1. Trang chủ
  2. » Luận Văn - Báo Cáo

The effects of a RMB devaluation on ASEAN economies

20 305 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 20
Dung lượng 242,75 KB

Nội dung

The Effects of a RMB Devaluation on ASEAN Economies: An Applied General Equilibrium Approach By Robert R. Teh Jr. Director Trade, Industry and Services Introduction There is growing complexity in the economic relationship between ASEAN and China. On the one hand, China is a major competitor to ASEAN both as an investment destination and as a major producer of labour-intensive manufactures. But on the other hand, China’s maintenance of the renminbi during the height of the Asian crisis was a major reason why the crisis did not precipitate an even more devastating meltdown in the region. This paper examines the effect of a depreciation of the Chinese renminbi on the ASEAN economies, focusing in particular, on the resulting pattern of competitive advantage and effect on the market share of ASEAN economies in major export markets - US, the EU and Japan. To the extent that a devaluation of the renminbi serves as a proxy for the trade rivalry between ASEAN and China, the outcome of the simulation should provide some answers to the state of the economic relationship between them. Ever since the Asian crisis broke out in mid-1997, China's maintenance of the value of the renminbi has served as a regional anchor preventing what could possibly have been successive rounds of competitive devaluations. There was, however, an implicit trade-off being made by China - geo-political gain from maintaining the renminbi as against the loss of export markets, as much cheaper goods from the crisis-plagued region compete with Chinese goods. However, now as export performance stalls and as growth slows in China’s domestic economy, the cost of delaying the devaluation may be steadily rising. The threat of regional currency instability may have also ebbed with the beginning of economic recovery in the crisis countries, making it less likely that a renminbi devaluation would be followed by beggar-thy-neighbour responses elsewhere in the region. To provide a quantitative analysis of the likely impact of such a devaluation on the ASEAN economies, this paper uses the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model to simulate several devaluation scenarios. The first part of this paper describes the GTAP model and examines some of the difficulties involved in using applied general equilibrium models to simulate macroeconomic crises and devaluation scenarios. The second part of the paper describes the procedures employed to simulate the Asian crisis and subsequently the renminbi devaluation. The third part discusses the results of the simulation. The results suggest that while a renminbi devaluation only has a small effect on total ASEAN exports, there is substantial sectoral impact on ASEAN exports of textiles and apparel as well as other manufactures. This suggests that individual ASEAN countries may experience a significant negative impact since textiles and other manufactures are a bigger proportion of the trade of countries like Indonesia, the Philippines and Thailand. Furthermore, a renminbi devaluation has large spillover effects on Japan, which could precipitate competitive devaluation pressures on the rest of the region. Finally, it is also important to factor in the possible rise of protectionist sentiment in the US, which has experienced strained relations with China, and which suffers a large imbalance in the trade account in the face of a significant renminbi devaluation. The results of the simulations tend to support the view that while ASEAN and China compete directly in export markets and as investment destination, the degree of competition may be less than what conventional wisdom suggests. The last part of the paper suggests further extensions of the study. Maybe as a final caveat, it is important to note that this paper is focussed exclusively on the trade effects of a renminbi devaluation. It abstracts from issues of macroeconomic stability and adjustment and the resulting impact on foreign investors of a realistic realignment of China’s currency. To the extent that a renminbi devaluation is seen as a commercial response to deteriorating export performance, then the framework of the analysis conducted here is probably appropriate for the purpose on hand. But if the realignment of the currency is seen as part of a larger policy commitment to economic reform in China, and couple this with the likely