1. Trang chủ
  2. » Tài Chính - Ngân Hàng

Encyclopedia of Finance Part 6 ppt

17 395 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 17
Dung lượng 571,13 KB

Nội dung

Chapter 9 CONDITIONAL ASSET PRICING WAYNE E. FERSON, Boston College, USA Abstract Conditional asset pricing studies predictability in the returns of financial assets, and the ability of asset pricing models to explain this predictability. The re- lation between predictability and asset pricing models is explained and the empirical evidence for predict- ability is summarized. Empirical tests of conditional asset pricing models are then briefly reviewed. KeyWords: stochastic discount factors; financial asset returns; predictability; rational expectations; conditional expectations; discount rates; stock prices; minimum-variance portfolios; mean vari- ance efficiency; latent variables; capital asset pri- cing models; market price of risk; multiple-beta models 9.1. Introduction Conditional Asset Pricing refers to a subset of Asset Pricing research in financial economics. (See Chapter 8.) Conditional Asset Pricing focuses on predictability over time in rates of return on financial assets, and the ability of asset pricing models to explain this predictability. Most asset pricing models are special cases of the fundamental equation: P t ¼ E t {m tþ1 (P tþ1 þ D tþ1 )}, (9:1) where P t is the price of the asset at time t, and D tþ1 is the amount of any dividends, interest or other payments received at time t þ 1. The market-wide random variable m tþ1 is the ‘‘stochastic discount factor’’ (SDF). By recursive substitution in Equa- tion (9.1), the future price may be eliminated to express the current price as a function of the future cash flows and SDFs only: P t ¼ E t { P j>0 ( Q k¼1, , j m tþk )D tþj }. Prices are obtained by ‘‘dis- counting’’ the payoffs, or multiplying by SDFs, so that the expected ‘‘present value’’ of the payoff is equal to the price. A SDF ‘‘prices’’ the assets if Equation (9.1) is satisfied, and any particular asset pricing model may be viewed as a specification for the stochastic discount factor. The notation E t {:} in Equation (9.1) denotes the conditional expectation, given a market-wide in- formation set, V t . Empiricists don’t get to see V t , so it is convenient to consider expectations condi- tional on an observable subset of instruments, Z t . These expectations are denoted as E(:jZ t ). When Z t is the null information set, we have the uncon- ditional expectation, denoted as E(.). Empirical work on conditional asset pricing models typically relies on ‘‘rational expectations,’’ which is the assumption that the expectation terms in the model are mathematical conditional expect- ations. This carries two important implications. First, it implies that the ‘‘law of iterated expectations’’ can be invoked. This says that the expectation, given coarser information, of the con- ditional expectation given finer information, is the conditional expectation given the coarser informa- tion. For example, taking the expected value of Equation (9.1), rational expectations implies that versions of Equation (9.1) must hold for the ex- pectations E(:jZ t ) and E(.). Second, rational ex- pectations implies that the differences between realizations of the random variables and the ex- pectations in the model, should be unrelated to the information that the expectations in the model are conditioned on. This leads to implications for the predictability of asset returns. Define the gross asset return, R itþ1 ¼ (P itþ1 þ D itþ1 )=P it The return of the asset i may be predictable. For example, a linear regression over time of R itþ1 on Z t may have a nonzero slope coefficient. Equation (9.1) implies that the conditional expectation of the product of m tþ1 and R itþ1 is the constant, 1.0. Therefore, 1 Àm tþ1 R itþ1 should not be predictably different from 0 using any information available at time t.If there is predictability in a return R itþ1 using any lagged instruments Z t , the model implies that the predictability is removed when R itþ1 is multiplied by the correct m tþ1 . This is the sense in which conditional asset pricing models are asked to ‘‘explain’’ predictable variation in asset returns. If a conditional asset pricing model fails to ex- plain predictability as described above, there are two possibilities (Fama, 1970, 1991). Either the specification of m tþ1 in the model is wrong, or the use of rational expectations is unjustified. The first instance motivates research on better condi- tional asset pricing models. The second possibility motivates research on human departures from ra- tionality, and how these show up in asset market prices. For a review of this relatively new field, ‘‘behavioral finance,’’ see Barberis and Shleifer (2003). Studies of predictability in stock and long-term bond returns typically report regressions that at- tempt to predict the future returns using lagged variables. These regressions for shorter horizon (monthly, or annual holding period) returns typic- ally have small R-squares, as the fraction of the variance in long-term asset returns that can be predicted with lagged variables over short horizons is small. The R-squares are larger for longer-hori- zon (two- to five-year) returns, because expected returns are considered to be more persistent than returns themselves. Thus, the variance of the expected return accumulates with longer horizons faster than the variance of the return, and the R-squared increases (Fama and French, 1988). Because stock returns are very volatile, small R-squares can mask economically important vari- ation in the expected return. To illustrate, consider a