Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 129 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
129
Dung lượng
1,82 MB
Nội dung
Chapter 1
Introduction
Background
Corruption has been a major policy concern across the globe because it
is detrimental both to economic development and political stability, and to
citizens‘ welfare. Countries plagued by widespread corruption often see
increasing income inequality, underinvestment and misallocation of resources
(Tanzi, 1998). As a country with the world‘s largest population, China has
experienced aggravation of corruption since the late 1970s with the start of
economic reforms. In 2009, Transparency International‘s Corruption
Perception Index (CPI) ranked China 79th among 180 countries.1 In the same
year, China‘s procuratorates investigated 4,1531 public officials for
work-related crime, with the recovered amounts on corruption cases valued at
7,120 million RMB (US$1,100 million or S$1,352 million).2 Corruption has
spread across various economic sectors and industries, particularly in
capital-intensive sectors such as real estate, construction, finance, customs,
taxation, and medical health in China.
Among various areas of Chinese corruption, this thesis focuses on
corruption related to land management, which has grown to unprecedented
1
See Transparency International, ―Corruption Perceptions Index 2009‖, available at
http://www.transparency.org/policy_research/surveys_indices/cpi/2009/cpi_2009_table
2
See Supreme People‘s Procuratorate of the PRC., ―Zuigao Renmin Jianchayuan Gongzuo
Baogao‖ [―Report on the work of the Supreme People‘s Procuratorate‖], available at
http://www.spp.gov.cn/site2006/2010-03-11/0002126662.html.
1
proportions in recent decades and become a major focal point in the country
(Deng, Zhang, & Leverentz, 2010). Land corruption encompasses a variety of
forms such as bribery in land use rights (hereafter LURs) assignment,
embezzlement and misappropriation of land-related revenues, land grabbing,
land sales in the black market, and other abusive land use behaviors that
violate land laws and principles. A 2009 survey in Guangdong Province found
that the construction and land planning departments were perceived to be the
most corrupt among government organizations.3 The magnitude of illegal
land use by local authorities is substantial; in the 11-year period from 1998 to
2008, over a million (1,215,117) illegal land use cases involving 534,834
hectares of land were filed by the Ministry of Land and Resources, among
which 237,094 hectares were farmland.4
The rise of corruption involved in land development remains among
the most contentious social, political and economic issues in contemporary
China (Chow, 2006; Lin & Ho, 2005). Land is fundamental to successful
marketization and urbanization, and the study of land corruption is of great
importance for at least four reasons. First, illegal land-use behaviors cause
losses of state-owned-assets and government revenues. For instance, corrupt
officials may sell urban state-owned land to investors at below market prices
in exchange for bribes, making the state suffer from capital losses. Second,
3
See Guangzhou Daily, ―Guangzhou Lianzheng Diaocha Xianshi Jianshe Guotu Bumen Ju
Fubai Shouwei‖ [―Guangzhou Anticorruption Survey Ranks Construction and Land Planning
Department the First‖], available at http://society.people.com.cn/GB/42735/12390009.html
4
Source: China Land and Resources Almanac, 1999-2009, compiled by the Ministry of Land
and Resources.
2
land corruption widens the gap between the rich and the poor by unequally
distributing land resources to different groups. In rural-urban peripheries, local
governments and developers often take farmers‘ land at low cost and sell the
LURs at high prices, reaping huge profits from land transference.
Consequently, real estate developers and those in power are better-off, while
the under-compensated farmers become landless and often jobless, suffering
from welfare loss. Third, land corruption erodes public trust, creates social
unrest and political instability. It strikes at the legitimacy of the ruling party
and affects the wellbeing of citizens in China. In urban areas, corruption and
abuse of power are driving massive toll breakdown by force (qiang chai).
Urban residents are constantly reported to protect their property from being
destroyed illegally by real estate agencies and local governments. In rural
areas, peasants‘ petitions and protests against illegal land-use are taking place
throughout the country. Central government officials acknowledge that 40%
of peasants‘ petitions are likely related to land disputes.5 Forth, the misuse of
land leads to farmland loss, threatens food security, adversely affects
economic production and suitable development. China‘s average area of
farmland per capita is only 40% of the world average, and 7,950 hectares of
farmland were lost between 1998 and 2008.6 The situation is aggravated by
5
See The Beijing News, ―Nongmin Shangfang Sicheng Yu Tudi Youguan‖ [―Forty Percent of
Peasants‘ Petitions are Related to Land‖],
http://news.xinhuanet.com/local/2011-03/25/c_121230216.htm.
6
See Jianping Ye and Youhui Zhang, ―Chengzhenhua Suo Yinfa De Wenti‖ [―The Problems
Caused by Urbanization‖],
http://www.qstheory.cn/ts/zxyd/byydtd/201003/t20100325_25146.htm.
3
illegal acquisition and conversion of land in rural-urban peripheries. To
address the pressure of economic development and urban expansion, large
amount of farm land is converted for non-agricultural purposes and food
security will become one of the major concerns for the central government. To
make matters worse, many pieces of land are acquired and converted in
violation of resources-protection laws and principles. These abusive and
illegal land management activities make land resources wasted, overexploited,
and ineffectively used.
The absence of corruption has a positive influence on the quality of
land management. From an environmental perspective, proper distribution of
land without abuses and corruption considers the responsibilities of protecting
natural resources and overall urban planning principles. Hence the possibilities
of overexploiting land resources can be reduced. Second, proper land
distribution without corruption is politically beneficial. A corruption-free land
administration system promotes citizens‘ sentiment of fairness and alleviate
the inequality over land use and serves the interest of local communities and
the general public. As a result, we expect the occurrence of inequalities,
disputes and social unrest can be prevented. Third, from the economic
perspective, proper and corruption-free land distribution strategies intend to
make use of land resources more effectively and more efficiently that
land-wasting behaviors cannot be tolerated. If land administration officials
abuse their power to grant or block access to land, the value of land can be
4
underestimated and underutilized.
In short, numerous social problems such as the loss of farmland, social
unrest, environment deterioration, deprivation of human rights, poverty and
inequality can be attributed to corrupt and illegal government activities in the
land sector, while a proper, accountable and corruption-free land management
system contributes to the development of a society and the welfare of its
citizens.
Research Questions and Objectives
Land corruption has become synonymous with, and surging alongside,
market-oriented land reforms in contemporary China. Both urban and rural
areas have witnessed gigantic reconstruction within the land administration
system, but urban land reforms are more influential and appear to be the
driving force behind rural land reforms in many places. Therefore, this
research focuses on urban land, with occasional reference to rural land.
Urban land reforms in contemporary China have centered around the
commercialization of LURs; more specifically, the introduction of paid land
leasing system and abandonment of free administrative allocation of land
under the socialist land management system (Zhu, 1999b). The transformation
from the state-led to market-led land allocation paradigm has been
accompanied by a rise in rampant land corruption in the 1990s (Gong, 1997;
Deng, Zhang &Leverentz, 2010). At the initial stage of land reforms (late
5
1980s to mid-1990s), the level of marketization was very low and urban land
supply was still subject to heavy state control. Restrictions on land
transference and limited access to land encouraged illegal land transactions in
the black market, besides, power was abused to obtain inside land-use
information for personal gains. In part to address the rampant corruption and
black market in the land sector, the Chinese central government decided to
reconstruct the urban land supply system. A deepening adoption of
market-driven urban land leasehold was witnessed in the 2000s. The previous
free and discounted allocation methods were gradually replaced by market-led
land pricing and allocation modes such as public tender, auction, and
quotation. The main objective was to end the perceived government monopoly
in resources allocation and to restrain local officials‘ discretion in land
licensing and permitting, in hopes that it would curb unprecedented
land-related corruption. The Ministry of Supervision, which worked
aggressively with the Ministry of Land and Resources to promote the new
policy, claimed that these tender, auction and quotation modes could reduce
government intervention in the land market and protect principles of openness
and fairness, and would be able to prevent corruption at its source.7
However, it is debatable whether this new policy has succeeded in
reducing corruption. Firstly, very few empirical studies have explored the
7
See ―Guotuziyuanbu Jianchabu Guanyu Luoshi Gongyeyongdi Zhaobiao Paimai Guapai
Churang Zhidu Youguan Wenti De Tongzhi‖[― Notice of the Ministry of Land and Resources
and Ministry of Supervision on the Implementation of the Assigned System of Commercial
Lands by Means of Public Bidding, Auction or Hanging out in a Shingle‖], available at
http://www.law-lib.com/law/law_view.asp?id=198388.
6
association between new land policy and corruption. Secondly, there is no
consensus among existing literature on the outcomes of the new policy. Tao,
Zhang and Li‘s (2010) empirical study reported that the tender and auction
modes may reduce corruption in land sector, while negotiation and quotation
modes may lead to opposite effects. Similarly, Cai, Henderson and Zhang
(2009) found that the auction mode has been successful in reducing corruption,
whereas quotation (or two-stage auction) fosters corruption. However,
according to Liang (2009), the adoption of market-led urban land supply
policy (tender, auction and quotation) in 2002 was found to be positively
associated with corruption in the years that followed. Deng, Zhang and
Leverentz (2010) reported an escalation of land corruption between the late
1990s and 2008, which seemed to imply that the new policy had failed to curb
corruption. Given the unresolved debate in the existing small body of
literature, there is a perceived need to empirically investigate the relationship
between recent land reforms and corruption in China.
This research attempts to analyze the impact of the market-led urban
land supply mechanism: specifically, the impact of the tender, auction and
quotation modes on the occurrence and severity of land corruption in China.
The primary objectives are to examine how corruption operates in urban land
sector and how it is shaped by market-led land supply modes. Hence, I
propose following research questions in this thesis.
I.
Has the introduction of market-led land leasing modes reduced
7
corruption as academics and practitioners claimed?
II.
If not, what are the factors that account for its failure?
To answer these questions, I empirically tested the relationship
between market-led land supply modes and land-law violations. Two
hypotheses that capture the features of urban land supply system in
contemporary China—rapid transition toward market-led land supply system
in the 2000s and growing financial dependence on land resources—were
derived from the literature review. Deepening adoption of the market
mechanism in land supply is expected to help reduce corruption. Conversely,
capitalization on land provides financial motives for local governments to
engage in illegal land use. Descriptive and regression analyses were
performed on a set of panel data to test these hypotheses. As it turned out, the
market-led land supply system failed to curb land corruption. Drawing on an
institutional approach, I explore reasons why the market mechanism has failed
to deter corruption through examining the legal and institutional loopholes in
the current system.
Research Design
This research used both quantitative and qualitative approaches:
quantitative methods, to test the two hypotheses in the first research question,
and qualitative method to explain the causal pathways through which
8
corruption is fostered or curbed by market-led urban land supply system to
address the second research question. Figure 1 illustrates how this research
was carried out.
Figure 1. Research Framework
Firstly, quantitative research is carried out to estimate the relationship
between market-oriented land reforms and corruption on the basis of spatial
characteristics and time effects. Two explanatory variables capturing the
major attributes of current urban land market are used to operationalize land
reform practice: transition toward market-led urban land supply system,
particularly the adoption of a new land supply policy in 2002, and financial
dependence on land-related revenues. Additionally, I control for various
factors that may affect corruption as encompassed by the panel model, such as
law enforcement, civil servants‘ wage, government size, and so forth. A set of
panel data collected from 31 provinces between 1998 and 2008 is analyzed
using panel data analysis model. The focus of this thesis is on the 1998-2008
period because 1998 is the start of an epoch-making point for China‘s land
9
administration regime. In 1998, a comprehensive revision to the Land
Administration Law was launched; more importantly, the Ministry of Land
and Resources was created in March 1998, marking the beginning of a
nationwide land reform. I chose provinces (rather than municipalities or
counties) as the unit of analysis, for two reasons: (1) in China‘s administrative
hierarchy, provincial-level administrative units are the most important
sub-national level authorities. Central regulations and policies are often
redefined or modified at provincial level so that policies remain consistent
within the jurisdiction of a provincial unit, and any revision to the original
regulations by municipal or county governments has to be approved by
provincial governments. (2) Statistics are usually compiled and published by
provincial governments, and these were the only available data to
systematically study land issues in China. Municipalities and counties rarely
published their data in a comprehensive and longitudinal manner.
The quantitative analysis relies on official statistics compiled by
various government bodies. Major sources of data include China Land and
Resources Almanac, China Statistical Yearbook, China Financial Yearbook
and provincial yearbooks, whose features are summarized in Table 7.
Admittedly, corruption is inherently difficult to measure. Land issues strike at
the legitimacy of the ruling party hence land corruption data is usually
considered confidential and not accessible to the public. However, we can find
alternative measures to indirectly capture the level of land corruption. This
10
paper selects land-law violations defined by the Land Administration Law as
proxies of land abuses and corruption. It should be acknowledged that official
land corruption statistics—land-law violations—have limitations in their
quality and reliability. First, the number of land-law violations has seen
remarkable fluctuations between 1998 and 2008, which is perhaps caused by
shifts in the intensity of land-law enforcement from time to time. These
fluctuations may affect the validity of regression results. To address this
problem, I integrate the variable of law enforcement in the regression analysis
to ensure the fluctuations in official land corruption statistics are under control.
By controlling the variations of law enforcement, we can also control the gap
between actual land corruption level and revealed land corruption level as
many scholars argue that official statistics only reflect the intensity of
enforcement rather than the actual level of corruption. Consequently, official
land corruption statistics can provide a proper indicator of trends in the actual
land corruption level.
The second limitation of the quantitative data is that these land-law
violations do not equal to land corruption because some violations are
committed by urban residents or peasants, which have no connection with
corruption. Despite these limitations, land-law violations are entangled with
bribery, abuse of power, and fraudulence hence are able to reveal illegal and
corrupt government behaviors in land management. Based on above reasons,
official land-law violation statistics can be employed as a reasonable proxy of
11
corruption in the land sector.
At the second stage, I use a qualitative method to interpret the
regression results and to explain the causal mechanisms through which
market-led land supply policy affects corruption. If the coefficients of two
explanatory variables showed expected signs, then hypotheses in this study are
confirmed—i.e., marketized urban land supply system indeed helps to reduce
corruption. However, if the explanatory variables showed opposite signs, I
would then use the qualitative approach to explain the failure of market-led
land supply policy in curbing corruption. To obtain the qualitative data, I
conducted fieldwork in Beijing, Hebei and Shanghai between November 13,
2010 and December 18, 2010. In-depth interviews with public officials,
businessmen, college professors and local residents were carried out. The
selection of participants was based upon the assessment of participants‘
potential to provide valuable information on land corruption and
anti-corruption policies. First, public officials‘ knowledge and experience
drawn from government positions are useful for understanding the
implementation of land policies and anticorruption polices. The selected
public officials consists of two groups: one group come from land
administration organizations representing experienced influential decision
makers who demonstrate the practices of land management, the other group
was from procurators, policemen, and officials of petition office who possess
experience of handling corruption cases. Second, college professors and
12
journalists specializing in public administration and urban issues may offer
unique insight into the outcomes of new land policies and anticorruption
policies. Real estate developers can tell stories of how they compete for land
use rights in tender, auction and quotation. More importantly, they are able to
provide information on the state-business relations which demonstrate a
hotbed for corruption. Finally, local residents and peasants as main
stakeholders are directly involved in land use activities such as toll breakdown
and land expropriation, they can provide in-depth knowledge about
government behaviors in land use. Their perceptions on local governments are
extremely important for understanding the scope and definition of land
corruption. Based on the above considerations, I contacted my acquaintances
in China to find qualified participants and used a snowballing technique to
establish a valid sample frame. Existing participants who willingly agreed to
engage in the research made recommendations of other qualified participants.
Finally, 26 male and female respondents aged above 24 were chosen and
interviewed: eighteen bureaucrats, two scholars, two real estate developers,
two villagers and one journalist. The bureaucrats held positions ranging from
department chief to ordinary staff member in land administration offices,
inspection and judicial system, and other government bodies that could be
vulnerable to corruption. The interviews were conducted face-to-face or via
the internet, using self-administered list of questions. As requested by the
interviewees, and to ensure anonymity, no names or workplaces are mentioned
13
in the thesis. The questions proposed during interviews can be categorized
according to the following:
1) The perceived level of corruption and illegality in urban land market.
2) The policy-making and implementation in land administration.
3) The governance and transparency in the assignment of LURs.
4) Government-business relationship in land market.
5) The supervision and penalty of officials involved in land corruption cases.
6) The interaction between land administration officers and citizens.
It should be noted that there were difficulties encountered in obtaining
reliable and systematical data through interviews. Interviewees tended to
withhold information and refused to reveal any abusive and corrupt activities
existing in their workplaces. As such, the contents of the interview may not
accurately reflect land corruption with a high degree of certainty. Moreover,
the informants‘ personal perspectives and their relationship with the
researcher may lead to biased statements that could negatively influence the
empirical analysis. In an attempt to overcome such difficulties, many
participant observations and informal conversations were carried out. I also
conducted documentary research by reviewing existing archives, reports,
documentaries, newspapers and websites to collect valuable information
related to land corruption.
14
Significance of This Study
This thesis finds that the newly established market-led urban land
supply regime fails to resolve problems of land abuses and corruption, which
have grown continuously over recent decades. While the central government
and several scholars have articulated the virtues of the tender, auction and
quotation modes in reducing corruption (Cai, Henderson &Zhang, 2009; Tao,
Zhang &Li, 2010), this paper demonstrates the inability of market-led land
supply modes to curb corruption. It shows that institutional loopholes in the
urban land supply regime and a lack of parallel supervision mechanism have
made corruption in land sector uncontrolled. Meanwhile, the central policies
are often manipulated by local states because of the conflicting interests of
state agencies at various levels, resulting in failure in policy implementation.
Based on the above findings, this research is expected to contribute to
the literature of corruption and land leasing in China in the following aspects:
Firstly, this study contributes to current corruption literature by
empirically studying land corruption issue in the Chinese context. Although it
has been agreed that current land reforms are at the root of many social
conflicts, empirical studies on land management problems are few in number.
In particular, corruption in land development is under-explored. This research
reveals the various forms of corrupt practices in urban land supply, such as
extracting bribes, stealing land-related revenues and violating land protection
rules and so forth, adding to the body of knowledge on how corruption
15
actually operates in urban land management.
Secondly, this research project presents empirical evidence for the
effects of market-led land supply regime on corruption in land management. It
makes use of both quantitative and qualitative research methods in a
multidisciplinary framework. Panel data analysis is complemented by
qualitative data obtained from intensive interviews with local officials,
business people, journalists and experts. The combination of two types of
methodology enables us to overcome the deficiencies of relying on a single
method, so that more valid and convincing conclusion can be drawn.
Moreover, this thesis employs a multidisciplinary approach incorporating
public administration, economics, sociology and geography to study how
corruption is shaped by China‘s land reforms.
Finally, the findings of this research have important implications in the
policy arena. This research intends to show the problems in current urban land
management system and provides recommendations for improving land use
efficiency and protecting land resources. Additionally, this research goes
beyond the land sector and situates the issue of land corruption within the
broader context of the central-local relationship and the national legal
environment and, hence, sheds light on the bigger picture of institutional
reforms in contemporary China. Furthermore, it would provoke future studies
in the area of land policy especially in rethinking and redesigning the tender,
auction and quotation system.
16
Organization of This study
The structure of this thesis is as follows:
Chapter 2 presents the basis for understanding the manifestations and
causes of corruption in China‘s land sector. An operational definition of land
corruption is provided, followed by a narrative report describing the forms and
characteristics of land corruption based on 20 corruption scandals. Existing
literature on land corruption in global and domestic contexts is then reviewed.
The focal point of literature review is on the controversial relationship
between market-led land supply system and corruption.
Chapter 3 identifies the research questions by tracing the
transformation of China‘s urban land supply regime. After analyzing the
major characteristics of current land reforms, two hypotheses are derived to
predict the relationship between land corruption and market-led land supply
system.
Chapter 4 utilizes descriptive analysis and regression analysis to test
the two hypotheses. Coefficients of independent variables are estimated by
panel data analysis and the results are interpreted accordingly.
Chapter 5 explains why the market-led land supply system has
unexpectedly failed to curb land corruption. Institutional and legal loopholes
that produce risks of corruption in urban land supply process will be
examined.
17
Chapter 6 summarizes the contributions and limitations of this
research
and
offers
suggestions
for
future
study.
Finally,
policy
recommendations are made to enhance accountability and integrity in urban
land management system.