accession of China to the WTO sometime in the year 2000, then this static analysis will likely underestimate the likely toll for ASEAN. As part of a larger package of reform measures, a renminbi devaluation could re-energise foreign investor interest in China and produce dramatic increases in economic efficiency and long-term export competitiveness that we would be unable to capture in the simulations conducted with the GTAP model. The GTAP Model To simulate the effects of a renminbi devaluation, this paper makes use of the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) model developed by Hertel and Associates and which is described in detail in Hertel 1997. The advantage of using this model is that it has been widely used for simulating a number of important global trade scenarios, such as a new round of WTO negotiations and global energy use and climate change. Hence it is already familiar to a large number of international trade economists and applied general equilibrium modellers and provides a widely shared platform for investigating international trade issues. Regional Household In each region, there is a regional household whose Cobb-Douglas preferences are defined over composite private expenditures, composite public sector expenditures and savings. The regional household derives income from ownership and sales of primary factors of production - capital, skilled and unskilled labour, land and natural resources. It turns out that the intertemporal, extended linear expenditure system could be derived from an equivalent, static maximisation problem, in which savings enters the utility function (Howe, 1975). This result provides a justification for the inclusion of savings in the regional utility function. Demand Private expenditures are governed by a Constant Difference of Elasticity (CDE) function which was first proposed by Hanoch (1975). The CDE function has the desirable property that the resulting preferences are not homothetic and is more parsimonious in its parameter requirements than functional flexible forms. It can also be shown that the CES and the Cobb-Douglas are special cases of the CDE function. Government expenditures are governed by a Cobb-Douglas preference function. Finally, there is inter-industry demand whose technical specifications are described by the usual input-output matrix. Production Production is assumed to be described by a multi-level production function (see Figure 1). The upper nest is a Leontief-type production function involving value added and intermediate inputs. The technical coefficients of this top-level nest are generated from the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) constructed for each region. Value added is produced through a Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) function of the five primary factors of production. Each intermediate input is in turn produced using domestic and imported components (the so-called Armington assumption) with the technical process described by a CES function. Finally, imported components are a mix of imports from the other regions in the global model with the technical process again described by a CES function. Households own all factor supplies - land, natural resources, capital, skilled and unskilled labor and sell their services to firms. In the GTAP model, sluggishness of some factors is allowed so that it is possible for factor prices not to be equalised within a region. Firms are supposed to sell output and purchase inputs (whether primary factors or intermediates) in competitive markets. Hence, firms make no economic profits. Prices and Taxes The GTAP model allows for factor taxes, production and consumption taxes, export taxes and import tariffs which are in turn distinguished by production sector, by agent (regional household, firm, government) and by region. Savings and Investment Given the Cobb-Douglas assumption about preferences of the regional household, savings are a constant proportion of regional household income. The pool of savings is what becomes available for investments. There is a capital goods sector in each region, which produces the investment goods. The rate of return on capital goods is assumed to be inversely related to the stock of capital. The allocation of investment across regions and sectors is done in such a way that expected regional rates of return change by the same percentage. In the model, the pooling of savings and the global allocation of investment is done costlessly. Aggregation We have used a smaller 9 region and 