special case of Equation (9.1), the simple Gordon (1962) constant-growth model for a stock price: P ¼ kE=(R Àg), where P is the stock price, E is the earnings per share, k is the dividend payout ratio, g is the future growth rate of earnings, and R is the discount rate. The discount rate is the re- quired or expected return of the stock. Stocks are long ‘‘duration’’ assets, so a small change in the expected return can lead to a large fluctuation in the asset value. Consider an example where the price-to-earnings ratio, P=E ¼ 15, the payout ratio, k ¼ 0:6, and the expected growth rate, g ¼ 3 percent. The expected return, R, is 7 percent. Suppose there is a shock to the expected return, ceteris paribus. In this example a change of 1 per- cent in R leads to approximately a 20 percent change in the asset value. Of course, it is unrealistic to hold everything else fixed, but the example suggests that small changes in expected returns can produce large and econom- ically significant changes in asset values. Campbell (1991) generalizes the Gordon model to allow for stochastic changes in growth rates, and estimates that changes in expected returns through time may account for about half of the variance of equity index values. Conditional Asset Pricing models focus on these changes in the required or expected rates of return on financial assets. 9.2. The Conditional Capital Asset Pricing Model The simplest example of a conditional asset pricing model is a conditional version of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) of Sharpe (1964): E(R itþ1 jZ t ) ¼ g o (Z t ) þb imt g m (Z t ), (9:2) CONDITIONAL ASSET PRICING 377 where R itþ1 is the rate of return of asset i between times t and t þ 1, and b imt is the market beta at time t. The market beta is the conditional covar- iance of the return with the market portfolio div- ided by the conditional variance of the market portfolio; that is, the slope coefficient in a condi- tional regression of the asset return on that of the market, conditional on the information at time t. Z t is the conditioning information, assumed to be publicly available at time t. The term g m (Z t ) represents the risk premium for market beta, and g o (Z t ) is the expected return of all portfolios with market betas equal to zero. If there is a risk-free asset available at time t, then its rate of return equals g o (Z t ). Sharpe (1964) did not explicitly put the condi- tioning information, Z t , into his derivation of the CAPM. The original development was cast in a single-period partial equilibrium model. However, it is natural to interpret the expectations in the model as reflecting a consensus of well-informed analysts’ opinion – conditional expectations given their information – and Sharpe’s subsequent writ- ings indicated this intent (e.g. Sharpe, 1984). The multiple-beta intertemporal models of Merton (1973) and Cox–Ingersoll–Ross (1985) accommo- date conditional expectations explicitly. Merton (1973, 1980) and Cox–Ingersoll–Ross also showed how conditional versions of the CAPM may be derived as special cases of their models. Roll (1977) and others have shown that a port- folio is ‘‘minimum variance’’ if and only if a model like Equation (9.2) fits the expected returns for all the assets i, using the minimum-variance portfolio as R mtþ1 . A portfolio is minimum variance if and only if no portfolio with the same expected return has a smaller variance. According to the CAPM, the market portfolio with return R mtþ1 is minimum variance. If investors are risk averse, the CAPM also implies that the market portfolio is ‘‘mean- variance efficient,’’ which says that g m (Z t )in Equation (9.2) is positive. In the CAPM, risk- averse investors choose portfolios that have the maximum expected return, given the variance. This implies that there is a positive tradeoff be- tween market risk, as measured by b imt , and the expected return on individual assets, when inves- tors are risk averse. In the conditional CAPM, mean–variance efficiency is defined relative to the conditional expectations and conditional variances of returns. Hansen and Richard (1987) and Ferson and Siegel (2001) describe theoretical relations be- tween conditional and ‘‘unconditional’’ versions of mean–variance efficiency. The conditional CAPM may be expressed in the SDF representation given by Equation (9.1) as: m tþ1 ¼ c 0t À c 1t R mtþ1 . In this case, the coefficients c 0t and c 1t are specific measurable functions of the information set Z t , depending on the first and second conditional moments of the returns. To implement the model empirically, it is necessary to specify functional forms for c 0t and c 1t . Shanken (1990) suggests approximating the coefficients using linear functions, and this approach is fol- lowed by Cochrane (1996), Jagannathan and Wang (1996), and other authors. 