The following paper attempts to reconcile our existing theories on corporate governance, executive compensation, and the firm with the events that took place at Enron.. I will argue that
Trang 1Enron and the Economics of Corporate Governance
June 2003
Peter Grosvenor Munzig Department of Economics Stanford University, Stanford CA 94305-6072 Advisor: Professor Timothy Bresnahan
ABSTRACT
In the wake of the demise of Enron, corporate governance has come to the forefront of economic discussion The fall of Enron was a direct result of failed corporate governance and consequently has led to a complete reevaluation of corporate governance practice in the United States The following paper attempts to reconcile our existing theories on corporate governance, executive compensation, and the firm with the events that took place at Enron This paper first examines and synthesizes our current theories on
corporate governance, and then applies theoretical and economic framework to the factual events that occurred at Enron I will argue that Enron was a manifestation of the principal-agent problem, that high-powered incentive contracts provided management with incentives for self-dealing, that significant costs were transferred to shareholders due
to the obscurity in Enron’s financial reporting, and that due to the lack of board
independence it is likely that management rent extraction occurred
Acknowledgements: I would like to thank my family and friends for their continued
support throughout this paper In particular, my mother Judy Munzig was instrumental with her comments on earlier drafts I also thank Professors Geoffrey Rothwell and George Parker for their help, and finally to my advisor Professor Bresnahan, for without his support and advice this paper would not have been possible
Trang 2“When a company called Enron… ascends to the number seven spot on the Fortune
500 and then collapses in weeks into a smoking ruin, its stock worth pennies, its CEO, a confidante of presidents, more or less evaporated, there must be lessons in there somewhere.”
-Daniel Henninger, The Wall Street Journal
Trang 3CONTENTS
I INTRODUCTION 3
II THE THEORY OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE 7
Corporate Governance and the Principal- Agent Problem 7
Executive Compensation and the Alignment of Manager and Shareholder Interests 11
Corporate Governance’s Role in Economic Efficiency 14
Recent Developments in Corporate Governance 15
III WHAT HAPPENED: FACTUAL ACCOUNT OF EVENTS LEADING TO BANKRUPTCY 17
Background/Timeline 18
Summary of Transactions and Partnerships 19
The Chewco/JEDI Transaction 20
The LJM Transactions 22
IV ANALYSIS OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ISSUES 26
Corporate Structure 27
Conflicts of Interest 30
Failures in Board Oversight and Fundamental Lack of Checks and Balances .33
Audit Committee Relationship With Enron and Andersen 35
Lack of Auditing Independence and the Partial Failure of the Efficient Market Hypothesis 38
Director Independence/Director Selection 41
V POST-ENRON GOVERNANCE REFORMS AND OTHER PROPOSED SOLUTIONS TO GOVERNANCE PROBLEMS 45
Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 45
Other Governance Reforms and Proposed Solutions 48
VI CONCLUSION 51
I INTRODUCTION
Often referred to as the first major failure of the “New Economy,” the collapse of Enron Corporation stunned investors, accountants, and boardrooms and sent shockwaves
Trang 4across financial markets when the company filed for bankruptcy on December 2, 2001
At that time, the Houston-based energy trading company’s bankruptcy was the largest in history but was surpassed by WorldCom’s bankruptcy on July 22, 2002 Enron
employees and retirement accounts across the country lost hundreds of millions of dollars when the price of Enron stock sank from its peak of $105 to its de-listing by the
NASDAQ at just a few cents Arthur Andersen, once a Big Five accounting firm,
imploded with its conviction for Obstruction of Justice in connection with the auditing
services it provided to Enron Through the use of what were termed “creative accounting techniques” and off-balance sheet transactions involving Special Purpose Entities (SPEs), Enron was able to hide massive amounts of debt and often collateralized that debt with
Enron stock Major conflicts of interest existed with the establishment and operation of
these SPEs and partnerships, with Enron’s CFO Andrew Fastow authorized by the board
to manage the transactions between Enron and the partnerships, for which he was
generously compensated at Enron’s expense
In addition to crippling investor confidence and provoking questions about the
sustainability of a deregulated energy market, Enron’s collapse has precipitated a
complete reevaluation of both the accounting industry and many aspects of corporate
governance in America The significance of exploring the Enron debacle is multifaceted
and can be generalized to many companies as corporate America evaluates its governance practices The fall of Enron demands an examination of the fundamental aspects of the
oversight functions assigned to every company’s management and the board of directors
of a company In particular, the role of the subcommittees on a board and their
effectiveness are questioned, as are compensation techniques designed to align the
interests of shareholders and management and alleviate the principal-agent problem, both theoretically and in application Companies such as Worldcom, Tyco, Adelphia, and
Trang 5Global Crossing have all suffered catastrophes similar to Enron’s, and have furthered the need to reevaluate corporate governance mechanisms in the U.S
My question then becomes, what lessons can be learned from the fundamental
breakdowns that occurred at the corporate governance level at Enron, both from an
applied and theoretical standpoint? This paper attempts to offer an analysis that
reconciles the events that occurred inside the walls of Enron and our current theories on
corporate governance, the firm, and executive compensation In particular, I look at the role the principal-agent problem played at Enron and attempt to link theories of
management’s expropriation of firm funds with the Special Purpose Entities Enron
management assembled I question Enron’s executive compensation practices and the
effectiveness of shareholder and management alignment with the excessive stock-option
packages management received (and the resulting incentives to self-deal) Links between the information asymmetry and the transfer of costs to shareholders is explored, as well
as the efficient market hypothesis in regards to Enron’s stock price And finally, the lack
of director independence at Enron provides a foundation for the excessive compensation practices given managers were extracting rents