18
Chapter 2
Literature Review
This chapter reviews recent literature on abuse of public authority
springing from China‘s land reforms in recent decades. The objectives of this
chapter are to organize the knowledge about land corruption in China and to
discuss the contributions as well as shortcomings of existing literature. Firstly,
an operational definition of land corruption will be presented based on the
literature review to identify the boundary of this research. Then, the patterns
and characteristics of land corruption in China are described using 20 sample
corruption cases. Finally, major studies of land corruption in global and
domestic contexts are outlined and discussed.
Working Definition of Land Corruption
Corruption is commonly defined as the exploitation of public power for
private gains (Guo, 2008; Rose-Ackerman, 1978; Shleifer & Vishny, 1993). In
the
Chinese
context,
forms
of
corruption
include
graft,
bribery,
misappropriation, collective illegal possession of public funds, unstated
sources of large properties, abuse of power, dereliction of duty, and fraudulent
practice. In addition, many misconducts that do not constitute corruption
crime but that violate morality or communism ideology are also considered as
19
corruption, such as excessive banqueting and entertainment, womanizing,
seeking privileged jobs for relatives, and purchasing excessive facilities (Liu,
1983). Given the unique political culture in China, the concept of corruption
shall be broadened in its scope and deepened in depth. Any government
behaviors that violate laws, prevailing norms or codes of conduct should be
regarded as corruption.
Land corruption shares some common features with corruption in
other economic sectors; yet, it demonstrates distinct features because land is
the fundamental factor in economic production. This thesis proposes an
operational definition of land corruption to clarify the boundary of this
research. Land corruption is defined in this thesis as the abuse of public power
over land resources for private gains or organizational interests, or which
violates regulations, principles or prevailing norms of land use. The forms of
corruption related to land encompass all types of illegal land use behaviors by
local government officials. In this thesis, the terms ―corrupt‖ and ―illegal‖
land use behaviors are used interchangeably as both types of behaviors pursue
private gains at the expense of public interests. Furthermore, both are handled
by the Central Commission of Disciplinary Inspection (CCDI) and Ministry of
Supervision, two major anti-corruption agencies in China. Major types of
illegal land use behaviors, such as the illegal purchase, sale and transfer of
LURs, unlawful approval of land occupancy, and granting of land at a lower
price, directly or indirectly involve abusive and unlawful behaviors of local
20
bureaucrats. Finally, two types of illegal land use activities—illegal approval
of land requisition and illegal transfer of land use rights at lower prices—are
classified as malfeasance by the criminal law.8 Given the close links between
corruption and illegality in land development, the two terms shall be read as
referring to the same issue.
The next question then arises: how is corruption manifested in the
urban land sector? The presence and characteristics of corruption vary
significantly from sector to sector; thus, it is necessary to thoroughly
investigate the manifestations of corruption in land management. However,
given the sensitive and secretive nature of land corruption, it is extremely
difficult to accurately describe how corruption operates. Notwithstanding, I
collected information on 20 land corruption scandals from newspapers articles,
anticorruption report and online medias from early 1990s to 2010; these are
presented in Appendix A. While these land corruption cases represent only the
tip of the iceberg, they shed light on the forms and characteristics of corruption
in the urban land sector; hence, a basic understanding of land corruption can be
drawn from these cases.
As shown in Appendix A, the magnitude and severity of land-related
corruption seem substantial. Many land corruption cases involve high-ranking
officials (yao an) and large sums of money (da an). It is commonplace to find
8
See ―Zuigaorenminjianchayuan Guanyu Duzhiqinquan Fanzuianjian Lianbiaozhun De
Guiding‖ [―Standards of Malfeasance Crime Registration set by the Supreme People‘s
Procuratorate‖], enacted on December 29, 2005.
21
instances of provincial governors or Party secretaries accused of corruption in
the land and property market. Of the 20 sample cases, 14 involve provincial or
ministerial level officials; 10 officials were sentenced to death, demonstrating
the severity with which land corruption is punished. Deng, Zhang and
Leverentz (2009) found a positive relationship between the ranks of corrupt
officials and the amount of land involved: the higher the official‘s rank, the
larger the amount of land that was being illegally used. The average land area
involved was 3.31 hectares for provincial officials and 1.25 hectares for city
officials. The bribe size is also substantial: at least hundreds of thousands of
RMB (several hundred thousand in US and Singapore dollars) are paid to local
officials as bribes, as reflected by the Jing Fusheng and Liu Zhihua‘s cases.
Secondly, corruption cases in land leasing suggest a massive scale that
lead many scholars to label such acts ―organizational corruption‖ (Lin, 2009;
Lu, 2000) or ―collective corruption‖(Gong, 2002). Urban land leasing regime
is built on a division of labor, with each land leasing deal requiring permits
and approvals from various government departments. Horizontally, corrupt
land leasing deals require collaboration among multiple government bodies,
including party and executive leaders, land and housing officials, urban
planning officials, and even banking and judicial officials. Vertically, land
related corruption is usually initiated or protected by the chief leaders or the
―first-in-command‖ (yibashou). If the ―first-in-command‖ is involved in
22
corrupt deals, the subordinates have to follow suit,9 as exemplified by Mu
Suixin and Ma Xiangdong‘s gang corruption cases. One local land
administration official stated the group behaviors as such:
There is no real estate developer who does not have guanxi with
chief party and government leaders in our area. Normally corrupt
land deals have been ‗approved‘ by the leaders; we are just
following that command. We land administration officials do not
possess such discretion to initiate corrupt land deals.10
Thirdly, forms of corruption such as bribery, nepotism and favoritism
are frequently observed in land corruption cases. Among the 20 sample cases,
at least 15 officials were accused of accepting bribes, while other forms of
corruption such as embezzlement and misappropriation appeared to be
regarded as less serious than bribery. This finding is consistent with
Wederman‘s study (2004). Continuous budgetary reforms may have prevented
the occurrence of direct theft of public assets such as embezzlement and
misappropriation, while public-to-private corruption prevails in the reform era,
along with a thriving real estate industry. Real estate companies that want to
maximize profits tend to bribe local officials to obtain land at the lowest
possible costs.
The preceding section presented the operational definition and major
9
This behavior is described by the report ―Ten Characteristics of Chinese Corruption‖, China
Report 2004, 40, p.107.
10
Interview with local land administration officials on November 18, 2010.
23
forms of corruption in China‘s urban land sector. The next section reviews
current literature to understand why land corruption prevails in both global
and national contexts.
Studies of Land Corruption in a Global Context
Corruption is a phenomenon that exists in many economic sectors, but
it is only in recent years that land-related corruption has attracted close
attention at the international level. Land administration is now perceived to be
one of the most corrupt sectors in many countries. Transparency International
(2009) finds that after the police and the court, land services are the most
prone to corruption, ―in the Middle East and North Africa, the most
bribe-prone institutions are reported to be those handling procedures related to
buying, selling, inheriting or renting land. In EU countries these land services
along with healthcare are most vulnerable to petty bribery‖ (p.3). However,
detailed documentation of corrupt activities in the land sector is a relatively
recent phenomenon. For many years, corruption studies have focused on
decentralization, liberalization and privatization of state-owned enterprises
(SOEs) while land-related corruption has been given scant academic attention.
Nevertheless, corruption in the land sector has emerged an important research
subject in urban economics and corruption studies.
Recent newspaper articles and scholarly works suggest that developing
countries and transitional economies are plagued by corrupt land management
24
that impedes sustainable development (Knox, 2009; Strong, 2003). In a study
on urban land privatization in Ukraine, Strong (2003) reported that in Kyiv a
builder must pay bribes at various stages of land and construction permitting.
In addition, prospective investors had no access to information related to land,
which then discouraged investment. Improper land leasing modes also
produced risks of corruption, ―a preference for negotiated sales of land rather
than auctions sometimes reflects favoritism and bribes in the privatization
process‖ (p. 200).
Another post-socialist country, Vietnam, has also been plagued by
serious corruption in the land sector. The World Bank‘s (2011) report,
Recognizing and Reducing Corruption Risks in Land Management in Vietnam,
argued that ―corruption is most likely to occur when an official or office has a
monopoly, when the official or office has a great deal of discretion over how
the decision is taken, and when there is little accountability for that decision or
transparency, which might make it harder for the corruption to proceed
unabated‖ (p. xiv). The risks factors for corruption embedded in Vietnam‘s
land management system include poor dissemination of land-related
information, unnecessarily complex and time consuming procedures, improper
and non-transparent settlement of complaints, ineffective oversights of media,
and so forth. Information dissemination and transparency in land management
was also emphasized in another World Bank report on Vietnam, titled Survey
Report on Information Disclosure of Land Management Regulations (Nguyen,
25
Nguyen, Tran, Prickett, Phan, 2010). Focusing on the disclosure of land
related information in Vietnam, this study insisted that land related
information was not readily available and accessible in Vietnam, ―in many
cases local officials cannot locate the information,‖ and ―individual citizens do
not seem to be aware of their right to access to information in general and land
related information in particular.‖ (p. 49) Therefore, the report suggested that
accessibility to land information had to be improved to reduce opportunities
for corruption. As post-socialist countries in the developing world, China and
Vietnam share considerable similarities in land administration, including
public ownership, separation between ownership rights and utilization rights,
and the introduction of public land leasehold and, hence, the World Bank
reports on land corruption in Vietnam would shed light on the same issue in
China.
In addition to the World Bank, the U4 Anti-corruption Resources
Center, a research agency operated by Chr. Michelsen Institute and
Transparency International jointly, also dedicates efforts to examine
corruption related to land management. One of the queries initiated by this
research center focused on corruption in land administration in Kosovo. The
publication Corruption in land administration / land management in Kosovo
(Nawaz, 2008) proposed multiple reasons for rampant land corruption in
Kosovo, such as the manipulation of documents, ineffective inspection system,
improper enforcement of laws and regulations, uncoordinated and confusing
26
land use process, weak role of civil society, and so forth. The author suggested
reform programs aimed at improving institutional qualities to resolve land
corruption problem in Kosovo.
Another Transparency International (2010) research project involved a
national corruption perception survey in Pakistan, a country that is also
plagued by corruption. The survey results suggested that land administration
was perceived to be the third most corrupt sector in Pakistan in 2010. At least
8 in 10 (82.04%) of 5,200 respondents reported that they encountered
corruption in their interactions with land administration officials. The report
cited the lack of accountability in the land administration system as the most
important
cause
of
corruption,
followed
by
discretional
power,
non-transparency, low salaries, land supply shortages, red tape-ism, and so
forth.
These studies have made significant contributions to the body of
knowledge on corruption in land sector; in particular, they provide theoretical
and empirical insights into studies on land corruption in developing and
transition economies. One important implication is that land corruption occurs
due to both sectoral and environmental factors. Sectoral factors such as
monopoly of land resources, discretion of land administration officials,
qualities of land administration institutions, government accountability and
transparency exert direct influence on the incidence of corruption. Systematic
factors, such as weak civil society, poorly-designed legal framework, and a
27
lack of the rule of law, can also exacerbate land corruption. The implication is
that land corruption cannot be addressed by merely focusing on land
administration itself; instead, comprehensive institutional reforms have to be
carried out to build a clean social and political environment.
Studies of Land Corruption in China’s Domestic Context
As a post-socialist country with developmental objectives, China is
unexceptionally suffering from rampant corruption in land management. A
combination of factors—loss of arable land and food insecurity—in recent
decades has raised public awareness on land protection in China. Scholars
have devoted their efforts to exploring why corruption prevails in China‘s land
sector. These particular perspectives can be divided into the following: (1)
central-local contentions and the fierce interregional competition triggered by
decentralization reforms may have encouraged rampant land lawbreaking; (2)
ambiguous land property rights in China is believed to cause chaotic land
management which facilitates corruption; and (3) state control in the
ownership and allocation of land resources is the root of land corruption.
These perspectives will be thoroughly investigated in the following literature
review.
Contentious Intergovernmental Relations
Intergovernmental relations, including both vertical and horizontal
28
aspects, have been largely redefined in the era of fiscal and administrative
decentralization. Decentralization is regarded as a strategy to promote
economic growth in local areas; however, it has created conflicts between
central and local governments and stimulated contentions among local
governments themselves, which can lead to abusive and illegal use of land
resources. The causal pathways are described as follows: firstly, fiscal reforms
in contemporary China have resulted in a recentralization of fiscal revenues
toward the central government and created a fiscal shortage for local
governments (Ko & Zhi, 2011). The lack of sufficient financial resources
makes local authorities trapped in a dilemma of delivering public goods with
insufficient fiscal revenues. To bridge the gap between revenues and
expenditures, local governments look for multiple sources to boost their
revenue stream; the soaring prices of land and real estate properties have, in
this regard, become an important source of capital. Land expropriation and
selling are strategies undertaken by local officials to increase their financial
power, and these have created to problems in the land sector. Guo (2008)
claimed that massive acquisition and selling of land resources have triggered
rent-seeking, corruption, and have caused harm to peasants‘ welfare. Lin
(2009) also pointed out that overexploitation of land has led to irrational land
grabbing and widespread illegal land sales in the black market.
The association between fiscal decentralization and illegal land use is
also supported by empirical evidence. Liang (2009) conducted a regression
29
analysis using a set of panel data between 1999 and 2005 to explore the
relationship between fiscal decentralization and land corruption. After
controlling for per capita GDP, provincial population, land revenues and some
features of land administration sector, the author found that fiscal
decentralization had significantly augmented land law violations by local
governments. Scholars also believe that a decentralized land management
system can contribute to abusive and corrupt land use activities in local areas.
In the era of administrative decentralization, local governments have been
given broad discretion in land requisition, conversion, and allocation, such
that central government is now facing difficulty controlling these local-based,
individual fiefdoms. Meanwhile, local governments continue to focus on local
development, effecting policy measures and preferences with their self-interests
at heart (Zhu, 1999). Broad discretion in land development has allowed local
authorities to act against the central policies for local interests, making the
principal-agent problem difficult to control. Gong (2006) drew on the
principal–agent approach to explain land corruption in China‘s local areas.
Gong asserted that China‘s local states have acquired both monopolistic power
and responsibilities in decentralization process. Land corruption occurs as
localities—the agents—betray the interests of central government—the
principal—in pursuit of their own interests. She explained the causal
mechanism as follows:
30
What has taken place in China‘s decentralization process is an
increase in all three; that is, while the degree of discretion of local
officials has increased to the extent of forming monopolized powers,
accountability and transparency of exercising these powers are not
established. Such a structure of governance provides enough room
for local officials to render favorable treatment to special interests in
exchange for personal gain. This is most evident in land-related
corruption activities in recent years. (p. 89)
Elaborating further on the principal-agent problem, Cao, Feng and Tao
(2008) pointed out that local governments which have strong incentives to
compete for manufacturing investment will always find ways to evade central
policies and that it would be difficult for the center to exert effective
supervision over such practices.
Zhang, Xu and Wang (2011) conducted an empirical study to examine
the effects of central-local contentions on corruption. Using panel data of land
law violations between 1999 and 2007, the authors found that when provincial
governors were selected from the corresponding province, a situation they
termed ―local coalition,‖ the severity of land law violations measured by the
amount of illegally-used land areas would likely increase by over 30%. This
empirical study confirmed that land-law violations occur because local
officials may act against central policies to protect local interests.
In addition to central-local conflicts, interregional contentions have
also been blamed for encouraging abusive and corrupt land-use behaviors
31
among local officials. Liang (2009) explained that China‘s political system
remains highly centralized by controlling the appointment and promotion of
local cadres. Under the current cadre promotion system, economic growth is a
major criterion in evaluating cadre performance and the motivation of
improving economic achievements has stimulated fierce interregional
competition. Land holds special status in economic production, as a major
market resource to be consolidated and mobilized so as to stimulate economic
growth, which provides further incentives and opportunities for cadres to
misuse land resources. Wu, Xu and Yeh (2007) described the behavior of local
cadres thus:
This (assessment of officials based on economic performance and
achievement in office) stimulates the officials to develop concrete
projects to demonstrate their record. The physical form of the built
environment-such
as
city
squares,
elevated
roads,
metro-mass-transit, and development zones-by its nature allows
easier visualization of the achievement than ‗intangible‘ social
development and public opinion. (p. 14)
Such political motives of local officials often lead to irrational and
shortsighted
activities
including
excessive
land
grabbing
and
an
overinvestment in infrastructure regardless of urban planning and land
protection regulations. Zhu (1999) claimed that vicious interregional
competition and local cadres‘ objective of short-term development has made
32
rent seeking prevalent in the land sector. Ho (2001) also noted that, ―the
ambition to achieve in their term of service causes cadres to approve the
construction of factories, office-towers and apartment buildings on
agricultural land, which opens up large opportunities for corruption‖ (p. 409).
A Lack of Protection on Property Rights
Another factor on land abuses springs from ambiguous land property
rights and its resultant lack of protection. Ambiguity in the definition of
property rights exists in both rural and urban land markets; this literature
review focuses on urban land areas with occasional reference to urban-rural
fringes.
According to China‘s Constitution, urban land is owned by the state,
while land in the suburban and rural areas is owned by the collectives.
However, it is not specific as to who represents the state (Ho, 2001). As Ho
pointed out, there is a legal twilight zone with regard to the concept of the
state as owner of urban land, which brings about confrontations between state
institutions. He acknowledged: ―the imprecise definition of state ownership is
the underlying cause of arable land loss as local governments illegally and
indiscriminately sell land for construction‖ (p.403). Because of ambiguity in
rural collective land ownership, state-collective confrontations can happen in
suburban areas during the tide of urban sprawl, a major manifestation of
which is that ―collective land and sometimes entire collectives have been sold
33
or appropriated without formal change of land ownership titles‖; worse yet,
collective ownership often becomes a hollow clause as ―the decision for land
sale is often taken in the cadres‘ private capacity‖ (Ho, 2001, p. 410), leading
to a severe problem of land loss.
Lin and Ho (2005) also believed that ambiguous property rights,
particularly in rural areas, is one possible explanation for the existence of
illegal conversion and transactions in the black market. The authors claimed
that rural collective ownership brings forth a confused definition. Both rural
collectives and peasants believe they have the right to dispose of the land. In
reality, peasants‘ rights and related benefits are very limited; often, it is the
collective, the villagers‘ committee, which decides on how land is to be used,
reaping the lion‘s share of profits in return.
The problem of ambiguous property rights was further discussed by
Zhang (2006). The author elaborated three types of ambiguities in current land
management laws: firstly, the definition of public interest is vague; secondly,
compensation to peasants deprived of land is not clearly specified; thirdly,
peasants‘ rights to rural land are not stipulated by law which, in effect, allows
the village committee to exercise the executive power. These legal ambiguities
weakened individual property rights to land and facilitated land grabbing, rent
seeking and corruption in localities (Zhang, 2006).
State Monopoly and Dual-Track System
34
Within the land management system, debates on the sources of and
solutions to land corruption have centered on role of state monopoly. Some
scholars employ a public choice perspective to explain how rent seeking and
corruption occur under public land ownership. Economists of the public
choice school assume that state monopoly in the operation of economy
encourages corruption (Tanzi, 1998). Given that China maintains strict state
monopoly in land ownership, rent seeking and corruption can be expected.
Chow (2006) criticized public ownership of land and bureaucratic power as an
important source of corruption, and suggested further reduction on
publicly-owned land and the government administrators‘ power to control
corruption. As the author put it:
by reducing the role of the state, including the sizes and number of
state-owned enterprises and banks, the amount of publicly owned
land (to be sold by auctions for example as in the case of Hong
Kong), the number of government bureaus having authority to
grant permit and licenses (some of which are necessary and
desirable) and the number of government development projects, we
can hope to reduce the amount of corruption substantially. (p.281)
Deng, Zhang and Leverentz (2010) also argued that ―officials at
various levels use every possible means to seek rent through monopoly in the
economic areas that had not been open for market competition‖ (p. 79), which
is exemplified in the urban land sector. The authors explained the relationship
35
between state monopoly and corruption in land requisition as follows:
Because only the state had the right to obtain land from farmers at
very low prices, officials frequently abused their power to approve
land acquisitions from suburban or rural areas and then let their
relatives or associates act as land brokers to transfer land to
developers. Frequently, developers identified good locations for
their projects and contacted officials or land brokers to persuade
government officials to get land from farmers at low costs. (p.79)
State monopoly gives rise to local officials‘ individual control of land
and property market, which provides opportunities for corruption. Gong (1997)
claimed that ―the authority over land (including planning, developing and
leasing, etc.) has provided government officials with means of money making.
