban Housing System”, which updated the 1988 plan and
4
The contents of the reform proposal in Shanghai include establishing the housing provident fund, raising
housing rent while giving the subsidies, selling the housing at discount prices, etc.
22
formally extended the housing reform to the entire country (Huque, 2005). Interestingly,
the HPF policy then frequently appeared on the reform proposal of many other cities,
such as Beijing, Tianjin, Qingdao, after it was initiated by Shanghai. In 1994, State
Council promulgated the “Decision on Deepening the Urban Housing System Reform”
(guowuyuan guanyu shenhua chengzhen zhufang zhidu gaige de jueding). The central
government first formally promoted the Housing Provident Fund policy and required all
the governments, public organizations, and enterprises to establish this institution. Thus,
a new wave of the adoption of HPF policy was coming. Later, State Council released the
“Suggestions on Enhancing the Management of Housing Provident Fund” (guanyu
jiaqiang zhufang gongjijin guanli de yijian) in 1996. And in 1998, State Council required
each provinces and departments of central government to make a full implementation and
improvement of the Housing Provident Fund institutions in its official documents (State
Council, 1998). Later, State Council released the Regulation on Management of Housing
Provident Fund (zhufang gongjijin guanli tiaoli) in 1999 and revised it in 2002, which
indicates the institutionalization of the HPF policy. We can see a clear expansion and
development trace of the HPF policy.
One thing should be noticed here is that the policy goals of HPF kept changing since it
was born (Taffin, Friedemann, & Kim, 2011, p. 6). The original goal of the HPF was to
“enhance housing affordability for urban residents” through compulsory saving (Taffin et
al., 2011, p. 6) and to solve the problem of the shortage of housing development fund (Y.
Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 160). In the early 1990s, welfare housing still played the
dominated role. At that time, the loan of HPF was a kind of construction loan, which
mainly opened to the work units for housing investment or large housing projects for low
income families (Cong, 2008, p. 84). Thus, the capital from the HPF helped to reduce the
financial burden and supported them to construct more housing for their employees.
However, the function of HPF had a drastic change in 1999, since welfare housing
system was totally abandoned in that year. The Regulation on Management of Housing
Provident Fund in 1999 clearly defined that the housing provident fund could only be
loaned to the individuals since then (State Council, 1999). Therefore, the HPF became an
important strategy to create a market-oriented housing finance system through which the
contributors could purchase a home by loaning at a low interest rate (Taffin et al., 2011, p.
23
6). Today, the HPF Scheme plays three functions, housing finance (i.e. releasing
mortgage lending to individuals), pension funds and housing policy instrument (Taffin et
al., 2011, p. 3). Nevertheless, as the generation and diffusion of the HPF policy is
important to this study, its initial goal and what happened during time period from 1991
to 1999 are the main focuses of this research.
As what has been talked in the sessions before, national intervention and local level
capacity are the two main factors that affect the adoption of innovation of a locality. As
for the factor of local capacity, it is a little bit complicated in this case. Since the
decentralization in China is incomplete and there is no free and fair election in the
locality, the local government has little downward accountability to the local residents.
Thus, the interests of ordinary urban local residents or employees could hardly directly
influence the decision of the government, especially at the time with the underdeveloped
internet. On the contrary, the local political elite and interest groups may have a more
important influence on the adoption of HPF policy. For this case, relative municipal
government and state enterprises are the two main bodies that should be analyzed.
First, the local government was the main provider of public housing and took the
responsibility for decision making on housing reform within its jurisdiction. What should
be noticed is that the government played two roles in this process. On the one hand, the
government itself is a work unit and has its own employees that it also need to and
usually first to consider their benefits and interests. On the other hand, it is also the
governor of the territory that should consider the overall conditions of the locality as a
whole. As a work unit, the municipal government, especially the officials of the
government themselves, should welcome this new HPF policy. Since the welfare system
was not abandoned at that time and the officers in government usually had better housing
conditions, to adopt this new policy may mean that the government could win their
employees with extra benefits. However, to government and government-owned
institutions 5 , their contributions to the housing provident fund should be appropriated
5
Government-owned institutions refer to those organizations that provide public services under
government direction. Their running is either fully or partly supported by the government budget revenue.