From an applied standpoint, I argue that following can be learned from Enron:
• Enron managed their numbers to meet aggressive expectations They were less
concerned with the economic impact of their transactions as they were with the
financial statement impact Creating favorable earnings for Wall Street
dominated decision making
• The Board improperly allowed conflicts of interest with Enron partnerships and
then did not ensure appropriate oversight of those relationships There was a
fundamental lack of communication and direction from the Board as to who
should be reviewing the related-party transactions and the degree of such review The Board was also unaware of other conflicts of interests with other transactions
• The Board did not effectively communicate with its auditors from Arthur
Andersen The idea that Enron’s employed accounting techniques were
"aggressive" was not communicated clearly enough to the board, who were
blinded by its trust in its respected auditors
Trang 6• The Board did not give enough consideration when making important decisions They were not really informed nor did they understand the types of transactions
Enron was engaging in, and they were too quick to approve proposals put forth by management
• The Board members had significant relationships with Enron Corporation and its management, which may have contributed to their failure to be more proactive in their oversight
• The Board relied too heavily on the auditors and did not fulfill its duty of ensuring the independence of the auditors Given the relationship between management
and the auditors, the Board should not have been so generous with its trust The Board is entitled to rely on outside experts and management to the extent it is
reasonable and appropriate - in this case it was excessive
From a theoretical standpoint, I argue that the following are lessons learned from
Enron:
• Enron was a manifestation of the principal-agent problem The ulterior motives
of management were not in line with maximizing shareholder value
• The high-powered incentive contracts of Enron’s management highlight more of
the costs associated with attempting to align shareholders with management to
counter the principal-agent problem and provided management with extensive
opportunities for self-dealings
• Significant costs were transferred to shareholders associated with asymmetric
information due to management’s sophisticated techniques for obscuring financial results Such obscuring also lead to a partial failure of the efficient market
hypothesis
• Due to the lack of board independence, the theory of rent extraction more likely
explains management’s actions and compensation than the optimal contracting
theory
This analysis of the Enron case attempts to explain what happened at Enron in the context of existing theories on the firm, corporate governance, and executive
compensation, as they are innately linked Section II discusses the general theory of
corporate governance defined from two perspectives, first from an applied perspective
and then from a theoretical perspective Next is an attempt to answer the question of why
Trang 7we need corporate governance and to explore its function theoretically The section ends with information on changes made in corporate governance over the last two decades
Section III details the factual account of events leading to the fall of Enron It
includes the history and background of the corporation, beginning with its inception with
the merger of Houston Natural Gas and Internorth in 1985 through its earnings
restatements and eventual bankruptcy filing in December of 2001 It also focuses on the partnerships and transactions that were the catalysts for the firm’s failure, in particular the Special Purpose Entities like Chewco, JEDI, and LJM-1 and LJM-2
Section IV provides analysis of the corporate governance issues that arise within Enron from a theoretical approach That is, a theoretical and economic framework are
applied to Enron’s corporate structure and compensation schedules, highlighting
opposing theories such as optimal contracting and rent extraction with regards to
executive compensation Further discussed is the principal-agent problem in the context
of Enron and management’s expropriation of shareholder’s capital Highlighted also are
management’s conflicts of interest that were allowed and that then went unmonitored by
the board Also included is an analysis on the lack of material independence on the board and the theory that management had bargaining power because of the close director-
management relationships I also discuss the relationship between the audit committee
and Arthur Andersen, as well Andersen’s lack of auditing independence Included is an
analysis on the partial failure of the efficient market hypothesis in the case of Enron and
the transfer of costs to the shareholders because of the asymmetric information due to
management’s sophisticated techniques for obscuring financial results
Section V looks at the primary legislative reform post-Enron, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, including its key points and the likely effects and costs of its implementation on
corporate governance and financial reporting The section includes other developments
Trang 8in corporate governance, and provides some solutions to improving governance and
executive compensation
II THEORY OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
Corporate Governance and the Principal-Agent Problem
Before applying theory to the case of Enron, it is important to first discuss the
nature of the principal-agent problem and the reasons for a governance system, as well as
to define corporate governance from an applied and theoretical approach I then will
discuss why corporate governance helps improve overall economic efficiency, followed
by the general developments in corporate governance over the past two decades On its most simplistic and applied level, corporate governance is the mechanism that allows the shareholders of a firm to oversee the firm’s management and management’s decisions In the U.S., this oversight mechanism takes form by way of a board of directors, which is
headed by the chairman Boards typically contain between one and two dozen members, and also contain multiple subcommittees that focus on particular aspects of the firm and
its functions
However, the existence of such oversight bodies begs the questions: why is there
a need for a governance system, and why is intervention needed in the context of a
free-market economy? Adam Smith’s invisible hand asserts that the free-market mechanisms will
efficiently allocate resources without the need for intervention Williamson (1985) calls
such transactions that are dictated by market mechanisms “standardized,” and can be
