Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 385 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
385
Dung lượng
1,51 MB
Nội dung
Joseph A. Schumpeter
[1883-1950]
Économiste autrichien classique, professeur à l'Université de Harvard,
aux États-Unis, à partir de 1932, 1883-1950
(1939)
BUSINESS CYCLES
A Theoretical,HistoricalandStatistical
Analysis oftheCapitalistProcess
Abridged, with an introduction, by Rendigs Fels
Un document produit en version numérique par Didier LAGRANGE, bénévole,
Chef de projets dans une entreprise du secteur automobile, France
Courriel: lagrange2@free.fr
Dans le cadre de: "Les classiques des sciences sociales"
Une bibliothèque numérique fondée et dirigée par Jean-Marie Tremblay,
professeur de sociologie au Cégep de Chicoutimi
Site web: http://classiques.uqac.ca/
Une collection développée en collaboration avec la Bibliothèque
Paul-Émile-Boulet de l'Université du Québec à Chicoutimi
Site web: http://bibliotheque.uqac.ca/
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 2
Cette édition électronique a été réalisée par Didier LAGRANGE, bénévole, Chef de
projets dans une entreprise du secteur automobile, France à partir de :
Joseph A. Schumpeter [1883-1950]
BUSINESS CYCLES. ATheoretical,HistoricalandStatisticalAnalysisof
the Capitalist Process.
New York Toronto London : McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1939, 461 pp.
Abridged, with an introduction, by Rendigs Fels
Polices de caractères utilisée :
Pour le texte: Times New Roman, 14 points.
Pour les citations : Times New Roman, 12 points.
Pour les notes de bas de page : Times New Roman, 12 points.
Édition électronique réalisée avec le traitement de textes Microsoft Word
2004 pour Macintosh.
Mise en page sur papier format : LETTRE (US letter), 8.5’’ x 11’’)
Édition numérique réalisée le 14 juillet 2007 à Chicoutimi,
Ville de Saguenay, province de Québec, Canada. Fichier revu
et corrigé le 31 mars 2008.
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 3
Joseph A. Schumpeter [1883-1950]
BUSINESS CYCLES.
A Theoretical,HistoricalandStatisticalAnalysis
of theCapitalist Process.
New York Toronto London : McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1939, 461 pp.
Abridged, with an introduction, by Rendigs Fels
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 4
Table of Contents
I. EDITOR'S INTRODUCTION
II. Chapter I.
INTRODUCTORY
III. Chapter II. EQUILIBRIUM ANDTHE THEORETICAL NORM OF
ECONOMIC QUANTITIES
A.
The Meaning ofa Model
B. The Fundamental Question
C. The Stationary Flow
D. Equilibrium andthe Theoretical Norm
E. Complications and Clarifications
F. Imperfect Competition
G. Equilibrium Economics andthe Study ofBusiness Fluctuations
IV. Chapter III. HOW THE ECONOMIC SYSTEM GENERATES EVOLU-
TION
A. Internal Factors of Change
B. The Theory of Innovation
C. The Entrepreneur and His Profit
D. The Role of Money and Banking in theProcessof Evolution
E. Interest (Money Market; Capital)
V. Chapter IV. THE CONTOURS OF ECONOMIC EVOLUTION
A. The Working ofthe Model; First Approximation
B. Looking at the Skeleton
C. The Secondary Wave; Second Approximation
D. Many Simultaneous Cycles; Third Approximation
VI. Chapter V. TIME SERIES AND THEIR NORMAL
A.
Introduction
B. Trend
C. A Single Cyclical Movement
D. Many Simultaneous Waves
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 5
VII. Chapter VI. HISTORICAL OUTLINES. I. INTRODUCTION; 1786-1842
A.
The Fundamental Importance oftheHistorical Approach to the Prob-
lems ofthe Cyclical Processof Evolution.
B. Questions of Principle. —A few questions of principle must be dis-
posed of first
C. The Long Wave from 1787 to 1842
VIII. Chapter VII.
HISTORICAL OUTLINES. II. 1843-1913
A. The Period 1843-1897.
B. The Agricultural Situations ofthe Period
C. Railroadization
D. Some Features ofthe Development of Manufactures
E. The First Sixteen Years ofthe Third Kondratieff (1893-1913)
IX. Chapter VIII. 1919-1929
A. Postwar Events and Postwar Problems
B. Comments on Postwar Patterns
C. Further Comments on Postwar Conditions
D. Outlines of Economic History from 1919 to 1929
E. The "Industrial Revolution" ofthe Twenties
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 6
Joseph Schumpeter,
BUSINESS CYCLES (1939)
I.