For most cases, the salaries of their employees are appropriated by the budget revenue. Public schools and
hospitals in China belong to this kind of institutions.
24
from the local revenue. Thus, the local revenue could positively influence the decision of
the government on the adoption of the HPF policy. Moreover, as a local governor, the
local government also needs to consider the affordability of the citizens, more
specifically, the ordinary employees. So here come the two hypotheses.
Hypothesis 1: The higher the local revenue of a city is, the more likely it is to adopt
the HPF policy.
Hypothesis 2: The higher the average income of the employees of a city is, the more
likely it is to adopt the HPF policy.
Furthermore, the situation and attitudes of the interest groups are also important in the
government’s consideration. After 1978, the government encouraged the work units and
individuals to play more roles on housing investment with the work units gaining more
financial and management power (Y. Wang & Murie, 1999, p. 156). Even though the
housing provident fund provided the enterprises broader sources of housing investment
that they can loan money from, the premise of the implementation of this policy is that
the enterprises have the capability to afford this compulsory payment first. Thus, the
performances of the enterprises are important factors to affect their behaviors. So the
enterprises’ economic performance of a region could also positively influence the
adoption of the HPF policy.
Hypothesis 3: The better the enterprises’ economic performance of a city is, the more
likely that it will adopt the HPF policy.
The factor of national promotion has already been quite obvious in the process of HPF
diffusion. This study hypothesizes that the national promotion will have a positive effect
on the adoption of the HPF policy. Thus, the hypothesis is as follows.
Hypothesis 4: The stronger the national promotion is, the more likely that a locality
will adopt this policy.
In sum, a synthesized hypothesis is as follows: The higher the local revenue, the higher
the average income of the employees, the better the enterprises’ economic performance,
and stronger the national promotion, the more likely a city is to adopt the HPF policy.
25
Another thing needs to further detect is the various effects of national influence on the
policy innovation of different regions. Despite that the central-local relations in China is
more like the principal-agent relationship, it does not mean that the local government as
the agents has little autonomy other than follow the national instruction. Therefore, the
national behavior could hardly have equal influence on every locality. Those localities
have more incentive to initiate a reform could be more likely to be affected by the
national intervention. Therefore, the hypothesis is as follows.
Hypothesis 5: The effect of national promotion on HPF policy innovation could be
positively affected by the conditions of local revenue.
The hypotheses above give various determinants of the diffusion of HPF policy in
China. Next chapter will put them into operationalization, will talk about the
measurement and methodology of this study, and will show the statistic results of the
analysis.
26
Chapter 4
Empirical Analysis
This chapter operationalizes and measures the dependent, independent and control
variables and makes an empirical analysis to test the hypotheses that have been raised in
the last chapter. Since “city” is the main carrier of the HPF policy, the unit of analysis of
this study is the municipalities at (or above) the prefecture level 6 in China. As the data of
287 municipalities in China is available for 10 years from 1990 to 1999, the dataset has a
time-series cross-sectional structure. Thus, this research separately uses binary timeseries cross-section (BTSCS) analysis and survival analysis to test the hypotheses. For
BTSCS analysis, the dependent variable is the timing that a city adopted the HPF policy.
For the survival analysis, the dependent variable is the odds of HPF policy innovation. As
what has been explained, the independent variables are the national promotion, the local
revenue, the average income of employees, and the conditions of the enterprises’
economic performance. Thus, the first variable is to measure the effect of the national
intervention, while the last three are to measure the influence of the local level capacity
and interests. Also, this research generates an interaction term between national
intervention and local revenue to test the effects of the national promotion on the HPF
policy innovation under different conditions of local level capacity and interests.