thought of as commodity markets with classic laws of supply and demand governing
them These markets consist of many producers and many consumers, with the quality of the goods being traded the same from producer to producer
Trang 9These market mechanisms do not apply to all transactions though, particularly
when looking at the separation of ownership and management of a firm and its associated contracts The need for a corporate governance system is inherently linked to such a
separation, as well as to the underlying theories of the firm The agency problem, as
developed by Coase (1937) and Jensen and Meckling (1976) as well as others, is in
essence the problem associated with such separation of management and ownership A
manager, or entrepreneur, will raise capital from financiers to produce goods in a firm
The financiers, in return, need the manager to generate returns on the capital they have
provided The financiers, after putting forth the capital, are left without any guarantees or assurances that their funds will not be expropriated or spent on bad investments and
projects Further, the financiers have no guarantees other than the shares of the firm that they now hold that they will receive anything back from the manager at all This
difficulty for financiers is essentially the agency problem
When looking at the agency problem from a contractual standpoint, one might
initially think that such a moral hazard for the management might be solved through
contracts An ideal world would include a contract that would specify how the manager
should perform in all states of the world, as dictated by the financiers of the firm That is,
a complete contingent contract between the financiers and manager would specify how
the profits are divided amongst the manager and owners (financiers), as well as describe appropriate actions for the manager for all possible situations However, because every
possible contingency cannot be predicted or because it would be prohibitively costly to
anticipate such contingencies, a complete contract is unfeasible As Zingales (1997)
points out, in a world where complete contingent contracts can be costlessly written by
agents, there is no need for governance, as all possible situations will be anticipated in the contract
Trang 10Given that complete contingent contracts are unfeasible, we are therefore left with incomplete contracts binding the manager to the shareholders As a result of the
incomplete contracts, there are then unlimited situations that arise in the course of
managing a company that require action by a manager that are not explicitly stated in the manager’s contract Grossman and Hart (1986) describe these as residual control rights the rights to make decisions in situations not addressed in the contract Suppose then,
that financiers reserved all residual control rights as specified in their contract with
management That is, in any unforeseen situation, the owners decide what to do This
would not be a successful allocation of the residual control rights because financiers most often would not be qualified or would not have enough information to know what to do
This is the exact reason for which the manager was hired As a result, the manager will
retain most of the residual control rights and thus the ability to allocate firm’s funds as he
chooses (Shleifer and Vishny 1996)
There are other reasons why it is logical for a majority of the residual control
rights to reside with management, as opposed to with the shareholders It is often the
case that managers would have raised funds from many different investors, making each
individual investor’s capital contribution a small percentage of the total capital raised As
a result, the individual investor is likely to be too small or uninformed of the residual
rights he may retain, and thus the rights will not be exercised Further, the free-rider
problem for an individual owner often does not make it worthwhile for the owner to
become involved in the contract enforcement or even be knowledgeable about the firms
in which he invests (Shleifer and Vishny 1996) due to his small ownership interest This
results in the managers having even more residual control rights as the financiers remove
themselves from the oversight function
Trang 11In attempting to define corporate governance from a theoretical standpoint, it is
helpful to think of the contract between the owners and management as producing
quasi-rents In defining quasi-rents, consider the example of the purchase of a specialized
machine between two parties Once the seller has begun to produce the machine, both
the buyer and the seller are in a sense locked into the transaction This is because the
machine probably can fetch a higher price from the buyer than on the open market due to its specificity, and the seller can probably complete the machine for cheaper than any
other firm at that point The surplus created between the differences in the open market
prices and the price in this specialized contract constitutes a quasi-rent, which needs to be divided ex-post The existence of such quasi-rents when produced in the contract
between management and owners creates room for bargaining as the quasi-rents need to
be divided, and Zingales (1997) argues that the bargaining over these ex-post rents is the essence of governance
To return to the earlier discussion of incomplete contracts, one may make the link that the residual control rights due to the incomplete contracting can be seen as a quasi-
rent, and thus must be divided ex-post How, then, are these rents divided given our
incomplete contracting assumption? This question gets to the heart of corporate
governance and its function Using Zingales’ (1997, p.4) definition, corporate
governance is “the complex set of restraints that shape the ex-post bargaining over the
quasi-rents generated by a firm.” This definition serves to summarize the primary
function of corporate governance under the incomplete contract paradigm
Executive Compensation and the Alignment of Manager and Shareholder Interests
The notions of executive compensation and the attempt to align manager and
shareholder interests are subsections of corporate governance and are directly linked to
Trang 12the agency problem and firm theory Previously discussed is why operating under the
incomplete contract approach tends to leave managers with a majority of the residual
control rights of a firm As a result of these residual control rights, managers have
significant discretion and are not directly (or are incompletely) tied to the interests of the
shareholders Acting independently of shareholders’ interest, managers may then engage
in self-interested behavior and inappropriate allocation of firm funds may occur