9.3. Evidence for Return Predictability Conditional asset pricing presumes the existence of some return predictability. There should be instru- ments Z t for which E(m tþ1 jZ t )orE(R tþ1 jZ t ) vary over time, in order for E(m tþ1 R tþ1 À 1jZ t ) ¼ 0to have empirical bite. At one level, this is easy. Since E( m tþ1 jZ t ) should be the inverse of a risk-free return, all we need for the first condition to bite is observable risk-free rates that vary over time. Indeed, a short-term interest rate is one of the most prominent of the lagged instruments used to represent Z t in empirical work. Ferson (1977) shows that the behavior of stock returns and short-term interest rates, as documented by Fama and Schwert (1977), imply that conditional covar- iances of returns with m tþ1 must also vary over time. Interest in predicting security returns is prob- ably as old as the security markets themselves. Fama (1970) reviews the early evidence and Schwert (2003) reviews anomalies in asset pricing based on predictability. It is useful to distinguish, 378 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE following Fama (1970), predictability based on the information in past returns (‘‘weak form’’) from predictability based on lagged economic variables that are public information, not limited to past prices and returns (‘‘semi-strong’’ form). A large body of literature studies weak-form predictability, focusing on serial dependence in re- turns. High-frequency serial dependence, such as daily or intra-day patterns, are often considered to represent the effects of market microstructure, such as bid–ask spreads (e.g. Roll, 1984) and non- synchronous trading of the stocks in an index (e.g. Scholes and Williams, 1977). Serial dependence may also represent predictable changes in the expected returns. Conrad and Kaul (1989) report serial depend- ence in weekly returns. Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) find that relatively high-return recent ‘‘winner’’ stocks tend to repeat their performance over three- to nine-month horizons. DeBondt and Thaler (1985) find that past high-return stocks perform poorly over the next five years, and Fama and French (1988) find negative serial de- pendence over two- to five-year horizons. These serial dependence patterns motivate a large num- ber of studies, which attempt to assess the eco- nomic magnitude and statistical robustness of the implied predictability, or to explain the predictabil- ity as an economic phenomenon. For a summary of this literature subsequent to Fama (1970), see Campbell et al. (1997). Research in this area con- tinues, and it’s fair to say that the jury is still out on the issue of predictability using lagged returns. A second body of literature studies semi-strong form predictability using other lagged, publicly available information variables as instruments. Fama and French (1989) assemble a list of vari- ables from studies in the early 1980s, which as of this writing remain the workhorse instruments for conditional asset pricing models. In addition to the level of a short-term interest rate, as mentioned above, the variables include the lagged dividend yield of a stock market index, a yield spread of long-term government bonds relative to short-term bonds, and a yield spread of low-grade (high- default risk and low liquidity) corporate bonds over high-grade corporate bonds. In addition, studies often use the lagged excess return of a medium-term over a short-term Treasury bill (Campbell, 1987; Ferson and Harvey, 1991). Add- itional instruments include an aggregate book-to- market ratio (Pontiff and Schall, 1998) and lagged consumption-to-wealth ratios (Lettau and Ludvig- son, 2001a). Of course, many other predictor vari- ables have been proposed and more will doubtless be proposed in the future. Predictability using lagged instruments remains controversial, and there are some good reasons the measured predictability could be spurious. Studies have identified various statistical biases in predict- ive regressions (e.g. Hansen and Hodrick, 1980; Stambaugh, 1999; Ferson et al., 2003), and have questioned the stability of predictive relations across economic regimes (e.g. Kim et al., 1991; or Paye and Timmermann, 2003) and raised the pos- sibility that the lagged instruments arise solely through data mining (e.g. Lo and MacKinlay, 1990; Foster et al., 1997). A reasonable response to these concerns is to see if the predictive relations hold out-of-sample. This kind of evidence is also mixed. Some studies find support for predictability in step-ahead or out- of-sample exercises (e.g. Fama and French, 1989; Pesaran and Timmerman, 1995). Similar instru- ments show some ability to predict returns outside the United States, where they were originally stud- ied (e.g. Harvey, 1991; Solnik, 1993; Ferson and Harvey, 1993, 1999). However, other studies con- clude that predictability using the standard lagged instruments does not hold in more recent samples (e.g. Goyal and Welch, 2003; Simin, 2002). It seems that research on the predictability of security returns will always be interesting, and conditional asset pricing models should be useful in framing many future investigations of these issues. 9.4. Tests of Conditional CAPMs Empirical studies have rejected versions of the CAPM that ignore lagged variables. This evidence, CONDITIONAL ASSET PRICING 379 and mounting evidence of predictable variation in the distribution of security returns led to empirical work on conditional versions of the CAPM start- ing in the early 1980s. An example from Equation (9.2) illustrates the implications of the conditional CAPM for predictability in returns. Rational ex- pectations implies that the actual return differs from the conditional expected value by an error term, u itþ1 , which is orthogonal to the information at time t. If the actual returns are predictable using information in Z t , the model implies that either the betas or the premiums (g m (Z t ) and g o (Z t )), are changing as functions of Z t , and the time variation in those functions should track the predictable components of asset returns. If the time variation in g m (Z t ) and g o (Z t ) can be modeled, the condi- tional CAPM can be tested by examining its ability to explain the predictability in returns. The earliest empirical tests along these lines were the ‘‘latent variable models,’’ developed by Hansen and Hodrick (1983) and Gibbons and Ferson (1985), and later refined by Campbell (1987) and Ferson et al. (1993). These models allow time vary- ing expected returns, but maintain the assumption that the conditional betas are fixed parameters over time. Consider the conditional representation of the CAPM. Let r itþ1 ¼ R itþ1 À R 0tþ1 , and similarly for the market return, where R 0tþ1 is the gross, zero beta return. The conditional CAPM may then be stated for the vector of excess returns r tþ1 ,as E(r tþ1 jZ t ) ¼ bE(r mtþ1 jZ t ), where b is the vector of assets’ betas. Let r 1t be any reference asset excess return with nonzero beta, b 1 , so that E(r 1tþ1 jZ t ) ¼ b 1 E(r mtþ1 jZ t ). Solving this expres- sion for E(r mtþ1 jZ t ) and substituting, we have E(r tþ1 jZ t ) ¼ CE(r 1tþ1 jZ t ), where C ¼ (b=b 1 ). and .