4.1 Data and measurement: the dependent variables
To measure the dependent variable of the timing that a locality adopts the HPF policy in
the BTSCS analysis, I will see whether or not a city adopted the HPF policy in a certain
year during the time period from 1990 to 1999. It is a dummy variable. If it adopted it, it
will be coded as 1; otherwise, it will be coded as 0. I build the dataset of the dependent
variable based on the information from the official website of the Housing Provident
Fund Administration Center or the relative department of each city and from the
academic works. For the data of the timing that each city adopted the HPF policy, refer to
the Appendix.
6
There are four subnational tiers in China, including the provincial government, prefecture-level
government, county-level government and township government.
27
As for the survival analysis, the dependent variable is the odds of each Chinese local
government, here namely the prefecture level (or above) cities in China, adopts the HPF
policy innovation. 7
4.2 Data and measurement: the independent variables
Besides the interaction term, this research has five independent variables. The first
variable is the local revenue. Since the extra-budgetary revenue of Chinese local
government is less transparent and difficult to calculate, the variable of the local revenue
is measured by the local budgetary revenue of each city in t-1 year from 1990 to 1999.
All the data is from the China City Statistical Yearbook.
As for the variable of the average income of employees, it would be measured by the
average wage of the workers and staff in t-1 year. This is because only these state
employees were the beneficiaries of the welfare housing in the old system. Also, they
would be the first target group if the local government adopted the HPF policy, so that
their conditions may have a stronger influence on the decision of the local governments.
The data also comes from the China City Statistical Yearbook.
The variable of the enterprises’ economic performance would be measured by the
average profits of independent enterprises earned per hundred yuan of investment of a
city in t-1 year 8 . Same as the previous variables, the data is from the China City
Statistical Yearbook.
As for the measurement of the variable of the national promotion, last chapter has
talked about that the national government separately released four important documents
to promote the HPF policy since 1994. According to the argument of this research, the
promotion of the central government affects the decision making of a city. Thus, it should
also be a dichotomous variable that since 1994, the year that the central government
7
This dependent variable is generated by Stata command: “stset”.
Actually, there are several other ways to measure this variable, such as total value of output per hundred
yuan of investment. This research chooses “the profits of independent enterprises earned per hundred yuan
of investment” since its data is more completed.
8
28
began to promote the HPF policy, the value for the year t is 1; and the values before 1994
are 0.
There is an ongoing debate on the role of interaction term in logit and probit model 9.
However, this research has no intention to be involved in such a debate on methodology.
Based on the need of this study, the interaction term is added to the model. It inspects the
effects of the national promotion on the HPF policy innovation under different conditions
of local level capacity and interests. As the local governments are the main actors that
interact with central governments, this interaction term only includes the factor that
directly reflects the interest of the local government. Therefore, this variable would be
measured as the product value of national promotion in year t and local revenue in year t1, since the interest of the local governments, in this case, are directly represented by
their local revenue.
4.3 Data and measurement: the control variables
This study also needs to control several variables that could have a significant influence
on the adoption of the HPF policy. As many studies argued, local resource is an
important factor that contributes to the policy innovation of a locality (i.e. Berry & Berry,
1990). Thus, the first control variable is the administrative level of the city, because those
municipalities at higher administrative level may have more resources to adopt a new
policy. Such resources include economic resources, political advantages, and even the
tradition to be a pioneer. Hence, those municipalities at higher administrative level may
be more likely to adopt the HPF policy.
There are four administrative levels of cities in China, which are the municipalities
directly under the central government at the provincial level, the vice-provincial level
cities 10, the prefecture level cities, and the county level cities (C. Wang, 2005, p. 18).
9
Some scholars argue that the interaction term is meaningless and even misleading when using the
nonlinear models such as logit and probit (F. S. Berry & Berry, 1991; W. D. Berry, DeMeritt, & Esarey,
2010), while others persist that such interaction term is necessary when testing the conditional hypothesis
(Brambor, Clark, & Golder, 2006).