In an effort to quell such misallocations by a manager, a solution is to give the
manager long term, contingent incentive contracts that help to align his interests with
those of the shareholders This view of executive compensation is commonly referred to
as the optimal contracting view It is important with this contracting that the marginal
value of the manager’s contingent contract exceed the marginal value of personal benefits
of control, which can be achieved, with rare exceptions, if the incentive contract is of a
significant amount (Shleifer and Vishny 1996) When in place, such incentive contracts
help to encourage the manager to act in the interest of the shareholders Critical to the
functioning of these incentive contracts is the requirement that the performance
measurement is highly correlated with the quality of the management decisions during his
tenure and that they be verifiable in court
The most traditional form of shareholder and management alignment under the
optimal contracting view of executive compensation is through stock ownership by the
manager This immediately gives the manager similar interests as the general
shareholding population and acts to align their interest Stock options also help to align
interests because it creates incentive for the manager to increase the stock price of the
firm, which consequently increases the value of his options when (if) he chooses to
exercise them Another form of an incentive contract that helps to align the interests of
shareholders and a manager is to remove the manager from office if the firm income is
Trang 13too low (Jensen and Meckling 1976) Again, this provides quite a strict incentive for
management to produce strong earnings, which aligns his interest with those of the
shareholders, and hopefully serves to maximize shareholder value
It is important to mention that these incentive contracts for agents are not without costs and have come under immense scrutiny recently, particularly with the recent
corporate governance scandals like Enron They provide ample incentive for
management to misrepresent the true earnings of a firm and do not completely solve the
agency problem, an issue that will be discussed further in section IV
A second and competing view of executive compensation is the rent extraction
view, or as Bertrand and Mullainathan (2000) call it, the “skimming view.” This rent
extraction view is similar to the optimal contracting view in that they both rely on the
principal-agent conflict, but under the rent extraction view “executive compensation is
seen as part of the [agency] problem rather than a remedy to it,” (Bebchuk, Fried and
Walker 2001, p.31) Under this view, an executive maintains significant power over the board of directors who effectively set his compensation This power the executive, or
management team, holds stems from the close relationships between management and the directors, and thus the directors and executives may be bonded by “interest, collegiality,
or affinity,” (Bebchuk, Fried and Walker 2001, p.31) Also, directors are further tied to management, and in particular the CEO, because the CEO is often the one who exerted
influence to have the director placed on the board, and thus the director may feel more
inclined to defer to the CEO, particularly with issues surrounding the bargaining over
management’s compensation
As a result of the power that management maintains, management has the ability
to bargain more effectively with the board over compensation, and can effectively extract more rents as a result These “rents” are referred to as the amount of compensation a
Trang 14CEO, or management, receives over the normal amount he would receive with optimal
contracting Therefore it is logical to anticipate seeing higher pay for executives
governed by weaker boards, or boards with little independence, which is consistent with Bertrand and Mullainathan’s (2000) findings That is, one of their conclusions was that
boards with more insiders (or less independence) are inclined to pay their CEO more In other words, CEO’s with fewer independent directors on their boards are likely to gain
better control of the pay process
More generally, it is important to mention that incentive contracts for executives
are common components of their compensation packages, and there is a vast amount of
literature on the effectiveness of incentive contracts Murphy (1985) argued from an
empirical standpoint about the positive relationship between pay and performance of
managers Murphy and Jensen (1990) later examined stock options of executives and
showed that a manager’s pay increased by only $3 for every $1000 increase in
shareholder wealth Murphy and Jensen concluded that it was evidence of inefficient
compensation arrangements, arrangements that included restrictions on high levels of
pay Others suggest that there needs to be a better approach in screening out performance effects that are outside an executive’s control when looking at incentive contracts
Rappaport (1999), in particular, argues that incentive contracts for executives would
provide more incentive and be better measures of executive performance if the stock
option exercise prices were indexed by broad movements in the market This would
imply that an executive would not be compensated simply because of broad movements
in the market, but more by his individual firm’s performance relative to other firms
Corporate Governance’s Role in Economic Efficiency
Trang 15Given the role executive compensation and incentive contracts play in attempting
to solve the agency problem, there remains the question of what role governance plays in improving economic efficiency In the ex-ante (which Zingales (1997) defines as the
time when specific investments should be made) period, there are two situations where
governance improves economic efficiency The first is that rational agents will focus on
value-enhancing activities that are most clearly rewarded, and therefore governance must help allocate resources and reward value-enhancing activities that are not properly
rewarded by the market Secondly, managers will engage in activities that improve the
ex-post bargaining in their favor As Shleifer and Vishny (1989) argue, a manager will
be inclined to focus on activities that he is best at managing because his marginal
contribution is greater, and this consequently increases his share of ex-post rents, or his
bargaining power for residual control rights
Another area where governance may improve economic efficiency is in the
ex-post bargaining phase for rents That is, governance may affect the level of coordination
costs or the extent to which a party is liquidity-constrained If residual control rights are