EDITOR’S INTRODUCTION
RENDIGS Fels -
Vanderbilt University
Table of Contents
"The younger generation of economists should look upon this book
merely as something to shoot at and start from—as a motivated pro-
gram for further research."'—Joseph A. Schumpeter, Preface to Busi-
ness Cycles, 1939 edition, p. v.
Schumpeter had bad luck with Business Cycles.
1
The most ambi-
tious work ofthe trilogy setting forth "the Schumpeterian system," it
has attracted less attention than his Theory of Economic Develop-
ment
2
or his Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy.
3
It is true that a
reference to Business Cycles can occasionally be found in a footnote,
but the text to which the footnote is appended rarely contains a dis-
1
The full citation is Joseph A. Schumpeter, Business Cycles : ATheoretical,
Historical, andStatisticalAnalysisoftheCapitalist Process, 1
st
edition (New
York and London : McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1939}. Schumpeter,
an Austrian economist who spent the last eighteen years of his life at Har-
vard, was born in 1883 and died in 1950. For an account of his life see the
"Memorial" by Arthur Smithies in the American Economic Review, Sep-
tember 1950, pp. 628-45.
2
The Theory of Economic Development ; an Inquiry into Profits, Capital,
Credit, Interst, andtheBusiness Cycle, translated from the German by Red-
vers Opie (Cambridge, Mass. : Harvard University Press, 1934).
3
3d edition (New York : Harper & Brothers Publishers, 1950).
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 7
criminating discussion of its ideas. Clemence and Doody accorded it
its proper place in The Schumpeterian System, but they preferred de-
fending their former teacher against criticism to paying him the higher
compliment of building on his work.
4
The publication date ofBusiness Cycles proved singularly unfor-
tunate. Had it appeared three years before Keynes's General Theory
sent economists scurrying off in other directions instead of three years'
afterwards, it would have gained from the enormous interest everyone
had in business cycles in 1933 and might have been accorded a recep-
tion second only to that later received by the General Theory itself.
5
Instead, it appeared just as the outbreak of World War II raised eco-
nomic problems to which Keynes's tools, but not Schumpeter's, could
be readily adapted. But Business Cycles lost almost as much from ap-
pearing six years too soon as from appearing six years too late. Given
a different title, it might in 1945 have profited from the growing inter-
est in economic development, for its theme is as much how the pre-
sent industrial nations developed as the themes indicated by its title
and subtitle. Modern scholars can hardly be blamed if they turn for
Schumpeter's ideas on the subject that currently fascinates them to a
book called The Theory of Economic Development rather than to a
book called Business Cycles.
They might have done so even if the titles had been reversed ; they
might well prefer the shorter, more finished account to the longer, less
polished one. The kind of fault that contributed to the success of
Keynes's General Theory added to the neglect of Schumpeter's Busi-
ness Cycles. Both would have been better books had their authors
spent another year improving them. Whereas the shortcomings ofthe
General Theory stimulated other economists to lay bare and refine and
4
Richard V. Clemence and Francis S. Doody, The Schumpeterian System
(Cambridge, Mass. : Addison-Wesley Press, 1950).
5
John M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money
(New York : Harcourt, Brace and Company, 1936).
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 8
apply the model half-concealed in it, incidentally making Keynesians
of them, the similar need to clarify and improve and use the Schum-
peterian model repelled them. There are no Schumpeterians. One need
not take issue with Schumpeter's criticism of Marshall for lavishing
too much time on the eight editions ofthe Principles to hold that he
himself made the opposite error.
6
Though a quarter ofa century has elapsed since the first edition of
Business Cycles, the opportunities it opened up for further research
remain largely unexploited. The chief exception is Schumpeter's own
Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. Much has been published on
innovation and entrepreneurship, usually with a nod in Schumpeter's
direction but no more. Even a work like Yusif A. Sayigh's Entrepre-
neurs of Lebanon, which ostensibly takes Schumpeter's concepts as its
starting point, actually deals with entrepreneurs as people—their edu-
cation, religion, opinions, even the number of their children—to the
neglect of what was central to Schumpeter's analysis, innovating ac-
tivity and its impact.