Possessing the power to decide whether, how, to whom, and at what price to
lease the land, they could easily abuse power by requesting bribes from
interested individuals or institutions‖ (p. 280). Deng, Zhang and Leverentz
(2010) also believed that ―urban land reforms featured by reassignment of
property rights provides opportunity for corruption because officials have the
power to decide who control property, who have the right for land-related
income flows, and who have the right to assign ownership‖ (p. 77).
Closely related to state monopoly, the dual-track land allocation
mechanism and suppression of market forces are also believed to facilitate
corruption. Deng, Zhang and Leverentz (2010) further argued that ―the dual
36
price policy created huge price differentials that in turn provided an enormous
opportunity for corruption‖ (p. 74). This is particularly so with regard to urban
land sector, which still maintains the dual pricing mechanism.
Firstly, under dual-track allocation system, land can be allocated either
free of charge, or based on payment. The existence of free and discounted land
supply modes, namely administrative allocation and negotiation, gives rise to
bribery and corruption (Yeh & Wu, 1996; Zhu 2002; Lin & Ho, 2005; Yeh,
2005; Xu, Yeh & Wu, 2009). The land rents created by the price gap between
free allocation and paid acquisition encourage land buyers to be rent seekers.
Deng (2003b) pointed out that corruption was a direct problem brought about
by free administrative allocation, as real estate developers may bribe local
officials to obtain land through free administrative allocation rather than
expensive market modes. Negotiated sale of land, which involves partial state
control, was also believed to facilitate corruption (Yeh & Wu, 1996; Zhu, 2002;
Deng, 2003b; Lin & Ho, 2005; Yeh, 2005; Xu, Yeh & Wu, 2009). As investors
can buy land at a much lower price through private negotiations (Deng,
2003b), they may approach land deals through guanxi networks, bribery and
fraud (Wong & Zhao, 1999). This argument was supported by Tao, Zhang and
Li‘s (2010) empirical study, which reported a positive association between
negotiated land deals and illegal land use activities.
Secondly, a dual-track allocation mechanism nurtures a black market
where illegal purchase, sale and transference of state-owned land prevail.
37
Work-units illegally lease administratively allocated land to other users
through the black market, and peasants illegally transfer rural farmland to
investors (Yeh, 2005; Yeh & Wu, 1996; Zhang, 1997). Such behaviors may
lead to a capital loss of state assets and damage to invaluable farmland. On the
other hand, Zhu (1994, 1999a) rejected the notion that dual-track mechanism
hinders the land market and suggested instead that the dual land market could
become an implicit program to nurture local enterprises and developers, a
means of fostering local government-enterprise coalitions, and an instrument
to strengthen local government‘s position in local development.
Nevertheless, the Chinese central government strongly believes that
land corruption is the result of heavy state intervention and low level of
competition in urban land market. Led by a neo-liberal paradigm, the central
government initiated a series of land reforms to cope with land corruption by
building a full-fledged land market. A major reform practice is the
abandonment of free and negotiated land deals and strict adoption of tender,
auction and quotation methods in urban land leasehold. The state has
articulated the merits of tender, auction and quotation modes as a solution to
abusive and corrupt land use.11 For instance, an article by Zhang Yanhua,
deputy general director of the Department of Land and Resources in Zhejiang
Province, stated that the tender, auction and quotation modes can help
11
See ―Jianchi He Wanshan Tudi Zhaopaigua Guiding, Baochi Dijia Pingwenheli Tiaozheng‖
[―Insist and Improve the Land Rules of Tender, Auction, and Quotation, Ensure Land Prices
are Stable‖], http://house.people.com.cn/GB/14627461.html; see also ―Guoziwei: Tudi Jiaoyi
Zhaopaigua Zhi Shi Haozhidu, Ke Fangzhi Fubai‖ [―SASAC: Tender, Auction, and Quotation
are Good Rules to Prevent Corruption‖], http://finance.people.com.cn/GB/11188332.html.
38
improve the quality of land administration, maximize the value of land assets,
and prevent corruption by ensuring transparency and fairness (Zhang, 2002).
Chinese scholars such as Qiu (2006) also strongly support the new land supply
regime. However, the marketization of urban land supply as a solution to
corruption turns out to be debatable. Paradoxically, the new land supply policy
generates new opportunities for corruption, as suggested by recent studies.
Liang‘s (2009) empirical research found that the adoption of market-led urban
land supply policy (tender, auction and quotation) in 2002 was positively
associated with illegal land use in the years 2002, 2003 and 2004. Cai,
Henderson and Zhang‘s (2009) theoretical model and empirical evidence
revealed that the quotation mode, or ―two stage auction,‖ as termed by the
authors, leads to less competitive bidding and more corruption than one-stage
auction. This finding was further confirmed by Tao, Zhang and Li (2010),
whose empirical study reported a positive relationship between quotation
mode and land lawbreaking. Given such debates, the effects of market-led
land leasing modes on corruption remains largely unknown.
Implications of Literature Review
The literature review has several important implications. Firstly,
although corruption has been intensively analyzed by political scientists and
economists, corruption related to land development is inadequately discussed
by scholars; in this regard, only World Bank and Transparency International
39
have occasionally launched research projects on land corruption; hence, our
knowledge about land corruption in the global context is limited. In China‘s
domestic context, documentation of government behaviors in urban land use is
new to the academic world, and there are only a few theoretical and empirical
works available to disclose why corruption is rampant in China‘s land sector.
Besides, causal arguments are often derived from anecdotal evidence or
individual cases rather than systematic observations and analysis, hence, many
have gone untested. Probably because of methodological challenges, empirical
studies on Chinese land corruption are rather limited in current English
literature (Cai, Henderson & Zhang, 2009). Among Chinese literature, only a
handful of local Chinese scholars have studied the land corruption issue using
an empirical approach (Liang, 2009; Tao, Zhang & Li, 2010). Given such
limited scholarship on the land corruption issue, there is a strong need to
thoroughly investigate how and why corruption occurs in China‘s land sector.
A major controversy within the current land corruption literature
concerns the relationship between marketized urban land supply policy and
corruption. Advocates of the neo-liberal theory attribute land corruption to
state monopoly in land ownership and land leasehold. Led by neo-liberal
ideology, the Chinese central government has carried out market-oriented land
reforms to reduce state monopoly in urban land supply. However, scholarly
works have reported the failure of marketized land allocation mechanism in
preventing corruption (Liang, 2009). Considering such disagreement, this
40
paper intends to probe into the linkage between corruption and marketized
land supply regime on a basis of statistical analysis.
41
Chapter 3
Research Questions and Hypotheses
This section elaborates on the research questions and proposes two
hypotheses for quantitative analysis. The research questions are tabled after
clarifying historical events in China‘s urban land reforms. 12 The two
hypotheses capture the basic characteristics of China‘s urban land reforms and
are used for empirical testing and further discussion. The following section
provides a detailed statement of research questions and the two hypotheses.
Urban Land Reform in China
Urban land reforms became an important developmental issue in China
starting in the early 1990s. In addressing the issue of inefficient land resource
management, low agricultural production and rural poverty in developing
countries, the World Bank proposed and aggressively promoted many
market-oriented policies, suggesting that state-led land policies distort the land
market. According to Deininger and Binswanger (1999), restrictions on land
sales and rentals inhibit investment and cause informal transactions in the land
market. State-led land use model is at the root of inefficiency and
under-productivity in the agricultural sector, and this is particularly so in
12
In the Chinese context, land reforms in rural and urban areas demonstrate great distinctions,
for the purpose of this research, only urban land reforms will be introduced, rural land
management regime is beyond the scope of this paper.
42
socialist settings (Deininger, 1995). Led by the pro-market rationale, the World
Bank prescribed market-led land policies as the panacea to land inefficiency in
Latin American, African and post-Communist countries (Borras, 2003a; Lahiff,
2006; Pereira, 2007). Major reform practices include privatization and
individualization of land ownership or LURs, promotion of open land rental
and sale market, decentralization of land administration institutions, conversion
of land from rural to urban uses, and reduction of government control in land
resources, and so forth (World Bank, 1997).
Privatization and individualization of property rights are of central
concern to policy agenda in post-communist counties such as Central and
Eastern Europe, Vietnam, and China (Ho & Spoor, 2006). In the Chinese
context, land was publicly owned and allocated free of charge in the
pre-reform era. Following a socialist ideology, land possessed no commercial
value and could then be traded in the open market. Urban land allocation
mechanism was an integral part of traditional central planning system. Land
development decisions were made out of economic and political demand
rather than economic and efficiency concerns. The urban land users were state
authorities, state enterprises, and other public organizations, but there were no
private organizations in the urban areas to compete for land. Meanwhile, land
could be used for an infinite period of time. Followed a rigid hierarchical
approval system, urban construction projects initiated by central and local
states had to be approved by the Central Planning Committee. Once approved,
43
local authorities were required to allocate a piece of land to the corresponding
project free of charge.
The socialist land allocation system was then believed to be
incompatible with the country‘s overall market-oriented reforms; in particular,
because it hinders efficient land use and investment in urban housing and
services (Zhu, 1999). This stimulated the adoption of market-driven land
supply paradigm in the reform era. In the World Bank report, China: urban
land management in an emerging market economy (World Bank, 1993), the
researchers suggested that China create an open land market to promote real
estate investment and urbanization and that institutional and legal changes be
initiated to accommodate the emerging market economy. Following a
neo-liberal rationale, the state gradually abandoned the socialist administrative
land allocation system to pursue a market-driven land management paradigm.
The following table presents the evolution of China‘s urban land reforms and
regulatory regimes in each period.
44
Table 1. Evolution of Urban Land Supply Regime in China
Period
1950-1986
Reform Practice
Legislation
Regulatory Regime
Centralization of
Constitution of the People's
Urban land was allocated to
national
Republic of China (1954, 1975)
users for free and was banned
land
resources
;
creation
of
National
Land
to be transferred.
Administration
Bureau
1987-1989
Pilot reforms of
Land Administration Law;
LURs were separated from
commercializatio
Regulations for Valuation on
land ownership and allowed to
n
Urban Land
be transferred between users;
of
LURs;
assessment
of
urban land was granted based
land value
on payment and kept for a
limited period of time.
1990-2001
Nationwide
Interim Regulations Concerning
Urban land used for public
adoption of land
the Assignment and Transfer of
interest was allocated for free,
leasehold;
the Right to the Use of the
commercial
State-Owned Land in the Urban
land can be assigned via
administrative
Areas;Provisional Regulations
negotiation, tender or auction.
allocation
on Granting and Transferring
reduction
of
the
Right
to
the
Use
and
industrial
of
State-Owned Land in Cities and
Towns; The Law on Urban Real
Estate Administration
2002-2005
abolishment
of
Granting of Use Rights in
Urban land used for public
negotiation
for
State-Owned Land by Tender,
interest is allocated for free,
Auction and Quotation
industrial
commercial land
land
can
be
allocated via negotiation, but
tender
and
action
are
encouraged; commercial land
has to be assigned by tender,
auction or quotation
2006-now
abolishment
of
Circular of the State Council on
Urban land used for public
negotiation
for
Intensifying the Land Control;
interest is allocated for free,
Provisions on the Assignment of
both
State-owned Construction Land
commercial land has to be
Use
Bid
allocated via tender, auction or
and
quotation.
industrial land
Right
Invitation,
through
Auction
industrial
and
Quotation
Source: concluded by the author
45
In
the
late
1980s,
urban
land
reforms
starting
with
the
commercialization of LURs began. In November 1987, pilot reform on LURs
was initiated in Shenzhen, Shanghai, Tianjin, Guangzhou, Xiamen and Fuzhou.
The success of these encouraged institutional reforms in the following year,
when transference of LURs was legalized by constitutional amendments.
Article 2 of the amendments was explicitly clear: ―No organization or
individual may appropriate, buy, sell or otherwise engage in the transfer of land
by unlawful means. The right to the use of land may be transferred according to
law.‖ Such changes were further confirmed by The Land Administration Law of
the PRC, issued in December 1988 and amended in 2004. The law had defined
land ownership and right to the use of land as follows:
The People‘s Republic of China resorts to a socialist public
ownership, i.e., an ownership by the whole people and ownerships
by collectives, of land. In ownership by the whole people, the
State Council is empowered to be on behalf of the State to
administer the land owned by the State. No unit or individual is
allowed to occupy trade or illegally transfer land by other means.
Land use right may be transferred by law. The state may make
expropriation or requisition on land according to law for public
interests, but shall give compensations accordingly. (Chapter 1,
Article 2)
After the commercialization of LURs gained constitutional support,
several other legislations were enacted to create a regulatory regime of new
46
urban land supply.13 Under the new policies, LURs are granted either of two
ways: free allocation (wuchang huabo), or paid land leasehold (youchang
churang). Under the free allocation system, land used for public interest intent
can be allocated to the final users (state, party, military, non-profitable
organizations and SOEs) without any fee. In 2001, the Ministry of Land and
Resources published a Directory of Allocated Land (huabo tudi mulu), which
gave detailed explanation of the administrative allocation process. Potential
land users submit land use applications and qualifications to the local land
administration departments for an evaluation. Only public welfare-oriented
projects qualified for free allocation, such as the construction of office
buildings for public organizations, urban infrustructure, energy and transport
facilties, prison and public security projects, and so forth. Once approved, one
parcel of land would be supplied to the applicants with no fees charged and no
limitation on duration.
Free allocation is a legacy of the socialist land allocation system, but
differs from the previous system in that land use applications are now
approved by local authorities instead of a central Economic Planning
Committee. Deeply rooted in socialist ideaology, the free allocation mode is
incompatible with the emerging market economy and brings considerable
amounts of capital losses. To remedy the inefficiency and economic loss,
further legislations were issued in the early 1990s, including Interim
13
The laws and regulations on the transference of LURs include the Interim Regulations of
the PRC Concerning the Assignment and Transfer of the Right to the Use of the State-owned
Land in the Urban Areas; the Provisional Regulations of the PRC on Granting and
Transferring the Right to the Use of State-Owned land in Cities and Towns; and the
Provisional Administrative Methods for Developing and Operating Vast Tracts of Land with
Foreign Investment, all were issued in 1990.
47
Regulations of the PRC Concerning the Assignment and Transfer of the Right
to the Use of the State-owned Land in the Urban Areas and the Provisional
Regulations of the PRC on Granting and Transferring the Right to the Use of
State-Owned land in Cities and Towns, allowing urban state-owned land to be
supplied through paid leasing, gradually giving rise to a market-oriented urban
land supply system.
Under the paid land leasing system, land used for profit-making
purposes are leased for a sum of money, and the LURs are owned for a
specified number of years, e.g., up to 70 years for housing, 50 for industrial
use, and 40 for commercial purposes. Each land parcel in the urban areas is
professionally assessed and valued, and the price updated regularly. In the
process of land appraisal, a benchmark price (BMP) is set. This represents the
average price of land at a particular location within a specific time period.
Land prices vary according to heterogeneous properties of land. According to
Ding (2001), the components to be considered in BMP setting include: (1) the
amount of land use rights fee paid to the government; (2) infrastructure costs
paid to the government for land improvement; (3) demolition cost; and (4)
land acquisition cost. The BMP values are updated every five years to reflect
socioeconomic changes. This functions as a guide to price decisions made in
land leasing, and provides a tool by which to protect land assets, and to
facilitate land management and promote land development, even though it has
its problems as well.
48
Besides the establishment of land pricing mechanism, the paid leasing
system also introduced new land supply modes—negotiation, tender, auction
and quotation—to simulate urban land and property market. Negotiation is a
quasi-market or quasi-administrative allocation method that aims to achieve
land deals based on agreement between land supplier and buyer. There are
multiple circumstances under which there is room for negotiation, such as
when land is not used for profit-making purposes, or when the original land
user applies to continue possession of LURs.14
Similar to free allocation, the negotiation mode is applied to subsidize
the projects that intend to promote social welfare, local employment and to
facilitate economic reforms. Prior to 2006, many technological and
capital-intensive manufacturing enterprises were allowed to obtain land
through negotiation. The negotiation mode is used to address complex issues
generated by the privatization of SOEs—the major holders of urban land in
pre-reform era. As land buyers are often required to relocate laid-off workers
and repay SOEs‘ debts, this entails private negotiation between local
government and land buyers.
In negotiated land sales, land administration departments and land
buyers negotiate on price, location, size, usage, duration, planning
requirements, and so forth. Land price is the central concern of negotiators,
14
For detailed explanations regarding the applicability of negotiation mode, see ―Xieyi
Churang Guoyou Tudi Shiyongquan Guiding‖[―Provisions on the Agreement-based
Assignment of the Right to Use State-Owned Land‖], article 4.3.
49
according to Article 5 of the Provisions on the Agreement-based Assignment of
the Right to Use State-Owned Land; prices of land in negotiated sales shall
never below 70% of the benchmark price of the land. Based upon this
requirement, a floor price is decided collectively—in private, —by land
administration officers. Then land administration organs and the buyer then
negotiate on the price, which are never to go below the set floor price.15
There are several drawbacks to negotiated land sales: firstly, the
process is not open to the public but instead, a secretive deal is struck between
land administration organs and potential land buyers; secondly, as the land
prices are not decided by any form of price mechanism but by the bargaining
power and guanxi between both parties, the negotiated price is often much
lower than the market price. Developers‘ incentive to replace market
allocation modes with negotiation can be a source of rent seeking and bribery.
Aware of the dark side of negotiated sales, the center decided to abandon
quasi-market mode and promote market-led allocation modes (tender, auction
and quotation). In July 2002, Regulation Governing the Granting of Use
Rights in State-Owned Land by Tender, Auction and Quotation was officially
adopted, requiring all land used for business purposes (commerce, tourism,
entertainment and commodity housing) to be allocated through market
transaction modes (tender, auction and quotation), although industrial land can
still be supplied by negotiation. The official abolishment of negotiated land
15
See ibid.
50
deals for industrial companies occurred on August 31, 2006. As the State
Council issued Circular of the State Council on Intensifying the Land Control,
all land used for industrial purposes should be distributed via market modes
the same as commercially-used land. Abrogation of negotiation mode was
further institutionized by the Provisions on the Assignment of State-owned
Construction Land Use Right through Bid Invitation, Auction and Quotation
promulgated in 2007, since when industrial enterprises are no longer
subsidized by cheap land.
Of the three land supply modes, auction is the most straightforward as
the successful bidder is the one that bids the highest price. In a public tender,
invitations are sent to potential land buyers who then submit their tender
documents and materials to the corresponding governments. Instead of
selecting the highest bidder, the evaluation of tender bids considers multiple
factors such as the design and reputation of the bidders (Deng, 2003a).
Quotation is a process similar to auction, but allows more flexibilities in
decision-making. When the land use information is disclosed, bidders submit
their prices to land administration organs and are allowed to update their land
prices in the listed period of time. The winning bidder is the one who offers
the highest price (Xu, Yeh & Wu, 2009).
Similar to negotiated land sales, there is also a floor price for
market-driven land supply modes; in addition, the tender mode requires a
minimum tendering price, while auction and quotation requires an opening bid
51
price and a starting price respectively, all of which are collectively determined
by land administration officers after taking into consideration the benchmark
and floor prices. Usually, any individual or organization may compete for
LURs in tender, auction and quotation, unless otherwise stipulated by law and
regulations.16 Figure 2 shows the procedures of obtaining land use rights
through different channels.
Figure 2. Procedures of Urban Land Supply in China17
Research Questions and Hypotheses
According to the preceding section, China‘s urban land supply regime
has shifted from a state-led to a market-led paradigm. Based on this historical
16
See ―Zhaobiao Paimai Guapai Churang Guoyou Jianshe Yongdi Shiyongquan
Guiding‖[―Provisions on the Assignment of State-owned Construction Land Use Right
through Bid Invitation, Auction and Quotation‖], article 11.
17
See Ministry of Land and Resources, ―Zhaobiao Paimai Guapai Churang Guoyou Tudi
Shiyongquan Guifan(Shixing)‖[―Rules on the Assignment of State-owned Land Use Right by
Means of Bid Tendering, Auction and Hanging Out a Shingle (for Trial Implementation)‖],
promulgated May 31, 2006; and ―Xieyi Churang Guoyou Tudi Shiyongquan
Guifan(Shixing)‖[―Rules on the Agreement-based Assignment of State-owned Land Use
Right (For Trial Implementation)‖], promulgated May 31, 2006.
52
background, research questions and hypotheses are derived in this section.
Table 2 shows the differences between state-led and market-led paradigms of
urban land supply.