assigned to a large, diverse group, the existence of free-riders in the group may create an inefficient bargaining system Also, if a party wishes to engage in a transfer of control
rights but he is liquidity-constrained, inefficient bargaining may again occur as the
transaction may not be agreed upon (Zingales 1997)
A third way that governance may effect overall economic efficiency is through
the level and distribution of risk Assuming that the engaged parties have different risk
aversions, corporate governance can then act to efficiently allocate risk to those who are least risk-averse (Fama and Jensen 1983), which improves the total surplus for the parties involved
Trang 16From a more general standpoint, it is also important to recognize that strong
governance in a system of capital markets such as the U.S promotes an efficient medium for those who are lending money and those who are borrowing, as well as provides some security outside of the legal framework for lenders of capital The nature of the firm
requires that financiers, or lenders of capital, will indeed lend their money to managers
who will in turn run a firm and hopefully create a return for the financiers If the
financiers did not feel comfortable that they would be receiving their capital back at some point in the future, they would not be inclined to provide managers with capital and, as a
result, innovation and industrial progression would be slowed tremendously Strong
governance helps to maintain investors’ confidence in the capital markets and helps to
improve overall efficiency in this manner
Recent Developments in Corporate Governance
Besides the theoretical basis of efficiencies provided by governance, it is
important to consider a more applied look at governance and how it has evolved over the past two decades in the U.S Indeed, corporate governance has changed substantially in the past two decades Prior to 1980, corporate governance did little to provide managers with incentives to make shareholder interests their primary responsibility As Jensen
(1993) discusses, prior to 1980 management thought of themselves as representatives of the corporation as opposed to employees and representatives of the shareholders
Management saw their role as one of balancing the interests of all related parties,
including company employees, suppliers, customers, and shareholders The use of
incentive contracting was still limited, and thus management’s interests were not well
aligned with that of its shareholders In fact, “in 1980, only 20% of the compensation of
CEOs was tied to stock market performance,” (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003, p.5) Also,
Trang 17the role of external governance mechanisms like hostile takeovers and proxy fights were
rare, and there tended to be very little independence on a board of directors
The 1980s, however, were defined as an era of hostile takeovers and restructuring activities that made companies less susceptible to takeovers Leverage was employed at high rates As Holmstrom and Kaplan (2003) argue, the difference between actual firm
performance and potential performance grew to be significant, or in other words, firms
were failing to maximize value, which lead to a new disciplining by the capital markets
The 1990s, by contrast, included an increase in mergers that were designed to take
advantage of emerging technologies and high growth industries
Changes in executive compensation throughout the two decades also changed
significantly Option-based compensation for managers increased significantly as
executives became more aligned with shareholders, specifically, “equity-based
compensation in 1994 made up almost 50% of CEO compensation (up from less than
20% in 1980),” (Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003, p.9)
There were also changes in the makeup of U.S shareholders during the two
decades, as well as changes in boards of directors Institutional investors share of the
market increased significantly (share almost doubled from 1980 to 1996, Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003), which came alongside an increase in shareholder activism throughout the
period The increase in large institutional investors suggests that firms will be more
likely to be effective monitors of management The logic follows because if an investor
(take a large institutional investor for example) owns a larger part of the firm, he will be
more concerned with the firm’s performance than if he were small because his potential
cash flows from the firm will be greater It is important to note that often the large
shareholders are institutional shareholders, which means that presumably more
sophisticated investors with incentives to show strong stock returns own an increasing
Trang 18share of firms Such concentration of ownership tends to avoid the traditional free-rider
problem associated with small, dispersed shareholders and will lead to the large
shareholders more closely monitoring management “Large shareholders thus address the agency problem in that they both have a general interest in profit maximization, and
enough control over the assets of the firm to have their interests respected,” (Shleifer and Vishny 1996, p.27)
Other developments in corporate governance over the two decades, aside from the regulatory and legislative changes post-Enron, include the fact that boards took great
strides to remove their director nominating decisions from the CEO’s control through the use of nominating committees The number of outside directors (referring to those
directors who are not members of management) also increased during the period, as did directors’ equity compensation as a percentage of their total director compensation
(Holmstrom and Kaplan 2003)
However, despite such improvements over the past two decades, the case of
Enron suggests that corporate governance was not immune from failure, and it highlights
many of the theoretical and applied issues with the current theories on corporate
governance, the firm, and executive compensation
III WHAT HAPPENED AT ENRON: FACTUAL ACCOUNT OF EVENTS
LEADING TO BANKRUPTCY
Background/Timeline
Enron was founded in 1985 through the merger of Houston Natural Gas and
Internorth, a natural gas company based in Omaha, Nebraska, and quickly became the
major energy and petrochemical commodities trader under the leadership of its chairman,
Trang 19Kenneth Lay In 1999, Enron moved its operations online, boasting the largest online
trading exchange as one of the key market makers in natural gas, electricity, crude oil,
petrochemicals and plastics Enron diversified into coal, shipping, steel & metals, pulp & paper, and even into such commodities as weather and credit derivatives At its peak,