10-sector aggregation of the larger 45 region and 50-sector GTAP model. The data employed in the study is version 4 which uses 1995 data as the benchmark. The data is described in greater detail in McDougall, R. et al (1999). The 9 regions used in our simulation are ASEAN, the US, EU, Japan, China, Korea, Rest of Asia, the Common Economic Relations (CER) and the Rest of the World. The GTAP database does not include all ASEAN countries, and hence, ASEAN in this paper covers only Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand and Viet Nam. In this paper, "China" includes both the People's Republic of China (PRC) and Hong Kong. This reflects not only the political reality that Hong Kong is now part of the PRC but also the level of economic integration between Hong Kong and the PRC. It is important to highlight that the inclusion of Hong Kong with the PRC implies that the renminbi devaluation is also accompanied by a devaluation of the Hong Kong dollar by the same amount. Now the likelihood of Hong Kong abandoning its currency board increases with the size of the renminbi devaluation, in which case, lumping Hong Kong and the PRC together may make sense only for large devaluation scenarios. For small devaluations of the renminbi, therefore, this paper may tend to overstate the likely impacts. Other regions include the US, Japan and the EU which represent the biggest export markets of ASEAN and China. Korea is given particular attention because it is an important crisis country. The other three regions, which complete the aggregation employed in this paper are the Common Economic Relations comprised of Australia and New Zealand, Rest of Asia and the Rest of the World. The 10 sectors are food, vegetable oils and fats, other agricultural products, extractive industries, textiles, chemicals, electronics and machinery, motor vehicles, other manufactures and services. The particular aggregation employed highlights important sectors of interest to the ASEAN countries. The mapping from the 45 country and 50 sector grouping of GTAP to our 9x10 model appears in Annex 1. Simulating a Devaluation Applied general equilibrium models are "real" models of the economy in which monetary and financial variables do not enter. Hence macroeconomic variables are normally not integrated into AGE models and if they are, ad hoc methods are typically used to introduce macroeconomic shocks or variables into AGE models. There are several ways in which macroeconomic shocks can be introduced in applied general equilibrium models. One would be to impose the shocks exogenously by changing real prices or investment flows. Another procedure would be to build explicitly dynamic models that allow interaction between expectations and investments. In this paper, we take the first approach and shock the standard GTAP model by adjusting the real exchange rate. There are a number of possible prices in the GTAP model that could be used as the real exchange rate. The Armington assumption is usually made in AGE models, which implies, that foreign and domestic products are never perfectly substitutable. So to take an example, domestic food is not identical to foreign-produced food and hence, their prices will differ even in the absence of other taxes and tariffs. Hence, one possible real exchange rate to use would be the ratio of the index of exportable and importable prices. However, in the context of the GTAP model, a more useful price to shock in order to simulate the effect of a devaluation is the relative price of the country's factors of production. This is more consistent with the macroeconomic consequences of a nominal devaluation since the ultimate adjustment entails changes in the prices of factors of production. A nominal devaluation that is followed by an equi-proportionate increase in the prices of primary factors of production would have no real effects. Thus in the paper, we have simulated the renminbi devaluation and the Asian crisis devaluation with changes in the prices of primary factors of production. Baseline Scenario The benchmark year used for release 4 of the GTAP database is 1995. However, this is not what we want to use for our baseline scenario since we must start with the Asian crisis of 1997 and attempt to mimic the resulting outcomes. This is done by reducing prices of all primary factors in ASEAN and Korea by the same rate as the real devaluation of the currencies in those countries (see Table 1). While the devaluation of the ASEAN and Korean currencies have been enormous, ranging from 67% to 