10
The vice-provincial level cities are developed from the cities specifically designated in the state plan,
which have the similar power of decision making and economic management to the provinces. In 1994, the
29
Moreover, the capitals of provinces could also gain more political or economic resources,
even though many of them are the prefecture level cities rather than the vice-provincial
level ones. Therefore, these provincial capitals could also be treated the same as the viceprovincial cities that are higher than the other prefecture level cities. In this study, the
majority of the 287 municipalities in this study are the prefecture-level cities, while there
are also 4 municipalities directly under the central government, 15 vice-provincial level
cities and 21 other provincial capitals. For this situation, I code all the prefecture level
cities as 1, code the 15 vice-provincial level cities and other 21 provincial capitals as 2,
and code the 4 municipalities directly under the central government as 3.
A related issue should be noticed is that the administrative division of China kept
changing in the time period of this study. Many prefecture-level cities in the late 1990s
were not at this level in the early 1990s. In other words, all the 287 municipalities in this
study are at the prefecture level (or above) in 1999, while some of them were upgraded to
the prefecture level during 1990s. Due to the same reason of controlling the cities’
administrative level, to control this is also important 11. The data of the administrative
division change comes from the website of administrative division. If a city upgraded to
the prefecture level in a certain year, the values of city level before that year should be 0,
while it would be coded as 1 since that specific year. For example, Guigang city in
Guangxi has been upgraded to the prefecture level city in 1995, so before 1995 its value
of the city level is 0, while it is 1 after 1995. Another example is Chongqing. It upgraded
to the municipalities directly under the central government in 1997, so before 1997 it
should be coded as 2, while after the year of 1997, the value of its city level is 3.
The number of the neighbors that adopt the HPF policy is another control variable.
According to many classical studies on policy diffusion (Baybeck et al., 2011; Berry &
Berry, 1990, 2007; Boehmke & Witmer, 2004), the neighbors’ behavior of a locality
Central Institutional Organization Commission officially assigned 16 cities as vice-provincial level cities
(Chongqing upgraded to municipalities directly under the central government in 1997). However, the legal
status of these cities is still unclear, since the vice-provincial level refers to the administrative level of the
top officials in these cities, rather than the administrative division level of the cities. (C. Wang, 2005, p. 18)
11
The administrative divisions in China, especially the prefecture level units, have experienced a drastic
change in 1990s and early 2000s. During this process, many prefecture level regions were changed into or
merged as prefecture level cities. However, as this change was happened in the same administrative
division level, it is not included in this control.
30
could significantly affect its adoption of a new policy through the way of learning,
competition, or simply imitation. Even though some scholars began to doubt the
influence` of the geographical factor (Shipan & Volden, 2012), this variable is worth to
test since no scientific evidence has demonstrated its insignificance. The neighbors’
influence on a certain city will be measured by the number of cities that adopt the HPF
policy within the same province in t-1 year. For example, there were 7 cities in Hebei
Province that has adopted the HPF policy until 1994. For the cities in Hebei Provinces,
the value of the “neighbor” variable in 1995 is 7.
Furthermore, this study also has a variable that controls the year in the BTSCS analysis.
31
Table 1 Summary Statistics for the Binary Time-series Cross-sectional Analysis
Variable
Observation
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
Timing
2745
0.605
0.489
0
1
Economic Performance
2472
1.117
1.366
-1.05
28.29
Local Revenue
2511
0.748
1.873
0.013
39.222
Average Wage
2520
0.403
0.219
0.0605
4.109
National Promotion
2870
0.6
0.49
0
1
Interaction
2511
0.491
1.717
0
39.222
City Level
2870
1.116
0.41
0
3
Neighbor
2870
6.209
5.857
0
21
Year
2870
1994.5
2.873
1990
1999
Local Level Capacity
and Interest
Control Variables
Table 1 presents the summary of the abovementioned variables for the BTSCS analysis.
We can see clearly from the table that this study uses economic performance, local
revenue, and average wage to measure the local level capacity and interests, since they
could represent the interests of local enterprises, government, and individuals,
respectively. Also, the variable of the national promotion and the interaction term
measure the effects of central government’s behavior on local policy adoption.