7
At the time Business Cycles was written, work on Kuznets cy-
cles—the long swings of fifteen to twenty years—was still at an early
stage. Since then a large amount ofstatisticalanda small amount of
analytical work has gone forward. Those who have made the principal
efforts to explain Kuznets cycles, Matthews and Abramovitz, have not
seen fit to draw on Schumpeter's work but have resorted to an incom-
plete and essentially aggregative tool, the capital-stock adjustment
principle.
8
(It is ironic that a generation of economists that tegards
6
«Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics, 8th edition (London : Macmil-
lan and Co., limited, 1922).
7
Entrepreneurs of Lebanon ; The Role ofthe Burine» Leader in a Developing
Economy (Cambridge, Mass. : Harvard University Press, 1962).
8
R.C.O. Matthews, TheBusiness Cycle (Chicago : University of Chicago
Press, 1959), Ch. 12 ; Moses Abramovitz, "The Nature and Significance of
Kuznets Cycles," Economic Development and Cultural Change, April 1961,
pp. 225-48.
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 9
disaggregation as a shining virtue has underestimated the theory of
such a staunch opponent of aggregation as Schumpeter. In our heart of
hearts, we prefer the aggregates of Keynes, Harrod, Domar, etc. ; de-
spite Walras's earlier and better claim to a general theory, we permit-
ted Keynes to take over the term, Schumpeter's objections notwith-
standing. Our cant about disaggregation means only that we have
guilty consciences.) Yet Schumpeter's concept of recesssion could be
exceedingly helpful in interpreting the 1870s, a period which raises a
problem ignored by Matthews and Abramovitz in the works cited in
the footnote above. Their most telling evidence for the existence of
Kuznets cycles consists of two circumstances, swings in the rate of
growth of real GNP that average fifteen to twenty years, andthe re-
currence of deep depressions at similar intervals—there was one in the
1870s, one in the 1890s, there would (or might) have been one in the
1910s but for World War I, and there was one in the 1930s. Including
1873-78 in the category of deep depressions at first sight seems rea-
sonable enough, since it is generally considered not only the longest
but also one ofthe worst business contractions on record. But
Abramovitz shows a "tentative" peak in the rate of growth of real
GNP, after eliminating the effects ofbusiness cycles, which he dates
1874.25.9 This means that the average annual rate of growth between
the complete business cycle with peaks in 1869 and 1873 andthe
complete business cycle with peaks in 1873 and 1882 was higher than
for neighboring pairs of cycles—in fact it was the highest on record
for any successive pairs of cycles, in spite ofthe fact that the contrac-
tion included in the 1873-82 period is rated a deep depression,
whereas the contraction phase ofthe preceding cycle was very mild.
Thus thestatistical finding about the rate of growth of real GNP col-
lides with the judgment that 1873-78 was a deep depression ; further-
more, it plays hob with Abramovitz's analysisofthe way Kuznets cy-
cles unfold, in which deep depressions and troughs in growth rates go
together. How can the paradox ofa rapid rate of growth in a period
encompassing deep depression be resolved ? Schumpeter's concept of
recession could illuminate it : previous innovation must have made
possible a great increase in output that imposed hardship—symptoms
Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles. (1939) 10
of depression—on all parts ofthe economy unable to adapt to the new
conditions. Not that one can turn to Schumpeter's own account ofthe
1870s for a ready-made explanation ofthe facts Matthews and
Abramovitz have wrestled with ; it is rather that today's economists
are missing an opportunity to build on Schumpeter's work.
The importance ofa book is judged by what it leads to. By this
test, it is doubtful if Schumpeter's Business Cycles would merit rescue
from the limbo of "out of print." The first reason for the present edi-
tion lies in the conviction that it can yet stimulate significant research.