Table 2. Comparing Free Allocation, Negotiation, Tender, Auction and
Quotation
Features
Modes of Land Allocation
Free
Quasi-administrative/Quasi-market
Market allocation
administrative
allocation (negotiation)
(tender, auction,
State control
Land transfer
Qualified
allocation
High
Banned
State, party,
Medium
Allowed
Some non-profit organizations;
quotation)
Low
Allowed
Real estate
Land users
military,
private enterprises in high-tech and
developers;
non-profit
capital-intensive industries (before
individuals; private
organizations
and SOEs
2006); original land users (e.g.,
SOEs), etc.
enterprises
(including private
high-tech and
capital-intensive
enterprises after
2006)
Decision
Government
makers
leaders and land
administration
Land value
No price
(free of charge)
Transparency
Government leaders, land
Land administration
administration officials and one
organs and multiple
land buyer
land buyers
A BMP is decided by land
A BMP is decided by
evaluation agency; a floor price is
land evaluation
decided by land administration
agency; starting
organs, upon which a transaction
prices are decided by
price is negotiated between land
land administration
administration organs and land
organs; the highest
buyer
bidders win
Non-transparent
Non-transparent
Transparent
Source: constructed by the author
Table 2 (above) shows that market-led land allocations possess
advantages in instituting good governance and preventing corruption in land
53
administration. Firstly, administratively allocated land was not allowed to be
transferred for investment purposes, which was an obstacle for more efficient
land users to access to the land (Zhu, 1999). The restrictions on transferring of
LURs gave rise to pervasive ungovernable and illegal land transactions by
state units in the black market (Xu, Yeh & Wu, 2009), resulting in losses in
land assets and government revenues. Under the new system, LURs can be
legally transferred for reinvestment, and this reduces the incentives for illegal
land transference in the black market. Secondly, under the administrative and
negotiated allocation models, decisions are made in a rigid and secretive
fashion, which gives local officials opportunities to abuse their power for
self-enrichment. The new market-led allocation system lowers state control in
land market by increasing the number of bidders and the level of competition.
Land-related information is publicized prior to the beginning of the
competition process, making urban land supply more open and transparent.
Each potential buyer possesses equal opportunities to compete for the land in
bidding process, and to monitor government behaviors. As the land supply
process becomes more transparent, fair and user-friendly, it is likely that
corruption will be curbed.
Based on the above merits of various market allocation modes, the
central government hopes that the adoption of completely market-led
leasehold of land will reduce land-related corruption. To achieve this, I
propose to explore the following research questions: has the new land supply
54
policy succeeded in reducing corruption? If not, what are the reasons for its
failure? With an objective to answer research questions, I derived two
hypotheses for empirical testing and further discussion. The hypotheses have
captured the major characteristics of current land reforms; hence, they are able
to elaborate on the relationship between market-led land supply system and
land corruption comprehensively. The first hypothesis is defined as follows:
H1: Adoption of market-led land supply policy (tender, auction and
quotation) reduces corruption.
This hypothesis reveals the fundamental issue of market-oriented land
reforms in China—is the free market ―cleaner‖ than the state? As discussed in
the
preceding section,
mechanism—coexistence
China‘s
of
land
state-led
market
features
allocations
a
dual-track
(administrative
and
negotiated land deals) and market-led allocations (tender, auction and
quotation). There is a strong belief among Chinese leaders and scholars that
administrative
and
privately
negotiated
land
allocations
encourage
rent-seeking and corruption because of the pricing gap between state track and
market track (Deng, Zhang & Leverentz, 2010). Hence, tender, auction and
quotation modes were adopted as a solution to the rampant behind-door deals
in urban land supply. It is expected that corruption can be reduced through
restraining state control and enhancing market forces. However, many
scholarly works have challenged the effectiveness of market-led land supply
regime in curbing land corruption. According to Liang (2009), the new policy
55
has triggered a surge of land corruption in the years that followed. Tao, Zhang
and Li (2010) and Cai, Henderson and Zhang (2009) found that corruption
was likely to take place under the quotation mode. Due to the lack of
consensus among scholarly attempts, there is a strong need to rigorously test
the relationship between market land supply modes (tender, auction and
quotation) and corruption.
H2:
Financial
dependence
on
land-related
revenues
aggravates
corruption.
Capitalization on land is one of the objectives of market-oriented land
reforms in contemporary China. As shown in Table 2 (on page 43), the land
pricing mechanism on public land leasehold had the effect of strengthening
local governments‘ financial power. Along with soaring land prices, land
conveyance fees become an important source of revenue for local authorities.18
Xu, Yeh &Wu (2009) reported that land sales contributed 30% to 70% of
municipal revenue in many cities. One official working in a city-level
procuratorate said:
Chinese local governments are solely relying on selling land to
collect fiscal revenues. Compared to other sources of revenues,
capitalization on land is convenient, quick and highly profitable;
the governments acquire land from peasants with almost zero cost
18
According to Land Administration Law (2004), 30% of land conveyance fees shall be
submitted to central government, the remaining 70% is distributed in localities.
56
and sell it to rich developers by charging millions of yuan. In
addition to that, there is no tax burden on land revenues; hence the
money is entirely under control of local governments.19
Table 3. Financial Dependence on Public Land Leasing
Year
Budgetary
Revenues
(100 million
RMB)
Extra-budgetary
Revenues
(100 million
RMB)
Land leasing
fees
(100 million
RMB)
Land leasing
fees
/Total revenues
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Total
4983.95
5594.87
6406.06
7803.30
8515.00
9850.00
11893.40
15100.80
18303.60
23572.60
28644.90
140668.5
2918.14
2912.99
3154.72
3578.75
3952.99
4039.38
4187.46
4348.49
5141.57
5318.83
5752.75
45306.07
249.93
514.33
595.58
1295.89
2416.79
5421.31
6412.18
5883.82
8077.64
12216.72
10259.80
53343.99
3.2%
6.0%
6.2%
11.4%
19.4%
39.0%
39.9%
30.3%
34.5%
42.3%
29.8%
28.7%
Source: China Finance Yearbook, 1999-2009; China Land and Resources
Almanac, 1999-2009
Above table illustrates the degree of financial dependence on urban
land leasing. It shows that land conveyance fees have contributed significantly
to local government financial power. On the one hand, this allows local states
to carry out more developmental projects and provide more public goods (Zhu,
1999). On the other hand, local governments become overly dependent on the
revenues generated by land sales, which is an unwanted consequence of
current market-oriented land reforms. Overdependence on land revenues could
19
Interview with one local official on November 18, 2010.
57
hinder the efficiency of land management and gives rise to corruption.
Scholars point out that strong economic incentives make it difficult for the
state to control and monitor the sales of LURs (Ding, 2002). Capitalization on
land and overdependence on land revenues has motivated local governments
to engage in irrational land grabbing and widespread illegal land sales in the
black market to gain substantial revenues (Lin, 2009). This demonstrates the
paradoxical nature of current land reforms, and leads to the second hypothesis.
Summary
As an integral part of economic reform, China‘s land sector has
witnessed its transition from state-led socialist system to market-led,
neo-liberal paradigm. However, corruption in land sector started to become
more prevalent from the early 1990s when the reassignment of property rights
began (Gong, 1997;Ding, 2002; Deng, Zhang& Leverentz, 2010). Land policy
reforms have produced both wanted and unwanted consequences. One of the
problems arising from the land reforms is widespread black market, bribery
and corruption (Ding, 2002). The central government has initiated a deepening
adoption of market mechanism in urban land supply to address land corruption.
However, whether the marketized land supply system is a successful solution
to corruption remains controversial in scholarship; hence, it is necessary to
empirically study the effects of current land reforms on corruption. This
chapter started by tracing the history of land reforms in China, and then
58
identified the research questions and hypotheses of this paper. In the next
chapter, the hypotheses will be tested using descriptive and regression
analyses.
59
Chapter 4
Empirical Study of Land Corruption in China
This chapter aims to empirically test the relationship between
market-led land supply modes (tender, auction and quotation) and land
corruption. Firstly, descriptive analysis is performed to trance the historical
pattern of land corruption in China. This allows us to see whether land
corruption is influenced by the new land supply policy. In the second step,
regression analysis is performed to gain more robust conclusions on the
association between market-led land supply modes and corruption. A set of
panel data covering 31 provinces between 1998 and 2008 is then analyzed
using two-way random-effects panel model. Based on the regression results,
the hypothesized impact of tender, auction and quotation modes on land
corruption can be identified.
Data
The data on land corruption is inherently difficult to obtain due to its
sensitive nature in the Chinese context. As numerous conflicts, protests and
riots have been attributed to land disputes and as many local officials enrich
themselves through illegal land-use activities, land corruption data is usually
considered confidential, and thus not accessible to the public. Although the
60
data that directly reflects land corruption is not available in a systematic and
longitudinal manner, we can find measures indirectly capturing the level of
corruption related to land. This paper selects five types of land-law violations
defined by the Land Administration Law as proxies of land abuses and
corruption. They include: (1) illegal purchase, sale and transfer of land use
rights; (2) damage of cultivated land; (3) encroachment of land without
approval; (4) unlawful approval of land occupancy; (5) granting of land at a
lower price, and other illegal behaviors related to land use.
These land-law violations are intertwined with bribery, abuse of power,
and fraudulence and are, therefore, abusive and corrupt in nature. The criminal
law classifies two other types of land-law violations—unlawful approval of
land occupancy and granting of land at a lower price—as crimes of
malfeasance.
20
Moreover, these land-law violations are processed by
disciplinary and supervisory organs in the same manner as corruption cases.
As a result, although land-law violations are not completely accurate in
reflecting land corruption, they can be employed as a reasonable proxy of
corrupt and abusive government behaviors in land use. The data related to
land-law violations and land transactions is compiled by the Ministry of Land
and Resources and obtained from the China Land and Resources Almanac.
Other relevant data is collected from China Statistical Yearbook, China
Financial Yearbook and provincial yearbooks, and summarized in Table 7.
21
See the Ministry of Land and Resources, ―Bu 39 Hao Ling Xiangjie‖ [―Elaboration of
Circular No. 39‖], http://www.mlr.gov.cn/zwgk/zcjd/200712/t20071212_666999.htm.
61
Describing the Trend of Land Corruption in China
This section attempts to show the impact of tender, auction and
quotation modes on land corruption by looking at the trend of land
lawbreaking. Our primary interest is to find out whether the level of land
corruption has declined after the market-led land supply system was adopted.
In the history of land reforms in contemporary China, tender and auction
modes were initially adopted in the late 1980s but accounted for an extremely
small fraction of urban land deals (Table 4). Marketization process gained a
strong momentum in 2002 when the Regulations governing the Granting of
Use Rights in State-Owned Land by Tender, Auction and Quotation (Circular
No. 11 of the Ministry of Land and Resources) was officially implemented
across the country. This regulation aggressively promoted the development of
the market-led urban land supply, in effect institutionalizing the tender,
auction and quotation system. Nationwide implementation of such new policy
implies a strong will of the central government in abandoning state control and
introducing market forces to manage urban land resources. Opposite to free
and negotiated land deals which are subject to intensive state intervention,
tender, auction and quotation modes respect market competition and serve
clients‘ interests. This circular is so influential that the Chinese view it as the
―second revolution in land‖.21 The following table shows urban land supply
21
See the Ministry of Land and Resources, ―Bu 39 Hao Ling Xiangjie‖ [―Elaboration of
Circular No. 39‖], http://www.mlr.gov.cn/zwgk/zcjd/200712/t20071212_666999.htm.
62
deals via different methods between 1998 and 2008.
Table 4. Urban Land Supply Via Different Means, 1998-2008
Year
Total
Free Administrative
Negotiation
Allocation
Tender, Auction,
Quotation
plots
plots
percentage
plots
percentage
plots
percentage
1998
529467
399050
75.37%
117266
22.15%
13151
2.48%
1999
267788
168771
63.02%
83692
31.25%
15325
5.72%
2000
279130
160284
57.42%
99632
35.69%
19214
6.88%
2001
311325
141168
45.34%
145228
46.65%
24929
8.01%
2002
333258
104491
31.35%
203866
61.17%
24901
7.47%
2003
255721
48334
18.90%
157381
61.54%
50006
19.55%
2004
221694
36844
16.62%
138111
62.30%
46739
21.08%
2005
192693
30581
15.87%
117642
61.05%
44470
23.08%
2006
217414
30747
14.14%
140933
64.82%
45734
21.04%
2007
187313
26909
14.37%
109748
58.59%
50656
27.04%
2008
149688
26330
17.59%
68093
45.49%
55265
36.92%
Average
267772
106683
33.64%
125599
50.06%
35490
16.30%
Total
2945491
1173509
39.84%
1381592
46.91%
390390
13.25%
Sources: China Land and Resources Almanac, 1999-2009.
At first glance, free and negotiated allocations dominated the urban
land supply throughout the 10 years between 1998 and 2008, accounting for
86.75% of total land allocations, while only 13.25% were achieved through
complete market modes. However, a close examination of land allocations
between 1998 and 2008 (see Table 4) suggests that the marketization process
accelerated after 2002 when the new land supply policy (tender, auction and
quotation) was officially adopted. In 1998, the market modes accounted only
for 2.48% of total land supply plots. However, the percentage of tender,
63
auction and quotation modes saw a big increase in 2003, from 7.47% to
19.55%, while the free administrative allocations were significantly reduced.
Also in the same year, the total number of market modes exceeded free
administrative allocations to become the second important land allocation
channel. After 2003, institutional changes to the land system have resulted in a
steady increase in the usage of market land allocation modes. Considering the
substantial influence of the new land supply policy, we incorporate it as an
indicator of a transition toward market land supply system and predict that the
land corruption rate will decline after 2002.
In the following stage, we select two indicators to show the national
trend of land corruption: the number of illegal land-use cases and the amount
of land being illegally used. These two indicators reflect different aspects of
land corruption: illegal land-use cases suggest the occurrence of land
corruption, while the amount of illegally-used land indicates its severity.
Relying on a single indicator does not capture the complete picture of land
corruption in China. Hence, both indictors are illustrated in Figure 3.
64
200000
150000
100000
50000
0
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
Illegal Land-Use Cases
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Illegally-Used Land(hectare)
Source: China Land and Resources Almanac 1999-2009.
Figure 3. Trend of Land Corruption at the National Level
As Figure 3 illustrates, the two trend lines of lawbreaking present
conflicting results. Between 1998 and 2008, the number of illegal land-use
cases progressively declined, albeit with some fluctuations, from which we
can infer that land corruption occurred less frequently. However, an opposite
trend was clearly observed in the total amount of land being illegally used.
From 1998 to 2002, the amount of abused land remained stable, with a big
jump in 2003, maintaining an increasing trend thereafter. Given the opposite
trend in the two indicators, one may conclude that the impact of market land
supply modes on corruption remains unknown because it is unclear whether
land corruption has worsened after 2003. However, the answer emerges if we
reconsider the meaning of each indicator based on following information.
65
Table 5. Breakdown of Land-Law Violators (Illegal Land-Use Cases)
State Organs
Illegal Land
Percentage
Use Cases
Enterprises & Institutions
Illegal Land
Percentage
Individuals
Illegal Land
Use Cases
Percentage
Use Cases
1998
5713
4.86%
19549
16.64%
92221
78.50%
1999
15069
9.08%
15030
9.05%
135943
81.87%
2000
18075
9.61%
15152
8.06%
154845
82.33%
2001
11243
8.59%
13425
10.26%
106235
81.16%
2002
12671
9.16%
16734
12.09%
108978
78.75%
2003
20067
11.23%
29654
16.60%
128933
72.17%
2004
10277
8.97%
21192
18.50%
83057
72.52%
2005
8054
7.21%
21037
18.83%
82632
73.96%
2006
11445
8.73%
27697
21.13%
91935
70.14%
2007
11987
9.72%
27877
22.60%
83479
67.68%
2008
8481
8.46%
16382
16.34%
75403
75.20%
Total
133082
8.87%
223729
14.91%
1143661
76.22%
Source: China Land and Resource Almanac, 1999-2009.
Table 6. Breakdown of Land-Law Violators (Illegally-Used Land)
State Organs
Illegally-Used
Percentage
Land(hectare)
Enterprises & Institutions
Illegally-Used
Percentage
Land(hectare)
Individuals
Illegally-Used
Percentage
Land(hectare)
1998
10358.09
29.91%
15128.32
43.69%
9141.85
26.40%
1999
8892.58
31.01%
14088.80
49.13%
5693.44
19.86%
2000
13745.40
43.38%
9622.12
30.37%
8319.71
26.26%
2001
12239.48
44.10%
9022.19
32.51%
6494.45
23.40%
2002
10868.23
34.43%
14182.13
44.93%
6511.75
20.63%
2003
20468.47
29.94%
33313.30
48.72%
14592.12
21.34%
2004
20208.70
25.02%
48294.34
59.80%
12255.97
15.18%
2005
9999.38
19.16%
27656.89
52.99%
14536.55
27.85%
2006
22029.02
23.88%
42244.60
45.80%
27963.80
30.32%
2007
25689.91
25.93%
52364.50
52.86%
21014.55
21.21%
2008
12452.00
21.60%
34284.40
59.46%
10923.46
18.94%
Total
166951.26
27.61%
300201.59
49.56%
137447.65
22.73%
Source: China Land and Resource Almanac, 1999-2009.
66
Tables 5 and 6 show the distribution of land corruption among
different violators based on the data from 1998 to 2008. The information of
illegal land-use cases in Table 5 gives the impression that individuals were the
most frequent violators of land laws, accounting for 76.22% of total cases,
followed by enterprises and institutions (qishiye danwei). However, in Table 6,
close examination of the illegally-used land reveals that enterprises and
institutions accounted for about half of the land being abused; local
government organs were responsible for 27.61% while only 22.73% were
caused by individuals. Since many enterprises and institutions are state-owned
or strongly supported by the governments, they can be regarded as state organs
or quasi-state organs. In which case, state agencies were responsible for 77.27%
of illegally-used land. Moreover, the average size of land illegally used by
individuals is 0.13 hectares; in sharp contrast, the number is 15.34 hectares for
state agencies. Thus, local state agencies constitute major violators of land laws
and regulations.
To summarize, the indicator of illegal land-use cases reflects many
individual behaviors rather than state violations, while the amount of
illegally-used land is an accurate indicator on the misuse of land by local
states, which is why I choose to select the former to decide the level of land
corruption. As Figure 3 illustrates, land corruption was aggravated in the
2000s, and market-led land supply policy (tender, auction and quotation)
67
adopted in 2002 failed to prevent the growth of land abuses in the following
years. This finding is similar to an earlier study by Liang (2009), who also
found that adoption of market-led land supply policy in 2002 was positively
related to land law violations in 2002, 2003 and 2004. However, to obtain
more robust results and convincing conclusion, it is necessary to perform
rigorous regression analysis to test the relations between the two.
Regression Analysis
The descriptive analysis in the previous section investigated the impact
of the 2002 market-led land supply policy and showed the fact that land
corruption worsened, in terms of the size of land being illegally used. Chapter
3 looked at the transformation of urban land supply regime and discussed
some drawbacks of the current land reforms. On that basis, two hypotheses
were proposed on the association between market-led land supply system and
corruption. In this section, I run regressions on a set of panel data to explore
the effects of tender, auction and quotation modes on land corruption.
Empirical Model Specification
In this paper, the panel data has spatial and time specific effects. When
I first conducted the Breusch-Pagan LM test to decide between random effects
regression and simple ordinary least squares (OLS) regression, the results
gave an extremely small P-value, implying that differences across provinces
68
are significant. Therefore, I determined that the OLS estimation method was
not appropriate, and that either fixed-effects model or random-effects model
should be used. Hausman test gives a P value larger than 0.05, hence a
random-effects model is preferred in analyzing the panel data. Furthermore,
the panel data have provincial and time specific effects and hence, a two-way
random-effects panel model is more appropriate. The model is specified in the
following:
LnYit =α+ βXit + ui +λt +εit
Where: Y is a land corruption rate of a province in a particular year, β is a
vector of coefficients of X, Xit is a matrix of the independent variables of the i
province at the time t; α is a constant, εis residuals, ui and λt indicate the
effects of provinces and time respectively, i denotes the provinces (i=1 to 31),
and t denotes the year (t=1 to 11).
Dependent Variable
The unit of analysis in this research consists of 31 provinces in China,
and the dependent variable is the level of illegality and corruption in land
sector within a specific province. There is no ideal method available to
precisely measure the level of corruption, particularly with regard to
land-related corruption. This study uses documented instances of land-law
violations to reflect abusive and illegal land-use behaviors of local
governments; both illegal land-use cases and areas involved in those cases
69
were utilized to provide a more comprehensive picture of land corruption in
China. For normalization and controlling for large variations due to outliers, I
use the log of illegal land-use cases per million local residents (LnLandcase)
and the log of illegally-used land areas in hectares (LnLandarea).