= denotes element-by-element division. The expected market risk premium is now a latent variable in the model, and C is the N-vector of the model parameters. Gibbons and Ferson (1985) argued that the latent variable model is attractive in view of the difficulties associated with measur- ing the true market portfolio of the CAPM, but Wheatley (1989) emphasized that it remains neces- sary to assume that ratios of the betas measured with respect to the unobserved market portfolio, are constant parameters. Campbell (1987) and Ferson and Foerster (1994) show that a single-beta latent variable model is rejected by the data. This rejects the hy- pothesis that there is a conditional minimum-vari- ance portfolio such that the ratios of conditional betas on this portfolio are fixed parameters. There- fore, the empirical evidence suggests that condi- tional asset pricing models should be consistent with either (1) a time varying beta, or (2) more than one beta for each asset. Conditional CAPMs with time varying betas are examined by Harvey (1989), replacing the constant beta assumption with the assumption that the ratio of the expected market premium to the conditional market variance is a fixed param- eter: E(r mtþ1 jZ t )=Var(r mtþ1 jZ t ) ¼ g. Then, the conditional expected returns may be written according to the conditional CAPM as E( r tþ1 jZ t ) ¼ g Cov(r tþ1 , r mtþ1 jZ t ). Harvey’s ver- sion of the conditional CAPM is motivated from Merton’s (1980) model, in which the ratio g, called the ‘‘market price of risk,’’ is equal to the relative risk aversion of a representative investor in equilibrium. Harvey also assumes that the con- ditional expected risk premium on the market (and the conditional market variance, given fixed g) is a linear function of the instruments: E( r mtþ1 jZ t ) ¼ d m 0 Z t , where d m is a coefficient vec- tor. He rejects this version of the conditional CAPM for monthly data in the United States. In Harvey (1991), the same formulation is rejected when applied to a world market portfolio and monthly data on the stock markets of 21 devel- oped countries. Lettau and Ludvigson (2001b) examine a condi- tional CAPM with time varying betas and risk premiums, using rolling time-series and cross-sec- tional regression methods. They condition the model on a lagged, consumption-to-wealth ratio, and find that the conditional CAPM works better for explaining the cross-section of monthly stock returns. 380 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE 9.5. Multi-beta Conditional Asset Pricing Models A multi-beta asset pricing model essentially ex- pands Equation (9.2) to allow for multiple sources of risk and expected return. Such a model asserts that the expected return is a linear function of several betas, i.e. E t (R itþ1 ) ¼ l 0t þ Æ j¼1, ,K b ijt l jt ,(9:3) where the b ijt , j ¼ 1, , K, are the conditional multiple regression coefficients of the return of asset i on K risk factors, f jtþ1 , j ¼ 1, , K. The coefficient l 0t is the expected return on an asset that has b 0jt ¼ 0, for j ¼ 1, , K; i.e. it is the expected return on a zero-(multiple-) beta asset. If there is a risk-free asset, then l 0t is the return of this asset. The coefficient l kt , corresponding to the k’th factor has the following interpretation: it is the expected return differential, or premium, for a portfolio that has b ikt ¼ 1 and b ijt ¼ 0 for all j 6¼ k, measured in excess of the zero-beta asset’s expected return. In other words, it is the expected return premium per unit of beta risk for the risk factor, k. Multiple-beta models follow when m tþ1 can be written as a conditional linear function of the K factors, as shown by Ferson and Jagan- nathan (1996). Bansal and Viswanathan (1993) developed con- ditional versions of the CAPM and multiple-factor models in which the stochastic discount factor m tþ1 is a nonlinear function of the market or factor returns. Using nonparametric methods, they find evidence to support the nonlinear versions of the models. Bansal et al. (1993) compare the perform- ance of nonlinear models with linear models, using data on international stocks, bonds, and currency returns, and they find that the nonlinear models perform better. Farnsworth et al. (2002) compared the empirical performance of a large set of condi- tional asset pricing models using the SDF repre- sentation. Conditional multiple-beta models with constant betas are examined empirically by Ferson and Har- vey (1991), Evans (1994), and Ferson and Korajc- zyk (1995), who find that while such models are rejected using the usual statistical tests, they still capture a large fraction of the predictability of stock and bond returns over time. Allowing for time varying betas, these studies find that the time variation in betas contributes a relatively small amount to the time variation in expected asset returns, while time variation in the risk pre- mium are relatively more important. While time