15%, the crisis-affected countries have also seen an appreciable change in prices eroding a significant amount of the currency devaluation. For example, while Indonesia has experienced a drop of nearly 67% in the value of the rupiah, price inflation ran at 61% in 1998 virtually wiping out any competitive edge gained from the currency depreciation. As a consequence, the real rate of depreciation for both ASEAN and Korea have been much lower. In the case of ASEAN the computed average rate of real devaluation is only about 14.3% while it is only 8.8% for Korea. TABLE 1 Nominal Devaluation and Rates of Inflation in ASEAN and Korea, 1997-99 REGION REGIONREGION REGION Nominal Nominal Nominal Nominal Devaluation DevaluationDevaluation Devaluation CPI CPI CPI CPI Inflation InflationInflation Inflation Real Real Real Real Devaluation DevaluationDevaluation Devaluation ASEAN 67.3% 80% 14.3% Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Singapore Thailand Vietnam 67.4% 33.6% 33.4% 14.9% 32.7% 21.2% 15.7% 1.7% 13.7% 10.9% -0.1% -25.6% -17.7% -13.2% -19.0% -10.3% Korea 20.7% 11.9% 8.8% Source: World Economic Outlook (May 1999). In the paper, the prices of all primary factors of production are reduced by the amount of real devaluation in each region. Prices of skilled and unskilled labor, capital, land and natural resources are reduced by 14.3% in ASEAN and by 8.8% in Korea. It would be preferable to have differential changes in factor prices since there is considerable evidence to suggest that the impact of the Asian crisis on unskilled labor was much more severe than to skilled workers or owners of land. However, we lack the detailed information on how factor prices have changed in each region and have therefore chosen to reduce them all by the same amount. There is also an important complication created by the way we have chosen to introduce the real devaluation in the GTAP model. Factor prices are made exogenous and reduced by the real devaluation experienced by the region. Accompanying the real devaluation, we have also added a shock to total factor productivity to mimic, among other things, the near collapse of the banking sector in the crisis-affected countries. While it is difficult to provide estimates of how much the banking crisis in Asia has affected the long-run growth potential of the region, it is important to take these supply shocks into account because they affect the short to medium term response of the producers in the crisis-affected countries. The output shock assumption has also been used in other AGE simulation of the Asian crisis. In this paper, we have made the productivity shocks equal to the actual GDP contraction experienced in ASEAN and Korea in 1998. This was equal to -5.5% for Korea while the GDP-weighted average for ASEAN was -4.3% (see Table 2). The output shock has the effect of dampening the export response to the initial real devaluation. This is consistent with one of the important stylised features of the Asian crisis, which saw exports in US dollar terms languish, despite the sharp fall in regional currencies. TABLE 2 Output Shock in ASEAN and Korea REGION REGIONREGION REGION GDP GROWTH GDP GROWTHGDP GROWTH GDP GROWTH ASEAN Indonesia -4.3% - 13 7% Malaysia Philippines Singapore Thailand Vietnam -6.8% -0.5% 1.5% -8.0% 3.5% Korea -5.5% Source: World Economic Outlook (May 1999). Baseline Measures of GDP and Export Performance The resulting global pattern of trade after the real devaluation and output shocks in ASEAN and Korea is our baseline scenario. We can compare this Asian Crisis baseline with the 1995 benchmark of the GTAP database. For Gross Domestic Product (GDP), we see that the Asian crisis simulation we have employed has probably understated the actual contraction in GDP experienced by the crisis countries. ASEAN’s GDP falls by 7.42% to US $ 568.0 billion while Korea’s GDP contracts by 16.2% to US $ 378.2 billion. This compares with the latest IMF estimates of 1998 GDP for the two regions concerned - US $ 446.6 billion for ASEAN and US $ 310.1 billion for Korea. The simulation also suggests that there is very little spillover effects of the Asian Crisis on other regional economies. One should probably not place too much weight on the lack of a contagion effect in the simulations since AGE models are real models and do not have a central role for financial variables. TABLE 3 Impact of Asian Crisis on Regional GDP (Simulation Result) REGION REGIONREGION REGION 1995 GDP 1995 GDP1995 GDP 1995 GDP CRISIS CRISISCRISIS CRISIS CHANGE IN GDP CHANGE IN