Enron was reporting revenues of $80 billion and profits of $1 billion (Roberts 2002), and was for six consecutive years lauded by Fortune as America’s most innovative company (Hogan 2002)
The sudden resignation, however, of Enron Vice-Chairman Clifford Baxter in
May of 2001 and subsequent resignation of CEO Jeffrey Skilling in August of 2001, both
of whom retired for undisclosed personal reasons, should have served as the first
indication of the troubles brewing within Enron Mr Skilling had been elected CEO only months before, and Mr Baxter had become Vice-Chairman in 2000 Eventually, amidst analysts’ and investors’ questions regarding undisclosed partnerships and rumors of
egregious accounting errors, Enron announced on October 16, 2001 it was taking a $544 million dollar after-tax-charge against earnings and a reduction in shareholder equity by
$1.2 billion due to related transactions with LJM-2 As will be discussed in the following section, LJM-2 was partnership managed and partially owned by Enron’s CFO, Andrew Fastow The LJM partnerships provided Enron with a partner for asset sales and
purchases as well as an instrument to hedge risk
Less than a month later Enron announced that it would be restating its earnings
from 1997 through 2001 because of accounting errors relating to transactions with
another Fastow partnership, LJM Cayman, and Chewco Investments, which was
managed by Michael Kopper Mr Kopper was the managing director of Enron’s global finance unit and reported directly to the CFO, Mr Fastow Chewco Investments was a
Trang 20partnership created out of the need to redeem an outside investor’s interest in another
Enron partnership and will be discussed at length in the following section
Such restatements sparked a formal investigation by the SEC into Enron’s
partnerships Other questionable partnerships were coming to light, including the
Raptors partnerships These restatements were colossal, and combined with Enron’s
disclosure that their CFO Mr Fastow was paid in excess of $30 million for the
management of LJM-1 and LJM-2, investor confidence was crushed Enron’s debt
ratings subsequently plummeted, and one month later, on December 2, 2001, Enron filed for bankruptcy protection under Chapter 11
Summary of Transactions and Partnerships
Many of the partnership transactions that Enron engaged in that contributed to its failure involved special accounting treatment through the use of specifically structured
entities known as a “special purpose entities,” or SPEs For accounting purposes in 2001,
a company did not need to consolidate such an entity on to its own balance sheet if two
conditions were met: “(1) an owner independent of the company must make a substantive equity investment of at least 3% of the SPE’s assets, and the 3% must remain at risk
throughout the transaction; and (2) the independent owner must exercise control of the
SPE,” (Powers, Troubh and Winokur 2002, p.5) If these two conditions were met, a
company was allowed to record gains and losses on those transactions on their income
statement, while the assets, and most importantly the liabilities, of the SPE are not
included on the company’s balance sheet, despite the close relationship between the
company and the entity
Trang 21The Chewco/JEDI Transaction
The first of the related party transactions worthy of analysis is Chewco
Investments L.P., a limited partnership managed by Mr Kopper Chewco was created
out of the need to redeem California Public Employees’ Retirement System (“CalPERS”) interest in a previous partnership with Enron called Joint Energy Development
Investment Limited Partnership (JEDI)
JEDI was a $500 million joint venture investment jointly controlled by Enron and CalPERS Because of this joint control, Enron was allowed to disclose its share of gains and losses from JEDI on its income statement, but was not required to disclose JEDI’s
debt on its balance sheet However, in order to redeem CalPERS interest in JEDI so that CalPERS would invest in an even larger partnership, Enron needed to find a new partner,
or else it would have to consolidate JEDI’s debt onto its balance sheet, which it
desperately wanted to avoid
In keeping with the rules regarding SPEs, JEDI needed to have an owner
independent of Enron contribute at least 3% of the equity capital at risk to allow Enron to not consolidate the entity Unable to find an outside investor to put up the 3% capital,
Fastow selected Kopper to form and manage Chewco, which was to buy CalPERS’ 3% interest However, Chewco’s purchase of CalPERS’ share was almost completely with
debt, as opposed to equity As a result, the assets and liabilities of JEDI and Chewco
should have been consolidated onto Enron’s balance sheet in 1997, but were not
The decision by management and Andersen to not consolidate was in complete
disregard of the accounting requirements in connection with the use of SPEs, despite the fact that it is was in both Enron’s employees’ interest and in the interest of Enron’s
auditors to be forthright in their public financial statements The consequences of such a
Trang 22decision were far-reaching, and in the fall of 2001 when Enron and Andersen were
reviewing the transaction, it became apparent that Chewco did not comply with the
accounting rules for SPEs In November of 2001 Enron announced that it would be
consolidating the transactions retroactively to 1997 This consequently resulted in the
massive earnings restatements and increased debt on Enron’s balance sheet
Not only was this transaction devastating to Enron, but its manager, Mr Kopper, received excessive compensation from the transaction, as he was handsomely rewarded
more than $2 million in management fees relating to Chewco Such a financial windfall
was the result of “arrangements that he appears to have negotiated with Fastow,”
(Powers, Troubh, and Winokur 2002, p.8) Kopper was also a direct investor in Chewco, and in March of 2001 received more than $10 million of Enron shareholders’ money for his personal investment of $125,000 in 1997 His compensation for such work should
have been reviewed by the board’s Compensation Committee but was not
This transaction begins to shed light on a few of the many corporate governance
issues arising from Enron, one being the dual role Kopper played as manager and
investor of the partnership while an employee of Enron This is a blatant conflict of
interest, explicitly violating Enron’s own Code of Ethics and Business Affairs, which
prohibits such conflicts “unless the chairman and CEO determined that his participation
‘does not adversely affect the best interests of the Company,’” (Powers, Troubh and
Winokur 2002, p.8) The second governance issue is in connection with the
Compensation Committee’s lack of review of Kopper’s compensation resulting from the transactions The third governance issue deals with the lack of auditing oversight from