32
Table 2 Summary Statistics for the Survival Analysis
Variable
Observation
Mean
Std. Dev.
Min
Max
Economic Performance
1252
1.364
1.37
-1.05
21.26
Local Revenue
1272
0.518
0.952
0.0133
16.274
Average Wage
1265
0.274
0.118
0.0605
1.142
National Promotion
1481
0.269
0.443
0
1
Interaction
1272
0.096
0.32
0
4.528
City Level
1481
1.0735
0.374
0
3
Neighbor
1481
2
3.438
0
21
Local Level Capacity
and Interest
Control Variables
Table 2 shows the summary statistics for the survival analysis, which focuses on how
long subjects survive before they die. The cases in such analysis are “at risk” of
experiencing the event of HPF policy innovation. After it experienced this event, it would
be “no longer observed or is at risk of experiencing another kind of event (or returning to
the previously occupied state)” (Box-Steffensmeier & Jones, 2004, p. 7), which means it
“died”. As the dependent variable in this model is the hazard rate of the HPF innovation,
the data of each city will be observed until the case “died”. In other words, if a local
government has innovated in the year t-1, it won’t be observed in the year t. Therefore,
we can see that the observations of each variable in the survival analysis are lesser than
that in the BTSCS analysis.
4.4 Methodology
4.4.1 Methodology for Binary Time-series Cross-Sectional Analysis
The adoption of HPF policy is a longitudinal record of a city. Following the work of
Berry and Berry (1990), I will first use the binary time-series cross-sectional analysis to
test the probability that a city adopts the HPF policy. The equation is as follows:
33
=
,
+
,
+
,
+
,
+
,
+
The dependent variable
,
+
,
+ +
means the whether a city i adopted the HPF policy in
,
the year t. It is a dummy variable, it is 1 when city i adopted the HPF policy in year t;
otherwise, it is 0.
in t-1 year.
,
,
denotes that the budget revenue that the city i got
denotes that the average wage of staff and workers of the city i in
the year t-1.
denotes the average profits that the
,
independent enterprises of city i earned in the year t-1 by per hundred yuan of investment.
refers the whether or not the central government promoted the
HPF policy innovation in the year t. And
is
,
the interaction term between local revenue and national promotion.
,
,
and
are the control variables which represent the administrative level of city i
in the year t and the number of city i’s neighbors that adopted the HPF policy in the year
t-1, respectively. At last, c is a constant value and denotes the deviation value.
4.4.2 Methodology for Survival Analysis
Last model has investigated how local capacity and interests and national promotion
influence the time of HPF innovation. It would be more comprehensive to use survival
analysis to detect how these two determinants affect the speed of the local innovations.
The equation of survival analysis is as follows:
=
,
+
,
+
,
+
,
+
+
,
,
+
,
The dependent variable,
,
+
+
, means the hazard rate that city i
adopts the HPF policy in the year t. All the independent variables have the same meaning
with those in the last equation, while
and
34
denote the constant and the deviation value,
respectively. This research will separately use the Cox Regression Model and the
Loglogistic Regression Model to make a robust check on the argument.