Explanatory Variables
The first hypothesis assumes a positive role of market-led land supply
system on corruption; thus, marketization is incorporated as a major
explanatory variable of the regression analysis. In terms of the measure for
marketization in urban land supply, some scholars use the real number of land
allocations through different modes (negotiation, tender, auction and quotation)
to measure the degree of marketization in land sales (Tao, Zhang &Li, 2010).
However, the real numbers of land allocations are less advantageous than
percentages in showing the relative weight and importance of different
allocation modes. Instead of using real number of land allocations, we create a
measure for the level of marketization in urban land supply (Mkt) using the
percentage of market-led land supply modes (tender, auction and quotation) in
total urban land allocation plots. The rationale is that tender, auction and
quotation modes encourage competition, transparency and fairness, while free
and negotiated allocations have heavy exposure to state control and
intervention.22 The measurement is defined in the following:
22
In the study by Tao, Zhang &Li (2010), the effects of tender, auction and quotation are
tested separately, however, this method is inappropriate for this research. First, the plots of
70
plots of tender auction and quotation
total plots free allocation negotiation tender auction and quotation
The second hypothesis illustrates the relationship between financial
dependence on land corruption. As explained in Chapter 3, local governments
are heavily relying on the commercialization of LURs to finance local public
service delivery. Such financial motives of local government lead to irrational
grabbing and selling of land resources, which opens doors for abuses and
corruption (Ding, 2002; Lin, 2009). Hence we incorporate the second
explanatory variable, which is the local governments‘ financial dependence on
land-related revenues. The measure of financial dependence on land-related
revenues is controversial in existing literature because the definition of
land-related revenues remains ambiguous in China. Broadly speaking,
land-related revenues encompass diverse items ranging from land conveyance
fees to various taxes charged on land and real estate market. Liu, Zhang &Ma
(2008) believe land-related revenues consist of four major categories (Figure
4).
tender and auction modes are much smaller than that of quotation; second, tender, auction and
quotation are integrated as one policy package that is difficult to be separated. In order to
study the policy outcomes, it is more reasonable to show how the three modes influence
corruption as a whole.
71
Land-related Revenues
Land leasing fees
(most important)
Taxes on land
(about 6 items)
Officially known
Figure 4.
Administrative
fees
Other invisible
income from land
Officially unknown
Land-Related Revenues
Contrary to the broad definition of land-related revenues, a narrow
definition only counts the most important component of land-related
revenues—land leasing fees. Studies by Du, Huang and Wu (2009) and Liang
(2009) adopted this narrow definition to measure financial dependence on
land—the percentage of land conveyance fees in total government revenues.
To minimize the measurement error, this paper adopts a broad definition.
However, due to the unavailability of data related to administrative fees and
invisible income from land, this paper only counts land leasing fees and
land-related taxes. Land-related taxes in this research include six items: house
property tax, urban land using tax, land value increment tax, agriculture tax
(abolished in 2006), tax on the use of arable land, and tax on contracts. The
land leasing fees are the total payment for obtaining LURs.23 The variable of
financial dependence on land (Dep) is measured by the percentage of
23
Normally local governments use some amount of land leasing fees to pay the cost of
demolishing, compensation and relocation of residents, etc., therefore government revenues
collected from land conveyance should be the net income with the cost being excluded.
However, the exact number of net incomes of land conveyance are not documented before
2003, but based on the data from 2003 to 2008, the payment of cost is rather small compared
to the net income. Take Beijing as an example, the size of net income accounts for an average
number of 77.6% in total land leasing fees annually, while the remaining 22.4% is accounted
for by cost.
72
land-related revenues in total amount of government revenues in a particular
province. Sources of data include China Statistical Yearbook, China Financial
Yearbook and China Land and Resources Almanac.
Control Variables
To isolate the effects of explanatory variables, we hold constant the
effects of other factors that may influence the level of land corruption. The
control variables in the empirical model include law enforcement, GDP per
capita, government size, real estate investment, relative wage in public sector,
and citizens‘ education.
Law enforcement (Law). The first control variable concerns the level of
law enforcement in local areas. In Dong and Torgler‘s (2010) work, the
level of law enforcement was measured by regional expenditure on police,
procuratorate, the courts and judiciary per capita. This paper constructs
the measure for law enforcement following Dong and Torgler‘ s approach,
that is, per capita expenditure by law enforcement agencies (police,
procuratorate, court and judiciary). This measure indicates how many
efforts have been made to detect crimes and to maintain order. The data of
law enforcement expenditures is collected from China Statistical
Yearbook.
73
GDP Per capita (GDPpc). We incorporated the level of economic
development in the empirical model because it is the critical part of local
officials‘ achievement within their term. Earlier studies pointed out that
since land can be used as a subsidy to attract investors contributing to
local development, chances of land abuses and corruption were high
because of the focus on short-term economic growth. In addition, regional
economic development level is commonly employed as control variables
by corruption studies (Treisman, 2000; Drury et al., 2006; Del Monte &
Papagni, 2007; Lessmann & Markwardt, 2009; Dong & Torgler, 2010).
Following a similar approach, I measured the regional economic growth
level using the log of Gross Regional Product per capita in RMB
(LnGDPpc), using the China Statistical Yearbook as the source.
Government size. Pro-market critique suggests that a larger government
leads to more rent-seeking behaviors (Tanzi, 1997; Rose-Ackerman,
2008). In many empirical studies, government size is frequently employed
as explanatory variable or control variable (Gerring & Thacker, 2005;
Goel & Nelson, 1998; Husted, 1999). In the Chinese context, Zhou and
Tao (2009) used government employment and fiscal expenditure per
capita as two indicators of government size; Wu (2008) used government
expenditures relative to local GDP to measure government size; Dong and
Torgler (2010) proposed the ratio of regional consolidated revenue to
local GDP and the employment share of the public sector as indicators of
74
government size. Following these approaches, I construct two measures
for government size: the relative size of government employment to
private employment (Govemploy), and the ratio of total government
expenditures (budgetary +off-budgetary expenditures) to local GDP
(Govspend). The data was obtained from China Statistical Yearbook.
Real estate investment (Rei). The rationale to control real estate
investment in the model is that a burgeoning real estate industry produces
need for land expropriation and allocation, creating chances of land
disputes, policy distortion, abuses and corruption as well. In other words,
the real estate industry encourages land corruption on the demand side.
This paper uses the ratio of real estate investment to regional GDP to
measure the development of real estate industry. The source of data is
China Statistical Yearbook.
Relative wage (Wage). Empirical studies show that low salary paid to
civil servants is associated with corruption (Rijckeghem & Weber, 1997),
while an increase in wages significantly lessens corruption (Herzfeld &
Weiss, 2003). Wu‘s (2008) study of corruption in China suggests that an
increase in wage levels in public sector can reduce corruption to a certain
level. Thus, the relative wage of public sector is considered as a control
variable in the model. Empirical work by Dong and Torgler (2010) also
reported that high relative wages within the public sector prevent officials
from corruption. In this paper, the wage level is measured by the ratio of
75
government employees‘ wage to local average wage, which is consistent
with the studies by Wu (2008) and Dong and Torgler (2010). The source
of data is China Statistical Yearbook.
Citizens‘ education (Edu). Citizens‘ education level is employed as a
proxy of social and cultural factors of corruption. The level and quality of
citizens‘ education vary significantly across China‘s vast local areas;
hence its influences should not be overlooked. Well-educated citizens are
more likely to supervise and scrutinize government behaviors as they
have more demand over public goods and services. They may show little
or zero tolerance for corruption and possess strong intention to reveal
corruption cases. Furthermore, citizens‘ education contributes to a
participative civic culture which is counterproductive to government
corruption (Putnam, 1993), and a participatory populace can exert
constraints on the politicians‘ ability to accumulate and arbitrarily use
rights (Kaufmann,1998). The level of citizens‘ education is measured by
the average number of schooling years in local areas.
76
Table 7. Variable Definition
Dependent
Variable
LnLandcase
Definition
Sources of data
The log of illegal land use cases per
China Land and Resources
million residents
Almanac;
China
Statistical
Yearbook
LnLandarea
Explanatory
Variable
Mkt
The log of illegally-used land areas in
China Land and Resources
hectares
Almanac
Definition
Sources of data
The plots of land allocations via tender,
China Land and Resources
auction and quotation modes divided
Almanac
by total plots of land allocations
Dep
The land-related revenues divided by
China Land and Resources
total local fiscal revenues
Almanac;
China
Statistical
Yearbook;
China
Financial
Yearbook
Control
Variables
Law
Definition
Per
capita
Sources of data
expenditure
of
law
China Statistical Yearbook
enforcement agencies (procuratortes,
courts, police and judiciaries)
LnGDPpc
Log of Gross Regional Product per
China Statistical Yearbook
capita
Rei
The ratio of real estate investment to
China Statistical Yearbook
regional GDP
Govemploy
The
size
of
local
governments
China Statistical Yearbook
measured by the ratio of government
employment to private employment
Govspend
The
spending
size
of
local
China Statistical Yearbook
governments measured by the share of
government expenditures in regional
GDP
Wage
The relative wage in public sector to
China Statistical Yearbook
local average wage
Edu
Average schooling years of local
China Statistical Yearbook
residents
Descriptive Statistics
The descriptive statistics of dependent variables and two explanatory variables
77
are highlighted in Table 8. Statistics of other variables are described in
Appendix B.
Table 8. Descriptive Statistics of Dependent and Explanatory Variables
Variable
Mean
Std. Dev.
Landcase overall
104.0846 87.03091
between
65.33989
within
58.45929
Landarea
Dep
Mkt
overall
1862.66
between
within
overall
0.349633
between
within
overall
0.195743
between
within
2600.415
1625.623
2050.351
0.293009
0.143274
0.25677
0.168861
0.081189
0.148471
Min
Max
Observations
4
719
N = 319
33.81818 317.6
n = 31
-83.3699 505.4846 T-bar =
10.2903
0.46
21346.52 N = 306
80.665
7894.271 n = 31
-2916.5
19665.23 T = 9.87097
0.008
1.784
N = 341
0.111364 0.661818 n = 31
-0.20018 1.536088 T = 11
0.001
0.798
N = 331
0.047182 0.390818 n = 31
-0.17508 0.687016 T-bar =
10.6774
The panel data used in this study should consist of 341 observations
for 31 provinces during 11 years (from 1998 to 2008). However, because of
missing data in some provinces, the observations were not equal across
different variables. Finally, 240 to 258 observations were taken in the
random-effects regressions. The mean of provincial illegal land-use cases per
million residents is 104, with a standard deviation of 87. With regard to the
Landarea, the mean of illegally-used land areas in the provinces is 1862.66
hectares, with a standard deviation of 2600. Descriptive statistics suggest that
frequency and severity of illegal land-use activities vary substantially across
provinces and time periods. For instance, Tibet had only 0.46 hectares of
78
illegally-used land in 2000, while Guizhou had 21,346.52 hectares in 2004.
The degree of provincial financial dependence on land-related
revenues is, on average, as high as 34.9%, with a standard deviation of 29.3%.
In some provinces, land-related revenues account for only 0.8% of
government fiscal revenues; in others, however, the amount of land-related
revenues may be 1.78 times of government fiscal revenues. As explained
earlier, land-related revenues in this research do not exclude the cost such as
demolition fees and peasants‘ compensation, nevertheless we can estimate the
contribution of land-related capital to local finance, as the cost is rather low
compared to revenue. In terms of the level of marketization in urban land
supply, between 1998 and 2008, only about 19.6% of land sales were via
tender, auction or quotation modes. China‘s urban land market is still subject
to heavy state intervention and far from mature. Figure 5 shows regional
variations in dependent and independent variables.
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
0
Average number of land corruption cases per million residents, 1998-2008
Source: China Land and Resource Almanac, 1999-2009.
79
Figure 5. Regional Variations in Illegal Land-Use Cases, 1998-2008
As shown in Figure 5, provincial variations in land corruption cases
were significant. Provinces ranking high in land corruption cases include
Zhejiang, Fujian and Gaungxi. Surprisingly, Guizhou province had the largest
number of land corruption cases per million residents during this period.
Provinces such as Tibet, Tianjin, Beijing, Heilongjiang, Shanghai and Jilin had
smaller number of land corruption cases. The regional gap of land corruption
was as large as 300 cases per million residents. From Figure 5, it is difficult to
claim that the distribution of land corruption cases follows a geographical rule
because both coastal and inner land provinces can have large number of land
corruption cases (refer to the map of China in Appendix C).
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
Average amount of illegally-used land areas between 1999 and 2008
Source: China Land and Resource Almanac, 2000-2009.
Note: the author has tried to find the data of provincial illegally-used land areas in 1998, but
the complete version of China Land and Resource Almanac of 1999 is not obtainable.
Figure 6. Regional Variations in Illegally-Used Land Areas, 1999-2008
80
In comparison with Figure 5, Figure 6 shows the distribution of
illegally-used land among different provinces. Surprisingly, Qinghai province
had the largest average amount of illegally-used land during this period,
followed by Jiangsu, Ningxia, Tibet and Gansu. Except for Jiangsu, the other
four highly ranked provinces are all located in inner land and underdeveloped
areas. Among the most corrupt provinces in urban land sector, Beijing and
Ningxia have smaller geographical sizes compared to other provinces, yet
their amounts of illegally-used land areas are large, suggesting that neither
territorial sizes nor geographical locations determine the distribution of land
abuses. The capital, Beijing, deserves attention. In Figure 5, it ranks as one of
the cleanest provinces in terms of land corruption cases, but ironically, the
amount of abused land turns out to be very large in Figure 6. All in all, the two
indicators—illegal land-use cases and size of illegally-used land areas—give
confusing results in explaining regional variations. Deciding which provinces
have relatively cleaner urban land sector is secondary to the more important
question: does the newly created market-led land supply system (tender,
auction and quotation mechanisms) exert influence on land corruption? Figure
7 presents information about the degree of marketization in urban land supply
regime across provinces.
81
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Number of tender,auction and quotation modes/total land alocation plots
Source: China Land and Resource Almanac, 1999-2009.
Figure 7. Different Levels of Marketization in Urban Land Supply,
1998-2008
Figure 7 shows regional variations in terms of marketization in urban
land supply. Provinces with a high level of marketization (or low level of state
intervention) in urban land supply include Jiangxi, Hainan, Henan, Yunnan
and Guizhou, which are economically underdeveloped and located at the inner
land of China. By contrast, Beijing, Sichuan, Xinjiang, Tainjin, Shanghai and
Jilin, which are larger economies, have the lowest level of marketization in
urban land management. Coincidentally, Jilin, Tianjin, and Xinjinag show
smaller size of illegally-used land, according to Figure 6. This phenomenon
contradicts with the conventional knowledge that state intervention (or a low
level of marketization) leads to more corruption. Similarly, Jiangxi, Hainan
and Henan are among the most marketized provinces in terms of land supply.
However, neither land corruption cases nor illegally-used land areas have a
82
smaller size in these three provinces. Does this mean that market-led land
supply system exerts no influence on the level of land corruption? The
following section will answer this question based on regression analysis.
Regression results
To estimate the correlations between land corruption and two
explanatory variables, I run four regressions using different indicators of land
corruption—illegal land-use cases and the amount of illegally-used land areas.
The following table presents estimation results of two-way random-effects
panel model.
Table 9. Results of Two-Way Random-Effects Regression
Dep
(1)
LnLandcase
0.285*
(0.172)
Mkt
Law
LnGDPpc
Wage
Govspend
Govemploy
Rei
Edu
_cons
0.00233***
(0.001)
-0.737***
(0.187)
-0.143
(0.443)
-0.338
(0.446)
-0.808
(0.510)
-2.419
(1.517)
0.0306
(0.093)
11.10***
(2)
LnLandcase
0.0213
(0.347)
0.00239**
(0.001)
-0.684***
(0.196)
-0.146
(0.456)
-0.331
(0.448)
-1.004*
(0.517)
-2.007
(1.460)
0.0390
(0.096)
10.64***
(3)
LnLandarea
1.011***
(0.269)
-0.00131
(0.001)
0.690**
(0.290)
-0.543
(0.721)
-0.182
(1.109)
-2.141**
(0.853)
-9.513***
(2.491)
0.409***
(0.147)
-1.336
(4)
LnLandarea
-0.813
(0.610)
-0.00256*
(0.002)
0.628*
(0.332)
-0.101
(0.762)
-0.704
(1.127)
-2.349***
(0.829)
-6.743***
(2.318)
0.367**
(0.153)
-0.386
83
lns1_1_1
_cons
lns1_2_1
_cons
lnsig_e
_cons
N
(1.546)
-0.673***
(0.074)
-2.181***
(0.044)
-0.790***
(0.022)
258
(1.604)
-0.660***
(0.077)
-2.037***
(0.048)
-0.796***
(0.022)
251
(2.481)
-0.234
(0.122)
-2.390**
(0.098)
-0.287***
(0.037)
245
(2.755)
-0.257
(0.128)
-0.911**
(0.177)
-0.333***
(0.036)
240
Note: Standard errors in parentheses
*
p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01
The first finding is that financial dependence on land resources,
measured by the share of land-related revenues in local fiscal revenues
(budgetary+ off-budgetary), has indeed aggravated corruption in land
management. The coefficient of Dep has a positive sign and remains
significant above 0.90 confidence level in both specification (1) and (3). In
specification (1), the coefficient of Dep is 0.285, suggesting 100 percentage
points increase in financial dependence on land resources leads to 28.5%
increase in land corruption cases; for instance, there were 320 land corruption
cases per million residents in Fujian province in 2008, if the percentage of
land-related revenues in total government revenues increases by 10 percent
points, an additional 9 cases will ensue, which gives a total of 329 land
corruption cases per million residents. In specification (3), Dep presents
stronger influence on land corruption that 10 percentage points increase of
Dep causes 10.1 percent increase in the total amount of illegally-used land.
This find has supported the prevalent opinion that ―fiscalization on land (tudi
caizheng)‖ is the root of corruption.
84
Throughout
the
above
specifications,
the
major
explanatory
variable—marketization of urban land supply—shows no statistically
significant impact on either illegal land-use cases or illegally-used land areas.
This regression result has confirmed the finding of descriptive analysis that
tender, auction and quotation modes failed to produce the intended outcomes.
In this being said, the first research question can be answered: the introduction
of market mechanisms does not reduce land corruption in China. The failure
of policies can be attributed to various reasons, such as bad policy design,
unsuccessful implementation, distortion, and numerous obstacles in policy
environment. The failure of market mechanisms—tender, auction and
quotation—will be analyzed comprehensively in next chapter.
Among the control variables, the level of law enforcement shows
positive association with occurrence of land corruption cases (specification (1))
but negative association with the size of illegally-used land (specification (4)).
Law enforcement is measured by per capita expenditure of legal agencies
(police, procuratorate, courts and judiciaries); hence, greater spending on law
enforcement may suggest a higher level of detection on land corruption, thus
more cases may be disclosed in the short period. However, harsh detection
may only target at individual behaviors rather than government‘s violations,
since individual cases account for a dominant percent in total illegal land-use
cases. Given that individuals are responsible for a small proportion of
illegally-used land, the effects of legal detection on the amount of abused land
85
are marginally significant (90% confidence level).
Another control variable per capita GDP also exerts conflicting
influence on land corruption. In specification (1), per capita GDP is
significantly negatively correlated with illegal land-use cases. Furthermore,
the influencing magnitude is as large as 73.7%. In other words, an 1% increase
in per capita GDP will reduce land corruption cases by 73.7%; economically
developed areas have fewer land corruption cases than underdeveloped areas.
In sharp contrast, when the dependent variable is measured by the amount of
illegally-used land, the association between per capita GDP and land
corruption becomes significantly positive. One possible explanation is that
rich areas, for instance, Shanghai, are highly urbanized and industrialized,
individual residents in those areas are less likely to be involved in misuse of
land resources as they are employed in manufacturing and service industries
rather than agriculture, hence, the number of illegal land-use cases is much
smaller. On the other hand, industrialized areas demand large-scale land
conversion and allocation to serve manufacturing and construction industries;
hence, misuse of large amounts of land resources is rampant.