Why an abridged edition ? Ordinarily, I deplore abridgements, but in
the present case there is every reason to believe that a shorter version
will prove more useful, especially since the longer one will always be
available in libraries. Eliminating digressions andthe less valuable
parts ofthe original two volumes, which ran to more than a thousand
pages, will enable the reader, I hope, to spend his time more profita-
bly. Having myself spent a great deal of labor trying to master the
original edition, I have nothing but sympathy for economists who felt
that it was not worth the effort
In the work of abridgement, my first concern has been to preserve
a complete statement ofthe theory, since less thorough accounts are
readily available elsewhere. This has meant retaining most of Chap-
ters II, HI, and IV and parts of Chapters I and V. Even in Chapters II-
IV, however, I have not hesitated to cut footnotes, paragraphs, and
whole pages where the discussion seemed to go pretty far afield, as
well as deleting superfluous sentences and phrases. Although I hope
that what remains is somewhat more readable than the original, it is
still hard going, and I would have liked to add as an appendix a sum-
mary of Schumpeter's theory that I prepared for my own use many
years ago. But it seemed better to save the space for Schumpeter's
own words. Besides, an excellent summary of Schumpeter's theory is
[...]... the rationale ofthe idea of variables that do not vary, the justification ofthe schema ofa stationary economic processThe values of prices and quantities which are the only ones, the data being what they are in each case, to satisfy those relations, we call equilibrium values The state ofthe system which obtains if all prices and quantities take their equilibrium values we call the state of equilibrium... could arise only from those aggregates Such reasoning is at the bottom of much faulty analysis of business cycles It keeps analysis on the surface of things and prevents it from penetrating into the industrial processes below, which are what really matters It invites a mechanistic and formalistic treatment of a few isolated contour lines and attributes to aggregates a life of their own anda causal significance... nature of economic phenomena only if it is possible to deduce prices and quantities from the data by means of those relations and to prove that no other set of prices and physical quantities is compatible with both the data andthe relations The proof that this is so is the magna charts of economic theory as an autonomous science, assuring us that its subject matter is a cosmos and not a chaos It is the. .. setting ofthe new countries, the exports into andthe imports from them, are part ofthe economic process, as they are part of economic history, and not outside of it Again, the invention of, say, the Montgolfier balloon was not an external factor ofthebusiness situation of its time ; it was, indeed, no factor at all The same is true of all inventions as such, witness the inventions ofthe antique... however, there is some freedom of choice between combinations, which means that it is possible to produce the bushel of wheat either with, say, a certain quantity of land anda certain quantity of labor or with more land and less labor or less land and more labor, other factors remaining constant, then the economic problem emerges in the shape of considerations about costs and values This is what is usually... hostility to it as soon as it was rigorously defined and made to stand out in all the gauntness of its abstractions This was attempted by the physiocrats and definitely achieved by Leon Walras The Marshallian structure is based upon the same conception, which it is important to emphasize in view ofthe fact that Marshall did not like it and almost made it disappear from the surface of his exposition The commonsense... listed in the same category as far as they may be considered, from the standpoint ofthebusiness organism, to be chance events But it is a fact that variations in the total supply of gold often come about in response to business situations and in exactly the same Joseph Schumpeter, Business Cycles (1939) 15 way as variations in the supply of any other commodity The variations in the monetary supply of gold... either by the monopolists themselves or by some agency which takes them away from the monopolists, for otherwise they would change the stationary flow As far as monopoly gains are due to the peculiar quality of some factor or to a monopolistic organization of those who own the factor, these gains will simply appear as wages or rents and may be entered into the appropriate category If there are appliances,... become an external factor, for it was not directly relevant to the course ofthe economic process at all It acquired relevance only as and when the new possibilities were turned into commercial and industrial reality, and then the individual acts of realization and not the possibilities themselves are what concern us Those acts, the formation of companies for the exploitation ofthe new opportunities, the. .. andof its application to one country dictated omitting virtually all the statistical analysis (Chapters VII-XIII anda long section of Chapter XIV ofthe original edition) One ofthe reviews that appeared not long after the 1939 edition was published criticized it for not having a serviceable statistical technique The criticism was just, and omitting thestatistical chapters may be deemed no great . contains a dis- 1 The full citation is Joseph A. Schumpeter, Business Cycles : A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process, 1 st edition (New York and London. Cycles was written, work on Kuznets cy- cles the long swings of fifteen to twenty years—was still at an early stage. Since then a large amount of statistical and a small amount of analytical work. Central Bank in Europe may be itself an act of business behavior and an element of the mechanism of cycles, as well as an external factor ; and so may collective measures taken by the business