4.5 Results
4.5.1 Results for Binary Time-series Cross-sectional Analysis
Overall, the results of the binary time-series cross-sectional analysis confirm the
argument that the local capacity and interests and the national promotion could together
affect the policy innovation of the local governments. The maximum-likelihood
estimation for the HPF policy innovation is reported in Table 3. Moreover, a postestimation is presented in Table 4 to show the changes in the predicted probabilities of
the HPF policy innovation with the variation of each independent variable. The predicted
values are calculated by summing up the constant value and each product of the estimated
coefficients and the selected values of other associated variables. In specific, the variable
of interest takes on selected values in an increasing order, while holding the rest on their
mean (for continuous independent variables) or mode (for the categorical independent
variables). The calculated equation is as follows:
Pr(1) =
exp(x)
1 + exp( )
35
Table 3 Maximum-Likelihood Estimation for HPF Policy Innovation
Independent Variables
Policy Innovation
Local Level Capacity
and Interest
Economic Performance
0.0928* (0.0486)
Local Revenue
0.330*** (0.110)
Average Wage
-1.632*** (0.496)
National Promotion
-2.28206*** (0.307)
Interaction
0.701*** (0.244)
Control Variables
City Level
0.5* (0.260)
Neighbor
0.302*** (0.0323)
Year
1.268*** (0.106)
Constant
-2528.59*** (210.132)
Note: ***p[...]... this research intends to provide an explanation of the diffusion of the Housing Provident Fund (HPF) policy among the municipalities in China However, before focusing on the case of HPF policy, we need to take a look at the large context of urban housing reform in China during the 1980s and early 1990s 3.4.1 Urban housing reform in China Since 1980s, China launched a full aspect economic reform to transit... conditions of the diffusion of innovations With a careful scrutiny, this research shows the necessity to further explore the determinants and process of policy diffusion in an incomplete decentralized system Finally, as China, the largest developing country in the world, is the main focus of this research, I present the existing studies which analyze the policy innovation and diffusion in China The previous... they get retired (Shanghai Municiple Government, 1991) In October of the same year, the Steering Group of Housing System Reform promulgated the “Opinions on Comprehensive Reform of the Urban Housing System , which updated the 1988 plan and 4 The contents of the reform proposal in Shanghai include establishing the housing provident fund, raising housing rent while giving the subsidies, selling the housing. .. research analyzing the driving force of the diffusion of police departments’ microblogging in China from the perspective of organization innovation (Ma, 2013), it 11 discusses the predominance of the upper government in general without paying attention to the possible variations in the effect of the upper government influence depending on the local conditions To fill the existing gaps, the research intends... on the process of policy diffusion in China and emphasized the importance of the central government; however, they ignore the active role of the local governments and the interaction between the central and local governments during the diffusion process This research will contribute to the existing literature by studying the policy diffusion process in a developing country and by examining the interaction... 1956) 8 2.3 Policy innovation and diffusion in China A sprawling literature on policy innovation in China has been published in Chinese journals since 2000, which probably resulted from the initiation of the prize for the innovation of the Chinese local governments Compared with the empirical studies on policy diffusion among the local governments in the U.S and other different countries, these researches... the internal factors of the states government 2.2 The mechanisms of policy diffusion and its conditions The popular determinants discussed above provide a space to further detect the driving force of policy diffusion The scholars also endeavor to detect the mechanisms of policy diffusion They either use these mechanisms as independent variables to explain the features of policy diffusion, such as the. .. Reform of the Urban Housing System (guanyu zai quanguo chengzhen fenqi fenpi tuixing zhufang zhidu gaige de shishi fang’an) in the first national working conference of housing reform The objective of this reform was to increase housing rent, to establish housing fund, to sell the public housing, and to establish housing finance More importantly, this document states that the following housing reform... important As for the case of the Housing Provident Fund (HPF) policy, this chapter hypothesized that the central government promotion and local level capacity and interests, such as the local revenue, the performance of the enterprises, and the average income of the employees, could together determine the diffusion of HPF policy Furthermore, as the localities have different interests, national intervention... burden and supported them to construct more housing for their employees However, the function of HPF had a drastic change in 1999, since welfare housing system was totally abandoned in that year The Regulation on Management of Housing Provident Fund in 1999 clearly defined that the housing provident fund could only be loaned to the individuals since then (State Council, 1999) Therefore, the HPF became an ... research intends to provide an explanation of the diffusion of the Housing Provident Fund (HPF) policy among the municipalities in China However, before focusing on the case of HPF policy, we... Finally, as China, the largest developing country in the world, is the main focus of this research, I present the existing studies which analyze the policy innovation and diffusion in China The. .. adjust the behaviors of the local officials Therefore, local governments would follow the instructions of the central government 3.4 Policy Diffusion of Housing Provident Fund in China Based on the