the Audit and Compliance Committee concerning the decision not to consolidate the
entity
Trang 23The LJM Transactions
In June of 1999, Enron again entrenched itself in related-party transactions with
the development of LJM-1 and later with LJM-2 Both partnerships were structured in
such a way that Fastow was General Partner (and thereby investor) of the entities as well
as Enron’s manager of the transactions with the entities, an obvious conflict of interest
LJM-1 (Cayman) and LJM-2 served two distinct roles They provided a partner
to Enron for asset sales and as well as acted to hedge economic risk for particular Enron investments Especially near the end of a quarter, Enron would often sell assets to LJM-1
or LJM-2 While it is important to note that there is nothing inherently wrong with such
transactions if there is true transfer of ownership, it would appear that in the case of the
LJM transactions there were no such transfers
Several facts seem to indicate the questionable nature of such transactions at the end of the third and fourth quarters in 1999, one of which was that Enron bought back
five of the seven assets just after the close of the financial period (Powers, Troubh and
Winokur 2002) It is reasonable to assume that the sale was purely for financial reporting purposes, and not for economic benefit Another fact that casts doubt on the legitimacy
of the sales is that “the LJM partnerships made a profit on every transaction, even when
the asset it had purchased appears to have declined in market value,” (Powers, Troubh
and Winokur 2002, p.12) Thus it appears that the LJM partnerships served more as a
vehicle for Enron management to artificially boost earnings reports to meet financial
expectations, conceal debt, and enrich those investors in the partnerships than as
legitimate partners for asset sales and purchases
Not only were the LJM transactions used in asset sales and purchases, but also for supposed hedging transactions by Enron Hedging is normally the act of protecting
Trang 24against the downside of an investment by contracting with another firm or entity that
accepts the risk of the investment for a fee However, in June of 1999 with the Rhythms investment, instead of the LJM partnerships committing the independent equity necessary
to act as a hedge for the investment should the value of the investment decline, they
committed Enron stock that would serve as the primary source of payment “The idea
was to ‘hedge’ Enron’s profitable merchant investment in Rhythms stock, allowing Enron
to offset losses on Rhythms if the price of Rhythms stock declined,” (Powers, Troubh and Winokur 2002, p.13) These “hedging” transactions did not stop with Rhythms, but
continued through 2000 and 2001 with other SPEs called Raptor vehicles They too were hedging Enron investments with payments that would be made in Enron stock should
such a payment be necessary
Despite Andersen’s approval of such transactions, there were substantial
economic drawbacks for Enron of essentially “hedging” with itself If the stock price of
Enron fell at the same time as one of its investments, the SPE would not be able to make the payments to Enron, and the hedges would fail For many months this was never a
concern, as Enron stock climbed and the stock market boomed But by late 2000 and
early 2001 Enron’s stock price was sagging, and two of the SPEs lacked the funds to pay Enron on the hedges Enron creatively “restructured” some transactions just before
quarter’s end, but these restructuring efforts were short-term solutions to fundamentally
flawed transactions The Raptor SPEs could no longer make their payments, and in
October of 2001 Enron took a $544 million dollar after-tax charge against earnings- a
result of its supposed “hedging” activities
Though they eventually contributed to Enron’s demise, these related party
transactions concerning LJM-1 and LJM-2 resulted in huge financial gain for Fastow and other investors They received tens of millions of dollars that Enron would have never
Trang 25given away under normal circumstances At one point Fastow received $4.5 million after two months on an essentially risk-free $25,000 investment relating to LJM-1 (Powers,
Troubh and Winokur 2002)
As discussed earlier, one of the downfalls of the principal-agent problem under
the incomplete contract paradigm lies with the allocation of residual control rights to
managers Because managers have much discretion associated with the residual rights,
funds may be misallocated This exact problem, the misallocation of firm funds, arose in
the case of Enron Enron shareholders had invested capital in the firm and management
was then responsible for the allocation of such funds With the residual control rights
management maintained due to the separation of ownership and management,
management, vis-à-vis the firm’s CFO Andrew Fastow and Michael Kopper, was able to expropriate the firm’s funds
There are many different methods a manager may employ in the expropriation of funds A manager may simply just take the cash directly out of the operation, but in the
case of Enron, management used a technique called transfer pricing with the partnerships they had created Transfer pricing occurs when “managers set up independent companies that they own personally, and sell output (or assets in this case) of the main company they run to the independent firms at below market prices,” (Shleifer and Vishny 1996, p.9
excluding parenthesis) The “independent firms” mentioned above were the partnerships, like Chewco, JEDI, and the LJMs that Fastow and Kopper managed and had partial
ownership of With the partnerships like the LJMs making a profit on nearly every
transaction, it is clear that Enron must have been selling those assets at below market
levels, which defines expropriation by way of transfer pricing It then makes sense that
as the partnerships sold back the assets, they profited each time because Enron would purchase the assets at prices higher than what the partnerships had paid Therefore,
Trang 26re-because Enron’s asset sales and purchases were enriching the investors in the
partnerships, management was effectively expropriating firm funds Management’s
expropriation of funds to the manager-owned and operated partnerships is a manifestation
of the principal-agent Management was literally enriching itself and the other owners of
the partnerships with firm funds, a problem that stems from the separation of ownership
and management in a corporation
It is important to note that the expropriation of firm funds in this case was really a breakdown in the first layer of the corporate governance institutions that exist to protect