Summary of Empirical Study
In this chapter, I described the national trend of land corruption to
show the impact of the market-led land supply policy adopted in 2002. I also
conducted regression analysis to test the hypotheses proposed in the preceding
86
chapter. Firstly, I found that land corruption in China has escalated with regard
to the amount of land being abusively used. The central government‘s
aggressive promotion of market-led land allocation policy in 2002 failed to
prevent the misuse of land resources; ironically, land lawbreaking witnessed a
new surge after 2002. The regression analysis finds no empirical evidence to
support the relationship between land corruption and market-led land supply
modes, which confirms the finding discovered through descriptive analysis. In
addition, regression results suggest that the money-centered land development
paradigm has stimulated predatory land use behaviors in localities. To grab
financial resources, local governments are irrationally and abusively using
land resources, opening another door for corruption.
All in all, why does the market-led land supply policy fail to fulfill the
objective in reducing land corruption? Why does land continue to be misused
after tender, auction and quotation modes were implemented? The questions
will be answered by examining the conflicting and paradoxical nature of the
newly established urban land supply regime in the next chapter. Employing an
institutional approach, Chapter 5 investigates how market-led land supply
system has shaped corruption in land sector.
87
Chapter 5
Discussion of Regression Results
The introduction of land market is a strategic remedy to the socialist
inefficient land management system and rampant illegal land deals in the
black market. In the preceding chapter, I tested the relationship between
market-led land supply modes—tender, auction and quotation—and illegal
land-use activities. Descriptive and regression analyses reveal that tender,
auction and quotation modes fail to prevent land from being abused; on the
contrary, land corruption continues to escalate even after the new land supply
policy was adopted. This finding raises an important question in this study:
why has the market-led urban land supply system, originally designed for
reducing corruption, failed to achieve its goal? This chapter attempts to
discuss and interpret this finding from an institutional perspective. It argues
that tender, auction and quotation modes are not to be blamed for rampant
corruption in land sector, instead, it is the legal and institutional loopholes in
current land management regime that jeopardize the functioning of urban land
supply system and makes land corruption difficult to control.
Institutional Loopholes in Market-Led Land Supply System
According to North (1990), ―institutions are the rules of the game in a
88
society or, more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape
human interaction‖ (p. 3). Institutions include both formal constraints—the
laws
and
regulations
devised
by
governments,
and
informal
rules—conventions and codes of conduct existing in social life. The
significance of institutions lies in their functions to reduce uncertainty and
provide a guide to human interactions. North (1990) further elaborated that
―institutions affect the performance of the economy by their effect on the costs
of exchange and production‖ (p. 5). Well-designed institutions reduce
transaction cost and enhance revenue production, whereas poorly designed
institutions cause inefficiency and corruption, which, in turn, undermines
economic performance. The value of institutions is demonstrated by many
other scholars. Williamson (1985) has emphasized the role of formal
institutions in reducing transaction costs and thus in enhancing the
performance of economic organizations. Another scholar Ostrom (1990) also
discussed how institutional design resolves the misuse of common resources
by individuals under the dilemma of collective action. The author proposed
that to resolve the problems of commons, cooperative institutions must be
carefully designed with effective monitoring and enforcing mechanisms, and
those resource users shall participate in governing the rules.
The term ―institutions‖ in this chapter focus on the official rules in
dealing with land management issues. The capacity and quality of institutions
is of great importance to the healthy functioning of urban land administration
89
system in China where a transitional economy has its uncertainties. Strong
institutional capacity enables land polices to be effectively carried out;
however, when institutions are poorly designed and weak, the efficiency and
integrity of land management is severely undermined, resulting in abusive and
corrupt practices. The institutional approach has been widely employed by
scholars to analyze urbanization and land reforms in China (Zhu, 1999; Ho,
2001, 2005; Qian, 2007; Wei & Zhao, 2009). Drawing upon a similar
approach, I conduct a preliminary study to identify the institutional loopholes
in current tender, auction and quotation system to explain its failure in curbing
corruption. The discussion is based on the 20 land corruption scandals
(Appendix A) and national data of illegally-used land areas (Table 10).
Table 10. Breakdown of Illegally-Used Land Areas at the National Level,
1998-2008
illegally-used
Year
land areas in
current year
Illegal
Damage
Encroachment
Unlawful
Granting
Purchase,
of
of Land
Approval
of Land at
Sale and
Cultivated
Without
of Land
a Lower
Transfer
Land
Approval
Occupancy
Price
Others
1998
34628.26
4614.80
763.43
22728.29
925.67
20.26
6885.02
1999
18553.81
2523.85
682.16
8644.58
300.41
63.70
6339.11
2000
22312.72
2591.51
775.87
12792.35
2262.89
213.07
3677.03
2001
17084.57
1859.32
875.02
12186.56
556.26
6.86
1600.55
2002
18100.17
1395.55
643.73
14519.62
96.95
5.89
1438.43
2003
28836.37
1823.67
889.92
24347.26
319.86
39.11
1416.45
2004
33122.15
1731.16
1013.92
28015.66
337.80
250.22
1773.38
2005
24501.27
859.15
1252.10
20997.84
37.69
0.40
1354.09
2006
55562.78
1872.57
1552.64
44173.21
4417.49
846.58
2700.29
2007
56705.65
2176.17
1266.50
49778.91
1026.40
14.08
2443.59
2008
22019.5
696.14
457.39
19847.62
227.47
0.05
790.83
332736.46
22143.89
10172.68
258031.9
10508.89
1460.22
30418.77
100%
6.66%
3.06%
77.55%
3.16%
0.44%
9.14%
Total
90
Source: China Yearbook of Land and Almanac 1999-2009, unit: hectare.
Table 10 (above) shows that illegally-used land areas are concentrated
on encroachment of land without approval (weijing pizhun zhandi), which
accounts for 77.55% of total land areas, followed by illegal purchase, sale or
transfer of LURs (maimai huo feifa zhuanrang), accounting for about 6.66%. In
addition, an increasing trend is clearly observed in two types of land-law
violations—damage of cultivated land, and encroachment of land without
approval. It appears that illegal land occupancy is the driving force of growing
illegally-used land areas. The question remains: why does land continue to be
illegally occupied, even though LURs have been openly granted through
tender, auction and quotation? In Figure 8, I reveal the risks of corruption
embedded in the procedures of market-led urban land supply system.
91
Figure 8. Risks of Corruption and Illegality in Tender, Auction and
Quotation24
Manipulation of Information
At the initial stage, land use information such as size, location, and
above-land fixtures, is announced by land administration organs; however,
such information may not be equally accessible to all potential land buyers, in
another scenario, obtaining the information is a time-consuming process. On
the supply side, information asymmetry increases transactions costs and
motivates land buyers to bribe land administration officials to get sufficient
land use information. On the demand side, land administration officials intend
to extract bribes from land buyers by hiding and selling information.
Communications in private between land buyers and individual land officials
are commonly held on a ―mutual benefits‖ basis. One local developer said that
they have to ―communicate‖ with local officials on a daily basis to get the
latest information about local land use, failing which, other developers would
obtain the information and exploit the opportunity to make profits. This
communication is often accompanied by feasting and gift giving, which makes
it difficult to detect and prove bribery and corruption.25
24
The stage of approving construction projects is excluded in Figure 8 because it mainly
involves urban planning organs rather than land supply organs, although the two are closely
related, they are in charge of different tasks.
25
Interview with a local real estate developer on November 23, 2010.
92
Problematic Selection of Land Supply Mode
At the second stage, a land allocation method is chosen between various
modes. The central government has mandated tender, auction and quotation
modes to acquire LURs for the purposes of industrial, commercial, tourism,
entertainment and commercial premises. However, many local officials choose
private negotiation as a land supply method instead of complete market modes.
The rules and regulations introduced by the central state were contested and
manipulated by local governments in various ways (Lin & Ho, 2005), making
local land regulations inconsistent with central policies. Xu, Yeh and Wu
(2009) noted that the enforcement of central policies was difficult as many were
overlooked by local states. The authors cited the example of land allocation in
Beijing municipality, when the center required all land used for business
purposes (commerce, tourism, entertainment and commodity housing) to be
allocated through market modes after July 1, 2002, the Beijing Municipal
Government issued Circular No. 33, which continued to allow negotiated
conveyance in four areas: small towns, green belts, urban renewal schemes, and
high-tech and major projects with urban significance. Negotiated land deals in
Beijing enlarged rather than decreased after the new land policy came into
effect (Xu, Yeh and Wu, 2009). The relationship between central and local
states has been dramatically redefined in current land politics, and the central
authority‘s efforts to reduce governmental role in land market have encountered
resistance in local areas where party and government leaders stimulate
93
economic growth and enrich themselves by manipulating land sales. A sudden
change in the land leasing system seems to shock localities and encourage
local governments to be disobedient. Power is abused to protect local interests.
Inconsistent and conflicting rules between the center and localities create
confusion in detecting illegal land use activities.
Distortion of Land Value
At the stage of evaluating land prices, land value is supposed to be
appraised by agencies or experts with professional qualifications in land
evaluation, and the bottom or starting price should never be known to buyers
prior to the start of the bidding process. The risks of corruption embedded at
this stage involve devaluation or overvaluation of land price. Firstly, the land
appraisal system is China was newly created in the 1990s; the qualifications of
land appraisal agencies are questionable and the criteria to be adopted in land
appraisal are vague, especially in underdeveloped areas. Moreover, many local
government officials who are unqualified to evaluate land values also
participate in the land assessment process. This administrative intervention
may distort the market pricing mechanism and bias the result; worse yet,
corrupt government officials are able to make use of the land assessment
information to help their friends or family obtain land at the lowest possible
price, as exampled by Dai Min‘s case. Even though professional land pricing
is gradually institutionalized and improved across the country, officials prices
94
can be abandoned as many land leasing prices are determined by negotiation
between local governments and land users with limited reference to the price
guidelines (Qian, 2008:500). This type of violation is closely linked to the
manipulation of land leasing modes discussed in the preceding section and
illegal reduction of land leasing fees to be discussed in following part.
Pre-Selection of Land Buyer
At the stage of operating tender, auction and quotation activities, risks
of corruption cannot be ruled out. Corruption occurring in tender and auction
activities has been documented by existing literature (Laffont & Tirole, 1991;
McAfee & McMillan, 1992; Compte et al., 2005; Menezes & Monteiro, 2006;
Burguet & Perry, 2007; Koc & Neilson, 2008; Arozamena & Weinschelbaum,
2009). Corruption can happen in auctions when bidders collude with each
other (McAfee & McMillan, 1992); bribery is likely to occur when land
administration officials, who administer the auctions, favor specific bidders
(Laffont & Tirole, 1991; Lengwiler & Wolfstetter, 2005); the level of
competitiveness in auctions affect the corruption level as well, as Celentani
and Ganuza (2002) found that corruption may increase as the number of
competing bidders is increased. These scholarly works commonly use
mathematical models to analyze the equilibrium of corruption in auctions.
Following similar auction rules, corruption is likely to take place in China‘s
land market as well. Differing from earlier studies, I approach this issue
95
through examining the institutional design of land auction system in China.
Current land legislations do not include specification on who are
qualified to participate in competition activities, which gives local land
administration organs too much discretionary power in choosing competitors.
Each locality appears to be making its own rules on the qualifications of land
bidders, as there are no clear and universal guidelines for selecting participants.
This institutional uncertainty creates and enhances opportunities for bribery,
cheating, fraud and corruption. For instance, as real estate tycoons usually
prefer monopoly, they may use different strategies to circumvent the
expensive market channels of buying land; instead, they tend to persuade land
administration officials to design bidding requirements that artificially
function as entry barriers, such as the amount of capital deposit, the
developer‘s rank and reputation in the real estate industry, etc. These bidding
requirements usually benefit favor-seekers and shut out other competitors. As
a result, arbitrary selection or direct appointment of winners is common in
land deals. The winners are those that pay the largest bribes or that claim
guanxi with land administration officials. Yu Feili‘s case exemplifies favor
seeking on behalf of officials‘ relatives. The information learned from the
author‘s fieldwork suggests that guanxi networks between investors and state
officials are usually a dominant factor in land deals.26
26
Interview with local real estate developers on December 3, 2010.
96
Theft of Public Funding
The final stage of land allocation system is the payment and
management of huge amounts of land leasing fees. Corruption happens most
frequently in this stage because of direct governmental exposure to money.
Bribery, embezzlement and misappropriation of public funds are major
manifestations of corruption at this stage. Firstly, land buyers who have strong
incentives to pay fewer fees tend to persuade land officials by offering bribes.
Of the 20 land corruption scandals studied, it was observed that unlawful
wavier or reduction of land leasing fees coupled with bribery occurred in at
least 10 cases: Hu Changqing, Cheng Kejie, Mu Suixin, Ma Xiangdong, Tian
Fengqi, He Minxu, Wang Wulong, etc. In an alternative scenario, illegal
reduction of land leasing fees is initiated by local governments as a strategy to
attract investors who contribute economic benefits and tax revenues to
localities; for instance, in ―industrial parks (gongyeyuan)‖ or ―development
zone (kaifaqu), land is leased for free or at a price far below market standard
to subsidize investors (Zhang, 1997), leading to a loss in the central
government‘s land revenues.
Besides bribery, embezzlement and misappropriation of public funds
happen as well. Categorized as extra-budgetary funds, land leasing fees can be
easily stolen due to a lack of effective internal accounting mechanism and
external scrutiny on extra-budgetary revenues, as reflected by Luo Yaping and
Chen Liangyu‘s cases. The National Audit Office‘s annual report revealed
97
many instances of mismanagement of land conveyance funds.27 Lin and Ho‘s
(2005) fieldwork in a county-level city on the Yangtze River Delta revealed
that over 98% of the land leasing fees collected between 1989 and 1997 were
retained by the municipal government and no monies were handed over to the
central state, which obviously led to losses in national land capital. 28 This
explains the regression result that fiscalization on land encourages land-law
violations.
Obtaining Land Use Rights—the Source of All Land Disputes
Every case of dispute, corruption and illegality in the land sector is
centered on the assignment of LURs. LURs, or property rights in land, are the
ultimate goal of land buyers and a prerequisite for all investment projects;
therefore, the assignment of LURs becomes the source of all land disputes,
power abuses and corruption. At this stage, major types of illegal land-use
behaviors involve encroachment of land without approval and unlawful
approval of land, which accounts for a dominant fraction of illegally-used land
areas. There were several scenarios where illegal occupancies and approval of
land are induced by the restriction of LURs.
Firstly, encroachment of land without approval, in which land is taken
27
For a recent report on illegal land use by National Audit Office, see China Daily (2010,
April 21), ―Audit catches illegal land use.‖ source:
http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/china/2010-04/21/content_9755534.htm.
28
The Land Administration Law has permitted local states to keep 70% of land leasing fees
to finance urban infrastructure and agricultural industry, with the remaining 30% to the central
government.
98
for construction of buildings or projects without official titling of LURs, may
occur due to the complex and time-consuming procedures of assigning LURs.
Profit-making opportunities do not go on forever in the real estate market, and
good locations face fierce competition from multiple developers. Tender,
auction and quotation modes make the land titling process even more lengthy
and complicated. Hence, dishonest developers may illegally grab the location
by building houses on the land where LURs are not yet granted. The
authorization to seize land is often issued by individual government officials
who have close guanxi networks with the developers. 29 Alternatively,
unlawful approval of LURs occurs because of local authorities‘ incentives to
attract investors. Even though an investment project does not meet general
legal requirements such as pollution control, energy saving or relocation of
residents, local authorities still give the go-ahead for the projects because of
the potential contribution to local taxation and GDP growth. Under the
protection of local authorities, these projects are often run for years without
official possession of LURs.
In the third scenario, expensive tender, auction and quotation channels
of obtaining urban state-owned land encourage land buyers to directly
approach rural collectives to obtain discounted rural land parcels. The
ambiguous concept of property rights is a popular explanation to illegal land
transference by rural collectives (Ho, 2001; Lin & Ho, 2005; Zhang, 2006). I
29
Interview with one real estate developer on November 23, 2010.
99
would add to the literature by identifying the inefficient and unfair land titling
institutions in the following. According to current Land Administration Law,
rural land has to be transformed from peasants‘ collective ownership to urban
state ownership before it can be utilized for construction, rural collectives on
behalf of peasants are not authorized to grant LURs to developers. However,
this institutional design has complicated land supply procedures, distorted
demand and supply mechanism, and created inequalities between rural and
urban areas. Rural land is forbidden to enter the market; instead, it is forcibly
taken by the state with low compensation, and rural collectives are denied to
share the profits of burgeoning real estate industry. The incentives to capture
profits make behind-the-scenes interactions frequently take place between
rural collectives and commercial users. As a result, rural land is often
converted without going through state expropriation process, thus creating
black markets (Zhu, 1999; Ho & Lin, 2003). This often constitutes two types
of land law violations: developers‘ illegal occupancy of land without approval
and rural collectives‘ unlawful approval of LURs.
Legal Loopholes of Market-Led Land Supply System
Effective land administration requires a sound legal system to ensure
rules and regulations are enforced and violations are prohibited. What is
missing is the supervision and monitoring function within the land
management regime. The Land Administration Law has delegated power to
100
the local land administration bureaus to supervise and penalize illegal
behaviors within the land sector. However, the bureau is constantly trapped in
a dilemma in daily supervision. Firstly, many of the legal violations are
committed from within, and it is unlikely that the officers would be able to
effectively monitor, investigate or penalize for their infractions. Secondly, the
enforcement of anti-corruption laws by local land administration bureau is
limited due to its subordinate status to local governments. According to
Article 70 of Land Administration Law, land administration organs shall
impose administrative punishments upon individuals, organizations, and
government bodies that have violated land laws. However, the author‘s
interviews with local land monitoring officials suggest that only individual
land users and social organizations are penalized for misuse of land resources,
while state organs that permit or initiate illegal land deals are kept from
supervision and penalty.30 Even if local governments‘ misbehaviors surface,
political and administrative interference can come to their rescue. Local
government officers can often elude prosecution and let the land
administration officials be punished. Worse yet, the land inspectors who adopt
a hard line in cracking down on local governments‘ illegal behaviors will be
penalized or privately dismissed from their jobs.31
Above situation is deeply rooted in the institutional arrangement of the
land management apparatus. Wu, Xu and Yeh (2007) described the land
30
31
Interview with a local official on November 22, 2010.
Interview with a local official on November 22, 2010.
101
management structure in the reform era: local land administration organs are
territorially under the control of local governments and vertically subordinated
to land administration organs at a higher level. Yet, the dual leadership is
asymmetrical, as local governments have a stronger voice than the
administration officers in charge of local land affairs, even though they are
higher on the hierarchy. Vertical leadership is weaker than horizontal control
because land inspection agencies are subordinate to the local governments,
who decide on fiscal allocation and cadre appointment in land departments.
On the other hand, higher-level land agencies have no financial or political
connections with their subordinates except technical guidance (yewu zhidao).
This structural weakness of local land administration organs has resulted in
their inability to implement anti-corruption policies effectively; the fear of
retaliation might stop them from initiating any investigation or exposing any
penalty upon local executive leaders.
The failure of horizontal inspection organizations to deter land
corruption has stimulated the recentralization of the land management system.
In 2004, State Land Supervision System (guojia tudi ducha xitong or SLS)
was created and nine regional SLS offices (Beijing, Shenyang, Shanghai,
Nanjing, Jinan, Guangzhou, Wuhan, Chengdu and Xian) were set up,
independent of local land administration bureaus at the various levels. 32 Each
32
See ―Guowuyuanbangongting Guanyu Jianli Guojiatudiduchazhidu Youguanwenti De
Tongzhi‖ [―Notice of the General Office of the State Council on Creating State Land
Supervision‖], http://www.gov.cn/xxgk/pub/govpublic/mrlm/200803/t20080328_32520.html.
102
SLS office supervises land use activities in several provinces. SLS offices are
administratively led by the Ministry of Land and Resources under the auspices
of the State Council, and are superior to provincial governments. For instance,
the jurisdiction of the Shanghai office includes three provinces (Shanghai,
Zhejiang, Fujian) and two cities (Ningbo and Xiamen). SLS inspectors are
placed in charge of two main tasks: to enforce farmland protection quotas
signed between the central government and various local governments, and to
supervise land market transactions and punish local officials who violate
existing rules (Su, 2008).
SLS is distinguished from existing land administration system in that it
exerts supervision and sanctions independently, and no local authority
(including governments at the provincial, municipal, county and township
levels) can intervene in the investigation process. The central ministry
appoints and pays the SLS inspectors, requiring them to be accountable to the
centre instead of the localities in ensuring that central land policies are strictly
implemented. SLS represents a vertically controlled land administration
system with enhanced top-down monitoring.