variation in conditional betas is not as important as time variation in expected risk premiums, from the perspective of modeling pre- dictable time variation in asset returns, this does not imply that beta variation is empirically unim- portant. From the perspective of modeling the cross-sectional variation in ‘‘unconditional’’ expected asset returns, beta variation over time may be empirically very important. This idea was first explored by Chan and Chen (1988). To see how this works, consider the unconditional expected excess return vector, obtained from the model as E{ E(rjZ)} ¼ E{l(Z)b(Z)} ¼ E(l)E(b) þCov(l(Z),b(Z)). Viewed as a cross-sectional re- lation, the term Cov(l(Z),b(Z)) may differ signifi- cantly in a cross-section of assets. Therefore the implications of a conditional version of the CAPM for the cross-section of unconditional expected returns may depend importantly on common time variation in betas and expected market risk premiums. Jagannathan and Wang (1996) used the condi- tional CAPM to derive a particular ‘‘uncondi- tional’’ 2-factor model. They show that m tþ1 ¼ a 0 þ a 1 E(r mtþ1 jV t ) þR mtþ1 , where V t de- notes the information set of investors and a 0 and a 1 are fixed parameters, is a valid SDF in the sense that E(R i,tþ1 m tþ1 ) ¼ 1 for this choice of m tþ1 . Assuming that E(r mtþ1 jZ t ) is a linear function of Z t , they find that their version of the model explains the cross- section of unconditional expected returns better than an unconditional version of the CAPM. New empirical tests of the conditional CAPM and multiple-beta models, using the multi-beta representation and SDF representations, continue to appear regularly in the literature. Future studies will continue to refine the relationships among the CONDITIONAL ASSET PRICING 381 various empirical specifications. Research on the predictability of security returns will always be interesting, and Conditional Asset Pricing Models should be useful in framing many future investiga- tions of these issues. REFERENCES Bansal, R. and Viswanathan, S. (1993). ‘‘No arbitrage and arbitrage pricing: a new approach.’’ Journal of Finance, 48: 1231–1262. Bansal, R., Hsieh, D., and Viswanathan, S. (1993). ‘‘A new approach to international arbitrage prici ng.’’ Journal of Finance, 48: 1719–1747. Barberis, N. and Shleifer, A. (2003). ‘‘A survey of be- havioral finance,’’ in R. Stulz (ed.) Handbook of the Economics of Finance. North Holland: Elsevier. Campbell, J.Y. (1987). ‘‘Stock returns and the term structure.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 18: 373–399. Campbell, J.Y. (1991). ‘‘A variance decomposition for stock returns.’’ Economic Journal, 101: 157–179. Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A., and MacKinlay, A.C. (1997). The Econometrics of Financial Markets. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Chan, K.C. and Chen, N.F. (1988). ‘‘An unconditional test of asset pricing and the role of firm size as an instrumental variable for risk.’’ Journal of Finance, 63: 431–468. Cochrane, J.H. (1996). ‘‘A cross-sectional test of a pro- duction based asset pricing model.’’ Journal of Polit- ical Economy, 104(3): 572–621. Conrad, J. and Kaul, G. (1989). ‘‘Mean reversion in short-horizon expected returns.’’ Review of Financial Studies, 2: 225–240. Cox, J.C., Ingersoll, J.E., and Ross, S.A. (1985). ‘‘A theory of the term structure of interest rates.’’ Econ- ometrica, 53: 385–408. DeBondt, W. and Thaler, R. (1985). ‘‘Does the stock market overreact?’’ Journal of Finance, 40: 793–805. Evans, M.D.D. (1994). ‘‘Expected returns, time-varying risk and risk premia.’’ Journal of Finance , 49(2): 655–679. Fama, E.F. (1970). ‘‘Efficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work.’’ Journal of Finance, 25: 383–417. Fama, E.F. (1991). ‘‘Efficient capital markets II.’’ Jour- nal of Finance, 46: 1575–1618. Fama, E. and French, K. (1988) . ‘‘Permanent and tem- porary components of stock prices.’’ Journal of Pol- itical Economy, 96: 246–273. Fama, E. and French, K. (1989). ‘‘Business conditions and expected return s on stocks and bonds.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 25: 23–49. Fama, E.F. and Schwert, G.W. (1977). ‘‘Asset returns and inflation.’’ Journal of Financial Economics,5: 115–146. Farnsworth, H., Ferson, W.E., Jackson, D., and Todd, S. (2002). ‘‘Performance evaluation with stochastic dis- count factors. ’’ Journal of Business, 75: 473–504. Ferson, W.E. (1989). ‘‘Changes in expected security returns, risk and the level of interest rates.’’ Journal of Finance, 44: 1191–1217. Ferson, W.E. and Foerster, S.R. (1994). ‘‘Finite sample properties of the generalized methods of moments tests of conditional asset pricing models.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 36: 29–56. Ferson, W.E. and Harvey, C.R. (1991). ‘‘The variation of economic risk premiums.’’ Journal of Political Economy, 99: 385–415. Ferson, W.E. and Harvey, C.R. (1993). ‘‘The risk and predictability of international equity returns.’’ Re- view of Financial Studies, 6: 527–566. Ferson, W.E. and Harvey, C.R. (1999). ‘‘Economic, financial and fundamental global risk in and out of EMU.’’ Swedish Economic Policy Review,6: 123–184. Ferson, W.E. and Jagannathan, R. (1996). ‘‘Economet- ric evaluation of Asset Pricing Models,’’ in G.S. Mad- dala and C.R. Rao (eds.) Handbook of Statistics.14 Chapter 1, 1–30, Amsterdam, the Netherlands. Ferson, W.E. and Korajczyk, R.A. (1995). ‘‘Do arbi- trage pricing models explain the predictability of stock returns?’’ Journal of Business, 68: 309–349. Ferson, W.E. and Siegel, A.F. (2001). ‘‘The efficient use of conditioning information in portfolios.’’ Journal of Finance, 56: 967–982. Ferson, W.E., Foerster, S.R., and Keim, D.B. (1993). ‘‘General tests of latent variable models and mean variance spanning.’’ Journal of Finance, 48: 131–156. Ferson, W.E., Sarkissian, S., and Simin, T. (2003). ‘‘Spurious regressions in financial economics?’’ Jour- nal of Finance, 58: 1393–1414. Foster, D., Smith, T., and Whaley, R. (1997). ‘‘Asse ss- ing goodness-of-fit of asset pricing models: the dis- tribution of the maximal R-squared.’’ Journal of Finance, 52: 591–607. Gibbons, M.R. and Ferson, W.E . (1985). ‘‘Testing asset pricing models with changing expectations and an unobservable market portfolio.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 14: 217–236. Gordon, M. (1962). The investment, financing and valu- ation of the firm. Homewood, IL: Irwin. 382 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE Goyal, A., and Welch, I. (2003). ‘‘Predicting the equity premium with dividend ratios.’’ Management Sci- ence, 49(5). Hansen, L.P. and Hodrick, R. (1980). ‘‘Forward ex- change rates as optimal predictors of future spot rates: An econometric analysis.’’ Journal of Political Economy, 88: 829–853. Hansen, L.P. and Hodrick, R.J.(1983). ‘‘Risk averse speculation in the forward foreign exchange market,’’ in J. Frenkel (ed.) An econometric analysis of linear models, exchange rates and international macroeco- nomics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Hansen, L.P. and Richard, S.F. (1987). ‘‘The role of conditioning information in deducing testable re- strictions implied by dynamic asset pricing models.’’ Econometrica, 55: 587–613. Harvey, C.R. (1989). ‘‘Time-varying conditional covar- iances in tests of asset pricing models.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 24: 289–318. Harvey, C.R. (1991). ‘‘The world price of covariance risk.’’ Journal of Finance, 46: 111–157. Jagannathan, R. and Wang, Z. (1996). ‘‘The condi- tional CAPM and the cross-section of expected re- turns.’’ Journal of Finance, 51: 3–54. Jegadeesh, N. and Titman, S. (1993). ‘‘Returns to buying winners and selling losers: implications for stock mar- ket efficiency.’’ Journal of Finance, 48: 65–91. Kim, M., Nelson, C.R., and Startz, R. (1991). ‘‘Mean reversion in stock returns? a reappraisal of the stat- istical evidence.’’ Review of Economic Studies, 58: 515–528. Lettau, M. and Ludvigson, S. (2001a). ‘‘Consumption, aggregate wealth and expected stock returns.’’ Jour- nal of Finance, 56: 815–849. Lettau, M. and Ludvigson, S. (2001b). ‘‘Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A Cross-Sectional Test when Risk Premia are Time-Varying.’’ Journal of Political Econ- omy, 109(6): 1238–1287. Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A.C. (1990). ‘‘Data snooping biases in tests of financial asset pricing models.’’ Review of Financial Studies, 3: 431–468. Merton, R.C. (1973). ‘‘An intertemporal capital asset pricing model.’’ Econometrica, 41: 867–887. Merton, R.C. (1980). ‘‘On estimating the expected re- turn on the market: an exploratory investigation.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 8: 323–362. Paye, B. and Timmermann, A. (2003). ‘‘How stable are financial prediction models? Evidence from US and International Stock Market Data.’’ Working Paper, University of California at San Diego. Pesaran, M.H. and Timmermann, A. (1995). ‘‘Predict- ability of stock returns: Robustness and economic significance.’’ Journal of Finance, 50: 1201–1228. Pontiff, J. and Schall, L. (1998). ‘‘Book-to-market as a predictor of market returns.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 49: 141–160. Roll, R. (1977). ‘‘A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests -part 1: On past and potential testabil- ity of the theory.’’ Journal of Financial Economics,4: 129–176. Roll, R. (1984). ‘‘A simple implicit measure of the ef- fective bid-ask spread in an efficient market.’’ Jour- nal of Finance, 39: 1127–1140. Scholes, M. and Williams, J. (1977). ‘‘Estimating beta from nonsynchronous data.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 5: 309–327. Schwert, G.W. (2003). ‘‘Anomalies and market effi- ciency,’’ in G.M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R.M. Stulz (eds.) Handbook of the Economics of Finance. North Holland: Elsevier. Shanken, J. (1990). ‘‘Intertemporal asset pricing: an em- pirical investigation.’’ Journal of Econometrics, 45: 99–120. Sharpe, W.F. (1964). ‘‘Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.’’ Jour- nal of Finance, 19: 425–442. Sharpe, W.F. (1984). ‘‘Factor models, CAPM’s and the APT.’’ Journal of Portfolio Management, 11: 21–25. Simin, T. (2002). ‘‘The (poor) predictive performance of asset pricing models.’’ Working Paper, The Pennsyl- vania State University. Solnik, B. (1993). ‘‘The unconditional performance of international asset allocation strategies using condi- tioning information.’’ Journal of Empirical Finance, 1: 33–55 Stambaugh, R.S. (1999). ‘‘Predictive regressions.’’ Jour- nal of Financial Economics, 54: 315–421. Wheatley, S. (1989). ‘‘A critique of latent variable tests of asset pricing models.’’ Journal of Financial Eco- nomics, 23: 325–338. CONDITIONAL ASSET PRICING 383 Chapter 10 CONDITIONAL PERFORMANCE EVALUATION WAYNE E. FERSON, Boston College, USA Abstract Measures for evaluating the performance of a mu- tual fund or other managed portfolio are interpreted as the difference between the average return of the fund and that of an appropriate benchmark port- folio. Traditional measures use a fixed benchmark to match the average risk of the fund. Conditional performance measures use a dynamic strategy as the benchmark, matching the fund’s risk dynamics. The logic of this approach is explained, the models are described and the empirical evidence is reviewed. Keywords: security selection; market timing; invest- ment performance; benchmark portfolio; alpha; market efficiency; conditional alpha; risk dynamics; stochastic discount factor; conditional beta; port- folio weights; mutual funds; pension funds 10.1. Conditional Performance Evaluation Conditional Performance Evaluation is a collec- tion of empirical approaches for measuring the investment performance of portfolio managers, adjusting for the risks and other characteristics of their portfolios. A central goal of performance evaluation in general, is to identify those managers who possess investment information or skills su- perior to that of the investing public, and who use the advantage to achieve superior portfolio re- turns. Just as important, we would like to identify and avoid those managers with poor performance. Since the risks and expected returns of financial assets are related, it is important to adjust for the risks taken by a portfolio manager in evaluating the returns. In order to identify superior returns, some model of ‘‘normal’’ investment returns is required, i.e. an asset pricing model is needed (see the entries on Asset Pricing Models and Condi- tional Asset Pricing). Classical measures of investment performance compare the average return of a managed portfolio to that of a ‘‘benchmark portfolio’’ with similar risk. For example, Jensen (1968) advocated ‘‘alpha’’ as a performance measure. This is the average return minus the expected return implied by the Capital Asset Pricing Model (Sharpe, 1964). The CAPM implies that the expected return is a fund-specific combination of a safe asset and a broad market portfolio, and so this combination is the benchmark. Chen et al. (1987), Connor and Korajczyk (1986), and Lehmann and Modest (1987) extended this idea to multi-beta asset pri- cing models, where several returns are combined in the benchmark to adjust for the fund’s risk. It is traditional to distinguish between invest- ment ability for security selection and ability for market timing. Security selection refers to an ability to pick securities that are ‘‘undervalued’’ at current market prices, and which therefore may be expected to offer superior future returns. Market timing refers to an ability to switch the portfolio between stocks and bonds, anticipating which asset class will perform better in the near future. The classical performance measures are ‘‘unconditional,’’ in the sense that the expected returns in the model are unconditional means, es- timated by past averages, and the risks are the fixed unconditional second moments of return. If expected returns and risks vary over time, the clas- sical approach is likely to be unreliable. Ferson and Schadt (1996) showed that if the risk exposure of a managed portfolio varies predictably with the business cycle, but the manager has no superior investment ability, then a traditional approach will confuse common variation in the fund’s risk and the expected market returns with abnormal stock picking or market timing ability. ‘‘Condi- tional Performance Evaluation’’ (CPE) models the conditional expected returns and risk, attempt- ing to account for their changes with the state of the economy, thus controlling for any common variation. The problem of confounding variation in mu- tual fund risks and market returns has long been recognized (e.g. Jensen, 1972; Grant, 1977), but these studies tend to interpret such variation as reflecting superior information or market timing ability. A conditional approach to performance evaluation takes the view that a managed portfolio whose return can be replicated by mechanical trad- ing, based on readily available public information, should not be judged to have superior perform- ance. CPE is therefore consistent with a version of market efficiency, in the semi-strong form sense of Fama (1970). In the CPE approach a fund’s return is com- pared with a benchmark strategy that attempts to match the fund’s risk dynamics. The benchmark strategy does this by mechanically trading, based on predetermined variables that measure the state of the economy. The performance measures, the ‘‘conditional alphas,’’ are the difference between a fund’s return and that of the benchmark dynamic strategy. This generalizes the classical performance measures, such as Jensen’s alpha, which compare a fund’s return with a fixed benchmark that carries the same average risk. Since CPE uses more infor- mation than traditional performance measures, it has the potential to provide more accuracy. In practice, the trading behavior of managers over- lays portfolio dynamics on the dynamic behavior of the underlying assets that they trade. For ex- ample, even if the risk of each security were fixed over time, the risk of a portfolio with time-varying weights, would be time varying. The desire to han- dle such dynamic behavior motivates a conditional approach. Investors may wish to understand how funds implement their investment policies dynam- ically over time. For example, how is a fund’s bond–stock mix, market exposure, or investment style expected to react in a time of high-interest rates or market volatility? CPE is designed to pro- vide a rich description of funds’ portfolio dynamics in relation to the state of the economy. A conditional approach to performance evalu- ation can accommodate whatever standard of su- perior information is held to be appropriate, by the choice of the lagged instruments, which are used to represent the public information. Incorporating a given set of lagged instruments, managers who trade mechanically in response to these variables get no credit for superior performance. To repre- sent public information, much of the empirical literature to date has focused on a standard set of lagged variables. Examples include the levels of interest rates and interest rate spreads, dividend- to-price ratios, and dummy variables indicating calendar-related patterns of predictability. More recent studies expand the analysis to consider a wider range of indicators for public information about the state of the economy (e.g. Ferson and Qian, 2004). 