shareholders These mechanisms of corporate governance take many different forms,
ranging from management decision-making and compensation, to board oversight, to
outside professional advisors and their roles to monitor the workings of a company
Management of a firm, and in particular its CFO, has a fiduciary duty to the shareholders
of the company, which serves to act as a governance mechanism In this case,
management abandoned their responsibility to shareholders in favor of enriching
themselves and manipulating financial statements, and thus undermined one of the many
mechanisms of corporate governance that contribute to its effectiveness
The expropriation of funds through transfer pricing is not an Enron-specific
phenomenon As Shleifer and Vishny (1996) mention, within the Russian oil industry
managers often sell oil at below market prices to independent manager-owned
companies Korean chaebol also have reportedly sold subsidiaries to the founders of the chaebol at below market prices (Shleifer and Vishny 1996)
At the formation of the LJM partnerships it was brought to the attention of the
board that having Fastow both invest in the partnerships and manage the transactions
with Enron would present a conflict of interest Management, however, was in favor of
the structure because it would supply Enron with another buyer of Enron assets, “and that
Trang 27Fastow’s familiarity with the Company and the assets to be sold would permit Enron to
move more quickly and incur fewer transaction costs,” (Powers, Troubh and Winokur
2002, p.10) After discussion, the board voted to ratify the Fastow managed partnerships, despite the conflict The board was under the impression that a set of procedures to
monitor the related party transactions was being implemented, and that because of the
close scrutiny the partnerships would face this would mitigate the risk involved with
them However, the Enron Board failed “to make sure the controls were effective, to
monitor the fairness of the transactions, or to monitor Mr Fastow’s LJM-related
compensation” (U.S Senate Subcommittee 2002, p.24), and will be discussed further in section IV
Despite the foregoing disparaging remarks regarding SPEs, it is important to note that SPEs are not inherently bad transaction vehicles, and can actually serve valid
purposes They are in fact very appropriate mechanisms for insulating liability, limiting
tax exposure, as well as maintaining high debt ratings They are widely used in both
public and privately held corporations and are fundamental to the structuring of joint
venture projects with other entities It was the expropriation of firm funds by Enron
management that was illegal, not the transaction vehicles themselves
IV ANALYSIS OF CORPORATE GOVERNANCE ISSUES
Corporate Structure
In order to fully analyze the corporate governance issues that arose within Enron,
a certain amount of background information regarding its corporate structure and the
implications of its high power incentive contracts is necessary By any standards,
Enron’s Board structure with five oversight subcommittees could have been characterized
Trang 28as typical amongst major public American corporations The Chairman of the Board was Kenneth Lay, and in 2001 Enron had 15 Board Members Most of the members were
then or had previously served as Chairman or CEO of a major corporation, and only one
of the 15 was an executive of Enron, Jeffrey Skilling, the President and CEO In his
testimony before the Senate Subcommittee on Investigations, John Duncan, Chairman of Enron’s Executive Committee, spoke of his fellow board members as being well
educated, “experienced, successful businessmen and women” and “experts in areas of
finance and accounting.” Indeed they had “a wealth of sophisticated business and
investment experience and considerable expertise in accounting, derivatives, and
structured finance,” (U.S Senate Subcommittee 2002, p.8) The board had five annual
meetings, and conducted additional special meetings as necessary throughout the year
As provided in U.S Senate Subcommittee report on The Role of Enron’s Board
of Directors in Enron’s Collapse (2002, p.9), the five subcommittees, consisting of
between four and seven members each, had the responsibilities as follows:
“(1) The Executive Committee met on an as needed basis to handle urgent
business matters between scheduled Board meetings
(2) The Finance Committee was responsible for approving major transactions
which, in 2001, met or exceeded $75 million in value It also reviewed
transactions valued between $25 million and $75 million; oversaw Enron’s risk
management efforts; and provided guidance on the company’s financial decisions and policies
(3) The Audit and Compliance Committee reviewed Enron’s accounting and
compliance programs, approved Enron’s financial statements and reports, and was the primary liaison with Andersen
(4) The Compensation Committee established and monitored Enron’s
compensation policies and plans for directors, officers, and employees
(5) The Nominating Committee nominated individuals to serve as Directors.”
Trang 29At the full Board meetings, in addition to presentations made by Committee
Chairmen summarizing the Committee work, presentations by Andersen as well as
Vinson & Elkins, the Enron’s chief outside legal counsel, were common Vinson &
Elkins provided advice and assisted with much of the documentation for Enron’s
partnerships, including the disclosure footnotes regarding such transactions in Enron’s
SEC filings (Powers, Troubh and Winokur 2002) Andersen regularly made
presentations to the Audit and Compliance Committee regarding the company’s financial statements, accounting practices, and audit results
Board members received $350,000 in compensation and stock options annually, which “was significantly above the norm,” (U.S Senate Subcommittee 2002, p.56)
Compensation to Enron executives in 2001 was extraordinarily generous too, as shown
by the following chart (Pacelle 2002), which includes the value of exercised stock options and excludes compensation from the partnerships:
Kenneth Lay (Enron Chairman/CEO).……….….$152.7 (in millions)
Mark Fevert (Chair and CEO, Enron Wholesale Services)….$31.9
Jeffrey Skilling (Enron CEO)……… … $34.8
J Clifford Baxter (Enron Vice-Chairman)……… …$16.2
Andrew Fastow (Enron CFO)……… $4.2
In 2000, Mr Lay’s compensation was in excess of $140 million, including the
value of his exercised options This level of compensation was 10 times greater than the average CEO of a publicly traded company in that year, which was $13.1 million (U.S
Senate Subcommittee 2002, p.52) It is important to note that $123 million of that $140 million came from a portion of the stock options he owned, which represents a significant percentage of total compensation from stock options