Despite this, the SLS is not free from problems. Local scholar Zhu
(2007) argued that the newly created SLS is unable to solve the fundamental
problems of China‘s land management system. Firstly, the responsibilities of
SLS offices are not clearly distinguished from that of the existing land
inspection departments. The overlapping authorities and responsibilities may
103
lead to ineffective land management. Secondly, similar to China‘s audit office,
and despite its high status in the administrative hierarchy, the SLS is an
internal supervision system within the land sector, and is unable to function
independently or to effectively deter land corruption. In addition, SLS only
interacts with the provincial level government and is unable to coordinate
supervision activities at the municipal, county and township levels, as vertical
leadership is still weak. Yu and Yu (2008) further pointed out that
SLS-initiated investigations have to rely on local land administration organs
which are directly controlled by local government; hence, it is doubtful that
statistics submitted to SLS by land administration organs truly reflect illegal
land use activities in localities. The author‘s fieldwork experience supports the
view the SLS authority is unable to reach the grassroots level where land
lawbreaking happens most frequently.
33
Established amidst a weak
institutional environment and equipped with limited political resources, the
special vertical inspection agency SLS is inadequate to curb land corruption
and to ensure the land policies are implemented in a transparent and effective
fashion.
33
Interview with local land administration official on November 22, 2010.
104
Figure 9. Relations between Land Inspection System and Local
Authorities
Above figure shows complex relations between land inspection
agencies and local authorities. It is observed that the inferior status of local
land administration organs has jeopardized its effectiveness in supervising and
punishing illegal land use activities undertaken by local governments. The
inspection of SLS, although directly exposed on provincial governments, is
unable to reach municipal, county and grassroots levels. To sum up, neither of
the two inspection organs has the authority to challenge local governments
and coordinate their efforts to combat land corruption effectively. In addition,
the inspection loopholes in current land sector have led to insufficient
sanctions on corrupt officials. The following table presents the number of
illegal land use cases and disposal of violations in accord with party
105
disciplines and criminal law between 1999 and 2008.
Table 11. Penalties on Land Corruption
Year
Illegal
Illegally-
Land
Land leasing
Fines
Disciplinary
Criminal
land-use
used land
withdrawn
fees
(10,000
or
Penalty
case
(hectare)
(hectare)
(10,000
RMB)
administrative
RMB)
penalty
5143295
773
39
1999
153526
28100
2000
172623
30483
3112
5955848
71471
622
49
2001
116010
24052
3134
12958896
65036
815
107
2002
112515
28036
3396
24167925
95354
1223
168
2003
128125
55897
5883
54213112
120456
925
132
2004
85176
70171
6346
64121759
191191
977
65
2005
80427
42989
6993
58838170
217574
1044
199
2006
96133
84082
11596
80776447
345021
3094
501
2007
95937
89847
8608
122167208
336803
2925
474
2008
60399
46672
6192
102597987
216525
3094
501
Source: China Land and Resources Almanac 2000-2009
Note: the numbers of ―Land Withdrawn‖ and ―Fines‖ in 1999 are missing; the data of 1998 is
not obtainable.
The number of officials receiving disciplinary or criminal punishment
for charges of land corruption is extremely small, as shown in Table 11. For
instance, only seven officials were criminalized for land corruption in each
province in 2008. Each year, about 10% of illegally-used land is withdrawn.
Compared with the land leasing fees, the amounts of fines charged on illegal
land-use activities are extremely small, accounting for less than 1% of total
land leasing fees in most years. As many illegal land-use behaviors escape
detection, the risk of receiving monetary or non-monetary sanctions on
land-law violations is extremely small, while potential benefits are huge. As
106
such, the current legal system fails to prevent local officials from engaging in
abusive and corrupt land-use activities. A prerequisite for the market-oriented
land reforms is a well-designed supervision function that is free from political
and executive interference, which is not observed in China‘s land sector.
Summary
This chapter discusses and explains the regression results using an
institutional approach. The failure in current market-led land supply system to
reduce corruption is explained by the legal and institutional loopholes in land
administration regime, as well as structural factors rooted in China‘s economic
and political landscape. The occurrence of corruption in the land sector is
shaped by the dynamical interactions between land market and local political
economy. Firstly, the rapid development of land market is coupled with poorly
designed institutions, which generates risks of corruption. Secondly, a lack of
parallel supervisory and sanction mechanisms in land management system
make land-law violations difficult to control. Thirdly, central-local contentions
in the reform-era have encouraged policy distortion in localities. In conclusion,
a clearly defined institution is a precondition for the successful operation of
land market. Marketization and reduction of state intervention should be
carried out in a good institutional environment that ensures transparency,
accountability, and rule of law; institutional malfunctions make land sector
vulnerable to land abuses and corruption.
107
Chapter 6
Conclusion and Limitations of this Research
This chapter summarizes the findings of empirical studies in previous
chapters. The contributions and limitations of this research will be addressed,
and suggestions for future study are provided as well. In the policy arena,
recommendations are made to enhance the integrity and accountability in
China‘s land management system.
Summary of this Study
This thesis has sought to illuminate how institutional changes in urban
land allocation regime affect corruption. With the rapid process of
urbanization and industrialization, land becomes an important vehicle for local
governments to regulate economy and to accumulate capital; however,
opportunities for land disputes and land corruption abound. This thesis began
by noting the importance of land management and seriousness of land
corruption in China. Then it traced the history of China‘s urban land reforms
in recent decades to identify the research questions and hypotheses of this
study. With an objective to curb corruption, the central government introduced
a market-led urban land supply system—urban land used for profit-making
purposes shall be leased via tender, auction or quotation methods, while
administrative and negotiation methods of land allocation in the earlier periods
108
were significantly reduced. Tender, auction and quotation methods are
believed to be more transparent and fair than administrative and negotiated
allocations which are subject to heavy state control; therefore, they are
expected to prevent corruption from its source. Regardless of the expansion of
market forces, one important question remains: to what extent has the
objective of tackling corruption been achieved through the use of tender,
auction and quotation? To answer this research question, this paper used
random-effects panel model to analyze a set of provincial level data between
1998 and 2008. It found that tender, auction and quotation modes have made
no contributions to corruption-control in China‘s land sector. Based on the
regression results, this paper thoroughly investigated the institutional and legal
loopholes in current urban land supply system to explain the failure of tender,
auction and quotation in tackling corruption. The theoretical and practical
contributions of this research are as follows:
1. The first theoretical implication is the limited role of the market
mechanisms in deterring corruption. Introduction of market mechanisms in
urban land allocation does not necessarily reduce corruption. As shown in
the descriptive analysis, land abuses have intensified in recent decades
with regard to the amount of illegally-used land areas. Particularly, land
abuses have progressed after the tender, auction and quotation modes were
adopted in 2002. The market-led land supply modes have failed to
effectively address land abuses and corruption. China‘s farmland
109
continues to shrink, and misuse of land is still alarming. This finding is
further confirmed by the regression analysis that tender, auction and
quotation modes have no statistically significant impact on either
occurrence or severity of illegal land-use activities. This finding seems to
challenge the central government‘s policy rationale that market-led land
supply modes are able to reduce state intervention thus to curb corruption.
It also appears to contradict the conventional wisdom of public choice
school that market is more efficient and corruption-free than state.
However, we can find that local states remain an active role in leading and
influencing land market via procedural manipulation by probing into the
designing and implementation of market mechanisms. The retreat of local
governments from marketplace is not genuine and there is no clear
boundary between the public and private sphere. Under this ambiguity,
market mechanisms are distorted and manipulated by local corrupt
officials for self-enrichment.
2. The second implication of this research is that without well-designed
institutions, the market-led paradigm fails to create a clean and effective
urban land market. The paradoxical nature of new land supply policy is
deeply rooted in the legal and institutional loopholes of the new land
supply regime. Current institutional design has produced numerous risk
factors of corruption in urban land assignment, such as manipulation of
land use information and land leasing modes, distortion of land prices,
110
collusion between bureaucrats and land buyers, mismanagement of
land-related revenues and so forth. These risk factors have made the
implementation of tender, auction and quotation subject to bribery,
favoritism, nepotism, cheating and fraud. Furthermore, China‘s land
management is also plagued by insufficient legislations and weak law
enforcement. Detections and penalties on illegal land-use behaviors are
insufficient due to executive and political interference. In this
circumstance, land corruption becomes increasingly difficult to control.
3.
Finally, this research confirms the general perception that local
governments‘ financial dependence on land deals breeds corruption within
state agencies. As a result of market-oriented land reform, capitalization
on land has encouraged irrational and illegal land grabbing in localities. In
the battle of grasping fiscal resources, local governments often choose to
manipulate even distort central land policies to reap the considerable
amount of land revenues. The deviant and disobedient behaviors of local
governments are often connected with violations of law, abuse of power
and corruption.
Limitations of this Research and
Suggestions for Future Study
The issue of corruption in China is still alarming and yet to be
addressed effectively. The land sector remains to be one of the most corrupt
111
economic areas in China, and public dissatisfaction on the soaring prices of
land and houses is escalating throughout the country. A thorough investigation
of the urban land supply mechanism and local government behaviors in land
market is necessary to understand the overall economic reform and social
contentions in China. Given the unavailability of land corruption data, we can
only measure land corruption indirectly in this study. Measuring the level of
corruption in land sector is inherently difficult because of conceptual and
methodological reasons. So far, there are no systematic data on land
corruption available in either official documents or scholarly works. The
illegal land-use behaviors disclosed by the Ministry of Land and Resources
are closely related to corruption, because many illegalities appear to have
governmental involvement or support; however, some behaviors may not
constitute abuses or corruption, for peasants and urban residents are equally
responsible for land abuses as well. Therefore, the measurement of land
corruption in this study may result in some biases. A second limitation of this
research concerns the incorporation of independent variables. Omitted
variable bias is difficult to control and remedy, particularly as the selection of
explanatory variables is not free of risks; thus, the accuracy of regression
estimation has to be improved. Thirdly, the causal inference of this research is
drawn from a narrow examination of the institutional and legal loopholes in
new land supply regime; however, analysis of institutions should go beyond
the land sector to incorporate broader state apparatus. The roles played by the
112
party‘s anticorruption agencies, procuratorates and courts should be analyzed
as well. Finally, since there is a distinction between urban and rural land
policies, this research focuses on corruption in urban land market; while abuse
of power in rural land management is equally severe, integration of the two
systems would be a massive yet meaningful undertaking to comprehend the
full picture of land issue in China. Future studies could perhaps look at
comparative land abuses in rural and urban areas.
Policy Implications
Addressing corruption in the land sector is extremely important in
contemporary China. Firstly, corruption in land management has resulted in
substantial capital loss to the central government, as local authorities often
undervalue land so as to attract investors. Secondly, the misuse of land,
particularly the loss of scarce arable land resources, is threatening national
food security and citizens‘ wellbeing. Thirdly, corruption related to land is
encroaching on citizens‘ trust in governments and offering a source of social
conflicts and political instability. Because of these reasons, continuous and
sincere efforts should be made to address the land corruption issue. The
findings in this research provide valuable policy implications to the
government on how to enhance accountability and integrity in land
management.
113
Firstly, institutional qualities in current land management regime need
to be improved to accommodate the rapid development of land and property
market. Current transitional LURs appropriation mechanisms and institutions
may not provide sufficient guidelines for the effective operation of land
market. The examination of the land supply procedures in Chapter 5 has
highlighted the institutional loopholes in land allocation process. Municipal
leaders need better land management tools to enhance professionalism in the
land allocation process, such as the evaluation of land prices, selection of land
allocation mode, compensation and relocation of residents, and assessment of
bidders‘ documents.
Perhaps the most important and urgent policy implication of this
research is the protection of property rights. Because of the ambiguous
definitions of urban land use rights and rural collective land ownership, we
observe the prevalence of the forced demolition of urban residents‘ private
properties and abuse of rural land expropriation rights. To solve this problem,
policy makers should be aware that urban residents and rural peasants are de
facto land owners, rather than local government officials and village
committee cadres. De facto land owners should be invited to participate in
land use decision-making process to oversee government activities on land use.
Local governments are obligated to publicize information on urban planning
and land allocation in a quick and comprehensive manner so that incentives to
obtain information through bribery can be reduced.
114
Corruption occurs when there is a monopoly of power and a lack of
accountability. The central government has made constant efforts to break
local government‘ monopoly of land use, as evident in the promotion of tender,
auction and quotation modes. However, this initiative requires substantial
implementation costs with unsatisfactory gains in the absence of institutions
enforcing accountability. The accountability enforcement does not simply
mean more control and monitoring. In contrast, the transition from
authoritarian nature of the Party-state to progress towards democracy can be a
long term and necessary solution.
The final implication concerns the reconstruction of central-local
relations in the domain of land administration. The central government has
centralized inspection and sanction functions to deter illegal land use activities
more effectively. However, it seems that the centralized land inspection
system—SLS—does not gain many achievements in supervising local
governments. SLS is subject to local party and governmental intervention, it
also has to rely on existing local land inspection organs to fulfill its targets.
One important question arises from this analysis: how to reconcile the
conflicts between the center and localities to make local governments
accountable in land management? Perhaps the answer lies in the financial and
tax reforms. As existing literature illustrates, the tax reform in 1994 has
resulted in fiscal recentralization (Ko and Zhi, 2011) and a lack of sufficient
financial resources in localities. The fact that financial motives encourage
115
illegal and abusive land use activities has been verified by regression analysis
in chapter 4 of this research. The center needs to reconstruct current tax
system to expand the sources of local fiscal revenues. In the mean time, local
governments should diversify their revenue sources by shifting from land
market to more productive industrial sectors. The transformation of revenue
collection pattern in local China would be an essentially important yet
challenging task to the Chinese government.
In conclusion, this study has made active endeavors to enhance public
awareness of land corruption in China. Empirical analysis allows for a better
understanding of the dynamics behind market-oriented land reforms and
corruption. This research reports that market forces are not necessarily
coupled with transparency, fairness, and low level of corruption.
Comprehensive reforms focusing on preventing institutional loopholes should
be undertaken to improve the quality of land management institutions so as to
protect scarce land resources.
116
References
Arozamena, L., & Weinschelbaum, F. (2009). The effect of corruption on
bidding behavior in first-price auctions. European Economic Review,
53(6), 645-657.
Borras, S. M. (2003a). Questioning market-led agrarian reform: experiences
from Brazil, Colombia and South Africa. Journal of Agrarian Change,
3(July), 367-394.
Borras, S. M. (2003b). Questioning the pro-market critique of state-led
agrarian reforms. The European Journal of Development Research,
15(2), 109-132.
Burguet, R., & Perry, M. K. (2007). Bribery and favoritism by auctioneers in
sealed-bid auctions. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 7(1),
Article 23.
Cai, H., Henderson, J. V., & Zhang, Q. (2009). China's land market auctions:
evidence of corruption. National Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper. Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w15067
Cao, G., Feng, C., & Tao, R. (2008). Local "land finance" in China‘s urban
expansion: challenges and solutions. China & World Economy, 16(2),
19-30.
Celentani, M., & Ganuza, J. J. (2002). Corruption and competition in
procurement. European Economic Review, 46(7), 1273-1303.
Chow, G. C. (2006). Corruption and China's economic reform in the early 21st
century. International Journal of Business, 11(3), 265-282.
Compte, O., Lambert-Mogiliansky, A., & Verdier, T. (2005). Corruption and
competition in procurement auctions. The RAND Journal of
Economics, 36(1), 1-15.
Deininger, K. (1995). Collective agricultural production: a solution for
transition economies? World Development, 23(8), 1317-1334.
Deininger, K. (2003). Land policies for growth and poverty reduction.
Washington, DC: World Bank Publications.
Deininger, K., & Binswanger, H. (1999). The evolution of the World Bank‘s
117
land policy: principles, experience and future challenges. The World
Bank Research Observer, 14(2), 247-276.
Del Monte, A., & Papagni, E. (2007). The determinants of corruption in Italy:
regional panel data analysis. European Journal of Political Economy,
23(2), 379-396.
Deng, F. F. (2003a). China's urban land reform, urban productivity, and local
government behavior. Eurasian Geography and Economics, 44(3),
210-227.
Deng, F. F. (2003b). Political economy of public land leasing in Beijing,
China. In S. C. Bourassa & Y. Hong (Eds.), Leasing public land:
political debates and international experiences (pp. 229-250).
Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Deng, X., Zhang, L., & Leverentz, A. (2009). The dual system of land use
policy and its related problems in contemporary China. In J. Hsu & R.
Hasmath (Eds.), China in an era of transition: understanding
contemporary state and society actors (pp. 79-102). New York, NY:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Deng, X., Zhang, L., & Leverentz, A. (2010). Official corruption during
China's economic transition: historical patterns, characteristics, and
government reactions. Journal of Contemporary Criminal Justice,
26(1), 72-88.
Ding, C. (2001). The benchmark land price system and urban land use
efficiency in China. Chinese Geographical Science, 11(4), 306-314.
Ding, C. (2002). Land policy reform in China: assessment and prospects. Land
Use Policy, 20(2), 109-120.
Dong, B., & Torgler, B. (2010). The causes of corruption: evidence from
China. Queensland University of Technology, School of Economics
and
Finance
Working
Paper
Series.
Retrieved
from
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1628107
Drury, A. C., Krieckhaus, J., & Lusztig, M. (2006). Corruption, democracy,
and economic growth. International Political Science Review / Revue
internationale de science politique, 27(2), 121-136.
Du, X., Huang, Z., & Wu, C. (2009). China land fiscalization and economic
growth: Based on provincial panel data analysis. Finance and Trade
118
Ecnomics, 1, 60-64.
Gerring, J., & Thacker, S. C. (2005). Do neoliberal policies deter political
corruption? International Organization, 59(1), 233-254.
Goel, R. K., & Nelson, M. A. (1998). Corruption and government size: a
disaggregated analysis. Public Choice, 97(1/2), 107-120.
Gong, T. (1997). Forms and characteristics of China's corruption in the 1990s:
change with continuity. Communist and Post-Communist Studies,
30(3), 277-288.
Gong, T. (2002). Dangerous collusion: corruption as a collective venture in
contemporary China. Communist and Post-Communist Studies, 35,
85-103.
Gong, T. (2006). Corruption and local governance: the double identity of
Chinese local governments in market reform. The Pacific Review,
19(1), 85-102.
Guo, Y. (2008). Corruption in transitional China: an empirical analysis. The
China Quarterly, 194(1), 349-364.
Guo, Y. R. (2008). Land questions under central and local fiscal competition:
Based on the analysis of the economics literature. Comparative
Economic & Social Systems, 2, 59-64.
Herzfeld, T., & Weiss, C. (2003). Corruption and legal (in)effectiveness: an
empirical investigation. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3),
621-632.
Ho, P. (2001). Who owns China's land? Policies, property rights and
deliberate institutional ambiguity. The China Quarterly, 166, 394-421.
Ho, P. (2005). Institutions intTransition: land ownership, property rights, and
social conflict in China. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Ho, P., & Spoor, M. (2006). Whose land? The political economy of land
titling in transitional economies. Land Use Policy, 23(4), 580-587.
Ho, S. P. S., & Lin, G. C. S. (2003). Emerging land markets in rural and urban
China: Policies and Practices. The China Quarterly, 175, 681-707.
Husted, B. W. (1999). Wealth, Culture, and Corruption. Journal of
119
International Business Studies, 30(2), 339-359.
Kaufmann, D. (1998). Research on corruption: critical empirical issues. In
Arvind K. Jain (Ed.), Economics of Corruption (pp. 129-176). Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers.
Knox, C. (2009). Dealing with sectoral corruption in Bangladesh: developing
citizen involvement. Public Administration and Development, 29,
117-132.
Ko, K., & Zhi, H. (2011). Fiscal decentralization: guilty of aggravating
corruption in China? Paper presented at the Joint Conference of the
Association for Asian studies & International Convention of Asia
Scholars, Hawaii, USA.
Koc, S. A., & Neilson, W. S. (2008). Interim bribery in auctions. Economics
Letters, 99(2), 238-241.
Laffont, J.-J., & Tirole, J. (1991). Auction design and favoritism. International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 9(1), 9-42.
Lahiff, E. (2006). State, market or the worst of both? Experimenting with
market-based land reform in Southern Africa. Paper presented at the
International Conference on Land, Poverty, Social Justice and
Development, Institute of Social Studies, The Hague.
Koc, S. A., & Neilson, W. S. (2006). Bribing the auctioneer in first-price
sealed-bid auctions. Discussion paper. Texas A&M University.