10.2. Examples Implementations of Conditional Performance Evaluation have typically used either simple linear regression models or ‘‘stochastic discount factor’’ CONDITIONAL PERFORMANCE EVALUATION 385 [...]... (1 968 ) ‘‘The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1 964 .’’ Journal of Finance, 23: 389-3 46 Jensen, M (ed.) (1972) Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets New York: Praeger Publishers Jiang, W (2003) ‘‘A nonparametric test of market timing.’ Journal of Empirical Finance, 10: 399–425 Kazemi, H (2003) ‘‘Conditional Performance of Hedge Funds.’’ Working Paper, University of Massachusetts at Amherst... ‘‘Portfolio performance and the ‘‘cost’’ of timing decisions.’’ Journal of Finance, 32: 837–8 46 Grinblatt, M and Titman, S (1989a) ‘‘Portfolio performance evaluation: old issues and new insights.’’ Review of Financial Studies, 2: 393–4 16 Grinblatt, M and Titman, S (1989b) ‘‘Mutual fund performance: an analysis of quarterly portfolio holdings.’’ Journal of Business, 62 : 393–4 16 Grinblatt, M and Titman, S (1993)... economic conditions.’’ Journal of Finance, 51: 425– 462 Ferson, W and Warther, V.A (19 96) ‘‘Evaluating fund performance in a dynamic market.’’ Financial Analysts Journal, 52 (6) : 20–28 Ferson, W., Henry, T., and Kisgen, D (20 06) ‘‘Evaluating government bond fund performance with stochastic discount factors,’’ Review of Financial Studies (forthcoming) 392 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE Grant, D (1977) ‘‘Portfolio... 513–534 Sharpe, W.F (1 964 ) ‘‘Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.’’ Journal of Finance, 19: 425-442 Starks, L (1987) ‘‘Performance incentive fees: an agency theoretic approach.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22: 17–32 Treynor, J and Mazuy, K (1 966 ) ‘‘Can mutual funds outguess the market?’’ Harvard Business Review, 44: 131–1 36 Wermers, R (1997)... large body of empirical literature on the performance of mutual funds Equity-style mutual funds have received the most attention There are fewer studies of institutional funds such as pension funds, and a relatively small number of studies focus on fixed-income-style funds Research on the performance of hedge funds has been accumulating rapidly over the past few years 390 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE Traditional... Journal of Financial Economics, 7: 381–390 Cumby, R and Glen, J (1990) ‘‘Evaluating the performance of international mutual funds.’’ Journal of Finance, 45: 497–521 Dahlquist, M and Soderlind, P (1999) ‘‘Evaluating portfolio performance with stochastic discount factors.’’ Journal of Business, 72: 347–384 Fama, E F (1970) ‘‘Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work.’’ Journal of Finance, ... look at the persistence of performance.’’ Review of Financial Studies, 11: 111–142 Connor, G and Korajczyk, R (19 86) ‘‘Performance measurement with the arbitrage pricing theory: A new framework for analysis.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 373–394 Copeland, T.E and Mayers, M (1982) ‘‘The value line enigma (1 965 –1978): A case study of performance evaluation issues.’’ Journal of Financial Economics,... examination of mutual fund returns.’’ Journal of Business, 60 : 97–112 Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., and Wermers, R (1995) ‘‘Momentum strategies, portfolio performance and herding: a study of mutual fund behavior.’’ American Economic Review, 85: 1088–1105 Henriksson, R.D (1984) ‘‘Market timing and mutual fund performance: an empirical investigation.’’ Journal of Business, 57: 73– 96 Jensen, M (1 968 ) ‘‘The... the return of the fund in excess of a short term ‘‘cash’’ instrument and apJ is Jensen’s alpha Ferson and Schadt (19 96) proposed the conditional model: rptþ1 ¼ ap þ bo rmtþ1 þ b0 ½rmtþ1  Zt Š þ uptþ1 , (10:2) where Zt is the vector of lagged conditioning variables and ap is the conditional alpha The coefficient bo is the average beta of the fund, and b0 Z t captures the time-varying part of the conditional... comparison of benchmarks and benchmark comparisons.’’ Journal of Finance, 42: 233- 265 Mamaysky, H., Spiegel, M and Zhang, H (2003) ‘‘Estimating the dynamics of mutual fund alphas and betas.’’ Working Paper, Yale School of Organization and Management Merton, R.C and Henriksson, R.D (1981) ‘‘On market timing and investment performance II: Statistical procedures for evaluating forecasting skills.’’ Journal of . Jour- nal of Business, 57: 73– 96. Jensen, M. (1 968 ). ‘‘The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945-1 964 .’’ Journal of Finance, 23: 389-3 46. Jensen, M. (ed.) (1972). Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets predictability of stock returns?’’ Journal of Business, 68 : 309–349. Ferson, W.E. and Siegel, A.F. (2001). ‘‘The efficient use of conditioning information in portfolios.’’ Journal of Finance, 56: 967 –982. Ferson,. risk.’’ Journal of Finance, 63 : 431– 468 . Cochrane, J.H. (19 96) . ‘‘A cross-sectional test of a pro- duction based asset pricing model.’’ Journal of Polit- ical Economy, 104(3): 572 62 1. Conrad, J.

Ngày đăng: 06/07/2014, 08:20

TỪ KHÓA LIÊN QUAN