GDPCHANGE IN GDP CHANGE IN GDP ASEAN 613,444.4 567,953.6 -7.42% USA 7,126,432.0 7,159,306.5 0.46% Japan 5,091,655.0 5,125,799.5 0.67% EU 8,209,777.0 8,250,170.0 0.49% China 813,366.7 815,950.1 0.32% Korea 451,163.3 378,228.3 -16.17% Rest of Asia 710,279.0 713,595.5 0.47% CER 405,301.8 404,579.6 -0.18% ROW 4,892,905.0 4,904,165.0 0.23% TOTAL TOTALTOTAL TOTAL 28,314,324.2 28,314,324.228,314,324.2 28,314,324.2 28,319,748.5 28,319,748.528,319,748.5 28,319,748.5 0 00 0.02% .02%.02% .02% Table 4 shows the world market share of all regions in the baseline scenario (Asian Crisis). ASEAN and China are still relatively small players in the world market with ASEAN representing 6.9% of world exports and China making up 5.0% of world exports. However, they are significant market participants in some important products. ASEAN is a major player in vegetable oils (20.9% of world exports) and other agricultural products (15.1% of world exports) while China has a huge share of textiles and apparel (17.9%) and a significant share of other manufactures (7.8%). Figure 2 shows the sectoral composition of ASEAN exports. More than a third of ASEAN exports are exports of electrical appliances and machinery; other major export sectors are other manufactures and services. FIGURE 2:SECTORAL COMPOSITION OF ASEAN EXPORTS TABLE 4 Baseline (Asian Crisis) Structure of World Exports In Per Cent (Simulation Result) SECTOR SECTORSECTOR SECTOR ASEAN ASEANASEAN ASEAN USA USAUSA USA Japan JapanJapan Japan EU EUEU EU China ChinaChina China Korea KoreaKorea Korea Rest Rest Rest Rest of of of of Asia AsiaAsia Asia CER CERCER CER ROW ROWROW ROW Food 7.20 12.80 0.50 43.30 2.30 0.70 3.00 4.80 25.40 Vegetable Oil 20.90 22.10 0.10 21.70 2.30 0.00 1.50 0.60 30.70 Other Agricultural Products 15.10 10.50 0.40 25.80 3.10 0.40 3.20 6.30 35.30 Extractive 8.00 3.30 0.30 12.00 1.60 0.10 1.90 4.00 68.80 Textiles and Apparel 7.40 5.00 2.90 33.10 17.90 3.90 11.40 0.40 17.90 Chemicals 4.80 12.00 6.10 49.40 2.50 1.80 2.70 0.90 19.80 Motor Vehicles 1.40 14.10 15.60 49.60 0.60 1.50 1.00 0.30 15.90 Electrical and Machinery 9.50 15.50 16.50 37.30 4.10 2.70 4.30 0.40 9.80 Other Manufactures 6.20 8.30 5.80 43.40 7.80 1.70 3.40 1.20 22.10 Services 6.60 17.50 5.40 40.80 5.90 2.10 1.60 1.70 18.30 Total TotalTotal Total 6.90 6.906.90 6.90 12.60 12.6012.60 12.60 8.50 8.508.50 8.50 39.80 39.8039.80 39.80 5.00 5.005.00 5.00 1.90 1.901.90 1.90 3.30 3.303.30 3.30 1.40 1.401.40 1.40 20.50 20.5020.50 20.50 Table 5 shows the market share of ASEAN and China in several key markets. ASEAN has a larger market share than China in the three markets, with the lead being most pronounced in the Japanese market. ASEAN exports have significant market share in food, vegetable oils, other agricultural products and electrical appliances and machinery. On the other hand, Chinese exports have significant market share in textiles and apparel and other manufactures. TABLE 5 Market Share of ASEAN and China in Selected Markets (Asian Crisis Simulation Result) SECTORS SECTORSSECTORS SECTORS USA USAUSA USA EU EUEU EU JAPAN JAPANJAPAN JAPAN ASEAN China ASEAN China ASEAN China Food 12.6% 2.4% 1.9% 0.5% 15.6% 8.2% Vegetable Oil 33.7% 0.3% 12.5% 1.2% 13.4% 5.6% Other Agricultural Products 26.6% 1.9% 7.5% 1.5% 26.4% 8.1% Extractive Industries 1.4% 1.0% 1.1% 0.6% 22.0% 3.7% Textiles & Apparel 12.9% 20.6% 4.2% 8.7% 9.4% 55.9% Chemicals 4.0% 4.6% 0.9% 1.3% 10.3% 6.0% Motor Vehicles 1.2% 0.8% 0.4% 0.1% 1.1% 1.3% Electrical and Machinery 15.2% 5.8% 4.1% 3.0% 21.0% 10.1% Other Manufactures 7.1% 15.0% 2.4% 4.1% 14.0% 17.2% Services 7.0% 9.6% 4.2% 3.2% 16.8% 7.4% TOTAL TOTALTOTAL TOTAL 8.8% 8.8%8.8% 8.8% 7.6% 7.6%7.6% 7.6% 2.9% 2.9%2.9% 2.9% 2.7% 2.7%2.7% 2.7% 16.3% 16.3%16.3% 16.3% 11.3% 11.3%11.3% 11.3% Renminbi Devaluation Simulation Results We now turn to examine how a renminbi devaluation would affect this baseline scenario. We simulate a series of real devaluation scenarios: low (10%) and high (25%). There is strong non-linearity in the simulation results with the trade impact becoming more pronounced for devaluation scenarios of 25% or more. Some of the general conclusions that can be drawn from the simulation results are the following (see Table 6): a. Chinese exports respond strongly to a renminbi devaluation as exports rises by 33.9% with a 10% devaluation and more than double with a 25% devaluation. b. The share of Chinese exports in world trade rises to 6.7% with a 10% devaluation and to 10.8% with a 25% devaluation. c. The biggest winners in absolute terms are Chinese exports