Lessmann, C., & Markwardt, G. (2009). One size fits all? Decentralization,
corruption, and the monitoring of bureaucrats. World Development,
38(4), 631-646.
Liang, R. (2009). Promotion incentives, departmental interests and land
lawbreaking under fiscal decentralization. China Economic Quarterly,
9(1), 283-306.
Lin, G. C. S. (2009). Developing China: land, politics and social conditions.
New York, NY: Routledge.
Lin, G. C. S., & Ho, S. P. S. (2005). The state, land system, and land
development processes in contemporary China. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers, 95(2), 411-436.
120
Lin, Z. (2009). Administrative corruption and anti-corruption in land
development projects. Legal Science, 1, 29-34.
Liu, A. P. L. (1983). The politics of corruption in the People's Republic of
China. The American Political Science Review, 77(3), 602-623.
Liu, H., Zhang, Z., & Ma, K. (2008). Woguo tudi caizheng shouru yanjiu
zongshu. Research on Development, 1, 141-144.
Lu, X. (2000). Booty socialism, bureau-preneurs, and the state in transition:
organizational corruption in China. Comparative Politics, 32(3),
273-294.
McAfee, R. P., & McMillan, J. (1992). Bidding rings. The American
Economic Review, 82(3), 579-599.
Menezes, F. M., & Monteiro, P. K. (2006). Corruption and auctions. Journal
of Mathematical Economics, 42(1), 97-108.
Nawaz, F. (2008). Corruption in land administration / land management in
Kosovo.
U4
Expert
Answer.
Retrieved
from
http://www.u4.no/helpdesk/helpdesk/query.cfm?id=175
Nguyen, N. A., Nguyen, D. N., Tran, T. T., Prickett, K., & Phan, T. V. (2010).
Survey report on information disclosure of land management
regulations. Washington, DC: World Bank.
North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic
performance. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for
collective action. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
Pereira, J. M. M. ( 2007). The World Bank‘s ‗market-assisted‘ land reform as
a political issue: evidence from Brazil (1997-2006). European Review
of Latin American and Caribbean Studies, 82(April), 21-49.
Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern
Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Qian, Z. (2007). Institutions and local growth coalitions in China's urban land
reform: The case of Hangzhou high-technology zone. Asia Pacific
Viewpoint, 48(2), 219-233.
Qiu, S. (2006). Tudi paimai yu guapai churang de yingxiang fenxi. China Real
121
Estate Market, 10, 76-80.
Rijckeghem, & Weber. (1997). Corruption and the rate of temptation. Do low
wages in the civil service cause corruption? International Monetary
Fund
Working
Paper
97/73.
Retrieved
from
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.cfm?sk=2246.0
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978). Corruption: a study in political economy. New
York, NY: Academic Press.
Rose-Ackerman, S. (2008). Corruption and Government. International
Peacekeeping, 15(3), 328 – 343.
Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 108(3), 599-617.
Strong, A. L. (2003). Tenure choices for urban land privatization in Ukraine:
the role of leasehold. In S. C. Bourass & Y. Hong (Eds.), Leasing
public land: policy debates and international experience (pp. 179-210).
Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
Tanzi, V. (1998). Corruption around the world: causes, consequences, scope,
and cures. Staff Papers - International Monetary Fund, 45(4),
559-594.
Tao, K., Zhang, M., & Li, L. (2010). Market reform and illegal action:
evidence from China's land lawbreaking. Nankai Economic Studies, 2,
28-43.
Transparency International. (2009). Global Corruption Barometer 2009.
Berlin: Transparency International.
Transparency International. (2010). National Corruption Perception Survey-TI
Pakistan
2010.
Retrieved
from
http://www.transparency.org.pk/pub/publications.php
Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal
of Public Economics, 76(3), 399-457.
Wedeman, A. (2004). The intensification of corruption in China. The China
Quarterly, 180, 895-921.
Wei, Y., & Zhao, M. (2009). Urban spill over vs. local urban sprawl:
entangling land-use regulations in the urban growth of China's
122
megacities. Land Use Policy, 26(4), 1031-1045.
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: firms,
markets, relational contracting. New York, NY: Collier Macmillan.
Wong, K. K., & Zhao, X. (1999). The influence of bureaucratic behavior on
land apportionment in China: the informal process. Environmental and
Planning C: Government and Policy, 17(1), 113-126.
World Bank. (1993). China: urban land management in an emerging market
economy. Washington, DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (1997). Rural development: from vision to action–a sector
strategy. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2011). Recognizing and reducing corruption risks in land
management in Vietnam. World Bank Working Paper. Retrieved
from
http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/main?menuPK=64187510&pa
gePK=64193027&piPK=64187937&theSitePK=523679&entityID=00
0356161_20110125015439
Wu, F., Xu, J., & Yeh, A. G. O. (2007). Urban development in post-reform
China: state, market, and space. London, UK: Routledge.
Wu, Y. (2008). Fiscal decentralizaiton, corruption and governance. China
Economic Quarterly, 7(3), 231-233.
Xu, J., Yeh, A. G. O., & Wu, F. (2009). Land commodification: new land
development and politics in China since the late 1990s. International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 33(3), 890-913.
Yeh, A. G. O. (2005). Dual land market and spatial structure of cities. In L. J.
C. Ma & F. Wu (Eds.), Restructuring the Chinese city: changing
society, economy and space (pp. 59-79). New York, NY: Routledge.
Yeh, A. G. O., & Wu, F. (1996). The new land development process and
urban development in Chinese cities. International Journal of Urban
and Regional Research, 20(2), 330-353.
Yu, J., & Yu, J. (2008). Views on establishment process of land supervision
system in China. Resources and Industries, 10(1), 69-73.
Zhang, L., Xu, X., & Wang, X. (2011). Difang guanyuan hemou yu tudi weifa.
123
The Journal of World Economy 3, 72-88.
Zhang, X. (2006). Asymmetric property rights in China’s economic growth.
Paper presented at the session on "Land Rights and Social Security in
China" of the Annual American Economics Association Meetings,
Boston, MA.
Zhang, X. Q. (1997). Urban land reform in China. Land Use Policy, 14(3),
187-199.
Zhang, Y. (2002). Lianzheng jianshe zhi zhongdian--youganyu jingyingxing
tudi shiyongquan zhaobiao paimai guapai churang. Zhejiang Land &
Resources, 3, 4-6.
Zhou, L. A., & Tao, J. (2009). Government size, market-orientation and
regional corruption: Evidence from the provincial level panel data.
Frontiers of Economics in China, 4(3), 425-448.
Zhu, J. (1994). Changing land policy and its impact on local growth: the
experience of the Shenzhen Special Economic Zone, China, in the
1980s. Urban Studies, 31(10), 1611-1624.
Zhu, J. (1999). Local growth coalition: the context and implications of china‘s
gradualist urban land reforms. International Journal of Urban and
Regional Research, 23(3), 534-548.
Zhu, J. (1999). The transition of China's urban development: from
plan-controlled to market-led. Westport, CT: Praeger.
Zhu, Z. (2007). Tudi ducha nanyue zhidu xianjing. China Reform, 4, 74.
124
APPENDICES
Appendix A
Table A1 Sample Cases of Corruption in Land Sector
Name
Position
Liu
Deputy
Changgui
34
Crime
governor
of
Guizhou province
Penalty
From 1995 to 2000, Liu took 1,100,000 RMB and 11
years
US$30,000 bribes to help real estate companies imprisonment
obtain permits of land use and construction projects.
Du
Deputy party secretary
In 2003, Du was engaged in illegal land leasehold, Expelled
Shicheng
of Shangdong province
his son was involved in many construction projects party
and illegal land selling.
Chen
Aimin
Deputy
35
Yu Feili
36
Director
of
from
and
position
From 2002 to 2003, Chen helped one real estate 15
years
Department of Land and
company to obtain LURs through manipulating imprisonment
Resources of Jiangxi
quotation leasing mode.
Vice
From 1992 to 1993,Yu helped his daughter‘s Expelled
Chairman,
Standing Committee of
company get a piece of land at a low price, then his party
People's
daughter gained over 20,000,000 RMB profits from membership
Congress,
Guangdong province
Hu
Deputy
governor
Changqing
Jiangxi province
from
transferring the LURs.
of
Hu helped real estate companies to obtain LURs at Death penalty
much lower prices. In return, he accepted bribes that
were worth millions of RMB.
Cheng
Vice Chairman of the
From 1994 to 1997,Cheng allowed a piece of land to Death penalty
Kejie
NPC
be sold at a low price to a company, that company
Mu Suixin
Standing
Committee
also got construction projects under Cheng‘s help.
Mayor of Shenyang city,
Mu authorized land use licenses and reduced land tax Death penalty
Liaoning
and fees illegally.
Ma
Deputy
Mayor
Xiangdong
Shenyang city, Liaoning
developer free of charge.
Tian
President
In 1998,Tian worked together with Mu Suixin to
life
Fengqi
people‘s court, Liaoning
allocate a piece of land to a developer for free.
imprisonment
Wang
Deputy
From 1995 to 1997, Wang helped real estate
Huaizhong
Anhui province
of
of
superior
governor
of
Ma accepted bribes and allocated a piece of land to a Death penalty
companies
to
obtain land
and
reduced
land
conveyance fees.
34
Source: Zunyi Intermediate People‘s Court, ―Liu Changgui Fan Shouhui Zui He Ju E
Caichan Laiyuan Buming Zui Yian‖ [―Liu Changgui trialed for the crime of bribery and
unidentified huge property‖], http://data.jxwmw.cn/index.php?doc-view-91271
35
Source: the Xinhua News, ―Toushi Jiangxi Tudi Xitong Fubai Woan: Tudi Guanyuan
Quanli Shikong‖[― Probe into the organized corruption in land administration system in
jiangxi: land officials‘ power out of control‖], http://fanfu.people.com.cn/GB/11915422.html
36
The cases of Yu Feili, Hu Changqing, Cheng KeJie, Mu Suixin, Ma Xiangdong, Tian
Fengqi, Wang Ju, and Wang Huaizhong were recorded by Jian Li (2004), ―Guidelines of Land
Corruption Cases,‖ China Land, 4, 21-33.
125
Death penalty
Wang
Youjie
37
Vice director, Standing
From 1994 to 2005, Wang helped real estate
Committee of People's
developers obtain LURs and reduced relevant fees.
Death penalty
Congress, Henan
Wang
Yingfu
38
Jing
Fusheng
39
Liu
Zhihua
40
He Minxu
Deputy General Director
From 1999 to 2003,Wang helped a real estate Life
of Department of Land
company to obtain a piece of commercial land imprisonment
and
through administrative means, he also approved land
Resources
of
Ningxia Province
requisition and construction projects illegally.
Minister of Propaganda
From 1989 to 1995, Jing took 7660,000 RMB
Life
of Fujian province
bribes in land and projects approval.
imprisonment
Deputy Party secretary
Liu accepted over 8,000,000RMB bribes in land
Death penalty
of Beijing
leasing, projects approval, and cadre promotion.
From 2000 to 2004, He accepted bribes to illegally
Expelled
Anhui province
grant LURs and reduced relevant fees.
position
Wang
Vice director, Standing
From 1995 to 2006, Wang helped real estate and
Expelled
Wulong
Committee of People's
construction companies to obtained LURs and
party
Congress, Jiangsu
reduced land conveyance fees.
position
Director of Land and
From 2001 to 2007, Luo embezzled a large amount Death penalty
Resources
Bureau,
of land conveyance fees.
Shuncheng
district,
Luo
Yaping
41
Deputy
governor
of
from
from
and
Liaoning
Wang
42
Bin
Dai Min
43
Deputy director, Bureau
Wang accepted money and presents from real estate
12
of Land and Resources,
developers that were worth more than 1.7 million
imprisonment
Chongqing
RMB
Manager of Agricultural
In 2006, Dai took bribes and leaked the upset price of
10
Bank of China Dongfang
land auction to a company. Under Dai‘s instructions,
imprisonment
37
Source: Legal Daily, ―Yuan Zhengzhoushiwei Shuji Wang Youjie Woan: Tanguan Yilin
Jiushi Yichuan‖[― Organized corruption of former secretary of zhengzhou municipal party
committee Wang Youjie: officials participate in organized corruption‖],
http://qingyuan.people.com.cn/GB/14748/5433429.html
38
Source: Procuratorial Daily, ―Ningxia Tudiju Yuanjuzhang Wang Yingfu Chanhui Shouhui
Jingli‖[―Former head of Ningxia land administration bureau Wang Yingfu repented accepting
bribes‖], http://qingyuan.people.com.cn/GB/14748/5490458.html
39
Source: Procuratorial Daily, ―Fujiansheng Yuan Xuanchuanbuzhang Jing Fusheng 766 wan
Yishen Beipan Wuqi‖[―Former director of Jiangxi Publicity Department of provincial party
committees Jing Fusheng was sentenced to life imprisonment for accepting 7,660,000 RMB
as bribes‖], http://society.people.com.cn/GB/6272084.html
40
The source for cases of Liu Zhihua, Wang Wulong, Li Jinbao, Du Shicheng and He Minxu
is ―Yin Fangdichan Fubai Er Luoma De Shiwei Gaoguan‖ [―Ten high-level officials punished
on real estate corruption‖], http://news.nj.allfang.com/newshtml/2007-02/9844_1.html
41
Source: ―Luo Yaping: Tudi Nainai Ye Fengkuang‖[―Luo Yaping: greedy land official‖],
http://www.jcrb.com/zhuanti/fzzt/lps/renwu/tiaomu/201101/t20110107_487012.html
42
Source: Procuratorial Daily, ―Chongqing Yi Jituan Dongshizhang Zishe Xianjinshouhui
Menkan:Chao 10wan Bushou‖[―One board director in Chongqing municipality sets standard
for bribery: bribes over 100,000 RMB will be rejected‖],
http://qingyuan.people.com.cn/GB/14748/8817390.html
43
Source: ―Hainan Yuan Nonghang Dongfangshi Zhihang Hangzhang Shouhui Huoxing‖
[―Manager of Agricultural Bank of China Dongfang city branch trialed on accepting bribes‖],
http://finance.sina.com.cn/g/20101116/20348962720.shtml
126
years
years
city branch
Chen
Liangyu
Party
44
that company obtained LURs successfully.
secretary
of
Shanghai
Chen misappropriated Social Security Fund for 18
years
investment in real estate market, he also helped his imprisonment
younger brother to obtain land at low price.
Wu
Zhenhan
President
45
Wang
Zhaoyao
46
of
superior
From 1998 to 2003, Wu accepted bribes in granting
people's court, Hunan
construction projects.
Vice chairman, Standing
Around 2003, Wang helped real estate companies to
Committee of Jiangsu
get LURs and accepted bribes in return.
People's Congress
44
Source: Jinwang Huang, ―Chumu Jingxin De Tudi Fubai‖[―Land corruption shocks the
eye‖], http://www.chineseworkers.com.cn/_d271368875.htm
45
Source: Oriental Daily, ―Ruya Faguan Luoma: Hunangaoyuan Yuan Yuanzhang Wu
Zhenhan Beipan Sixing‖[―Former president of High People‘s Court of Hunan province was
sentenced to death‖], http://news.sina.com.cn/c/2006-11-15/014410498677s.shtml
46
Source: Democracy and Law, ―Wang Zhaoyao: Xiangzuo Tanbaicongkuan De
Dianxing‖[―Wang zhaoyao: confess and repent‖],
http://cpc.people.com.cn/GB/64093/64371/5149120.html
127
Death penalty
Death penalty
Appendix B
Table A2 Descriptive Statistics of All Variables
Variable
Landcase
Landarea
Dep
Mkt
Law
GDPpc
Wage
Govspend
Govemploy
Rei
Edu
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
overall
between
within
Mean
104.0846
1862.66
0.349633
0.195743
108.2586
13817.63
1.141619
0.197727
0.169167
0.068352
7.752545
Std. Dev.
87.03091
65.33989
58.45929
2600.415
1625.623
2050.351
0.293009
0.143274
0.25677
0.168861
0.081189
0.148471
93.2094
77.30262
53.7053
11532.24
9458.969
6793.531
0.131896
0.113384
0.070133
0.114153
0.101684
0.05473
0.110212
0.087646
0.068489
0.048037
0.041318
0.025507
1.177689
1.120915
0.409213
Min
4
33.81818
-83.3699
0.46
80.665
-2916.5
0.008
0.111364
-0.20018
0.001
0.047182
-0.17508
22.3506
46.34738
-83.1556
2342
4356.593
-5412.82
0.854
0.954273
0.860346
0.094
0.111455
-0.13045
0.03
0.053455
-0.08847
0.007
0.019091
-0.0341
2.948
3.967273
6.202727
Max
719
317.6
505.4846
21346.52
7894.271
19665.23
1.784
0.661818
1.536088
0.798
0.390818
0.687016
642.3915
366.3195
384.3305
73124
47483.45
40390.06
1.715
1.448273
1.408346
0.972
0.654182
0.892818
0.81
0.494636
0.603258
0.344
0.243909
0.168443
11.085
10.43936
8.552727
Observations
N=
319
n=
31
T-bar = 10.2903
N=
306
n=
31
T = 9.87097
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
331
n=
31
T-bar = 10.6774
N=
279
n=
31
T=
9
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
N=
341
n=
31
T=
11
128
Appendix C
Map A1 Map of China
Source: http://english.peopledaily.com.cn/china/images/map11.jpg. Accessed
on June 15, 2011.
129
[...]... to 2010; these are presented in Appendix A While these land corruption cases represent only the tip of the iceberg, they shed light on the forms and characteristics of corruption in the urban land sector; hence, a basic understanding of land corruption can be drawn from these cases As shown in Appendix A, the magnitude and severity of land- related corruption seem substantial Many land corruption cases... and redesigning the tender, auction and quotation system 16 Organization of This study The structure of this thesis is as follows: Chapter 2 presents the basis for understanding the manifestations and causes of corruption in China s land sector An operational definition of land corruption is provided, followed by a narrative report describing the forms and characteristics of land corruption based on. .. argue that official statistics only reflect the intensity of enforcement rather than the actual level of corruption Consequently, official land corruption statistics can provide a proper indicator of trends in the actual land corruption level The second limitation of the quantitative data is that these land- law violations do not equal to land corruption because some violations are committed by urban residents... 20 corruption scandals Existing literature on land corruption in global and domestic contexts is then reviewed The focal point of literature review is on the controversial relationship between market- led land supply system and corruption Chapter 3 identifies the research questions by tracing the transformation of China s urban land supply regime After analyzing the major characteristics of current land. .. improving land use efficiency and protecting land resources Additionally, this research goes beyond the land sector and situates the issue of land corruption within the broader context of the central-local relationship and the national legal environment and, hence, sheds light on the bigger picture of institutional reforms in contemporary China Furthermore, it would provoke future studies in the area of land. .. studies on land corruption in developing and transition economies One important implication is that land corruption occurs due to both sectoral and environmental factors Sectoral factors such as monopoly of land resources, discretion of land administration officials, qualities of land administration institutions, government accountability and transparency exert direct influence on the incidence of corruption. .. of Chinese Corruption , China Report 2004, 40, p.107 10 Interview with local land administration officials on November 18, 2010 23 forms of corruption in China s urban land sector The next section reviews current literature to understand why land corruption prevails in both global and national contexts Studies of Land Corruption in a Global Context Corruption is a phenomenon that exists in many economic... information on land corruption and anti -corruption policies First, public officials‘ knowledge and experience drawn from government positions are useful for understanding the implementation of land policies and anticorruption polices The selected public officials consists of two groups: one group come from land administration organizations representing experienced influential decision makers who demonstrate... reveals the various forms of corrupt practices in urban land supply, such as extracting bribes, stealing land- related revenues and violating land protection rules and so forth, adding to the body of knowledge on how corruption 15 actually operates in urban land management Secondly, this research project presents empirical evidence for the effects of market- led land supply regime on corruption in land management... time These fluctuations may affect the validity of regression results To address this problem, I integrate the variable of law enforcement in the regression analysis to ensure the fluctuations in official land corruption statistics are under control By controlling the variations of law enforcement, we can also control the gap between actual land corruption level and revealed land corruption level as many ... paid land leasing system and abandonment of free administrative allocation of land under the socialist land management system (Zhu, 1999b) The transformation from the state -led to market- led land. .. open land rental and sale market, decentralization of land administration institutions, conversion of land from rural to urban uses, and reduction of government control in land resources, and... 13 The laws and regulations on the transference of LURs include the Interim Regulations of the PRC Concerning the Assignment and Transfer of the Right to the Use of the State-owned Land in the