of textiles and other manufactures. Their share of world trade rises to 36.6% and 17.5% respectively with a 25% renminbi devaluation. d. The biggest winners in percentage terms are Chinese exports of motor vehicles, electrical appliances and machinery and other manufactures. e. The biggest losers from the renminbi devaluation are the EU, Japan, the CER and the US. This follows from the rapid expansion of Chinese exports in those sectors in which the EU, Japan and the US are major exporters. f. ASEAN experiences only a moderate impact from a renminbi devaluation. Exports contract by 1.02% with a 10% devaluation and by 3.2% with a 25% devaluation. However, individual ASEAN countries who are major exporters of textiles and apparel and other manufactures may suffer disproportionately more. g. Global trade still expands as a result of a renminbi devaluation despite the fall in exports from all other regions. Table 6 shows the changes in export values in the aftermath of a renminbi devaluation. China’s exports leap by US $ 96.6 billion (a 33.9% increase) in the wake of a 10% devaluation while ASEAN’s total exports decline by nearly US $ 4.0 billion (a 1.02% fall). A 25% devaluation of the renminbi more than doubles Chinese exports by US $ 341.17 billion (a 119.7% increase) and reduces ASEAN exports by US $ 12.5 billion (or a 3.2% decline). TABLE 6 Change in Regional Exports from Renminbi Devaluation (Simulation Result) REGION REGIONREGION REGION TEN PERCENT DEVALUATION TEN PERCENT DEVALUATIONTEN PERCENT DEVALUATION TEN PERCENT DEVALUATION TWENTY TWENTYTWENTY TWENTY- -FIVE PERCENT FIVE PERCENT FIVE PERCENT FIVE PERCENT DEVALUATION DEVALUATIONDEVALUATION DEVALUATION ASEAN -1.02% -4.0 billion -3.18% -12.5 billion [...]... is consistent with the greater trade and economic links among the Asia-Pacific countries As is expected, ASEAN exports lose market share in Japan and the US and just manages to maintain its hold on the EU market Intra -ASEAN trade also declines as a result of the renminbi devaluation, with the share of intra -ASEAN imports falling from 19.2% to 18.5% for a 25% renminbi devaluation We also note that prior... expense of Japan and the EU We also examine in which markets Chinese exports gain the most (Table 11) and in which markets ASEAN loses its hold (see Table 12) Chinese exports gain market share in all regions, with the biggest gains being made in the Japanese and US markets There is also strong penetration of the Asian economies - ASEAN, Korea and rest of Asia - particularly for larger rates of devaluation. .. manufactures are a bigger proportion of the trade of countries like Indonesia, the Philippines and Thailand ASEAN' s import share also falls significantly in its key markets - Japan, China and the US A renminbi devaluation is also expected to erode the share of intra -ASEAN trade Furthermore, there are other associated risks of a renminbi devaluation which must be taken into account It turns out that... REGIONS GTAP REGIONS 1 ASEAN Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, Viet Nam 2 US United States of America 3 EU United Kingdom, Finland, Germany, Denmark, Sweden, Rest of European Union 4 Japan Japan 5 China China, Hong Kong 6 Korea Korea 7 CER Australia, New Zealand 8 Rest of Asia Taiwan, India, Sri Lanka, Rest of South Asia 9 Rest of the World Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico,... billion with a 25% devaluation Sectoral Effects The reason for the larger impact on Japan and the US has to do with the sectoral composition of Chinese exports after the devaluation From Table 7, we see that motor vehicle exports already doubles (albeit from small levels) with a 10% devaluation There is also a strong response in the electrical appliances and machinery sector, textiles and other manufactures... to the renminbi devaluation, ASEAN enjoys greater market share in all regions However, with a 25% devaluation, China zooms past in all regions except in ASEAN itself Other Risks While the direct impact on ASEAN of a renminbi devaluation is expected to be sector-specific as well as probably country specific, there are other risks associated with a renminbi devaluation that have to be taken into account... increased US protectionism, particularly if the devaluation is sufficiently large, and the spillover effects of a renminbi devaluation on other traders and how they respond to it may be an additional worries Summary and Conclusions The paper uses a 9 region 10 sector applied general equilibrium model to simulate the effect of a renminbi devaluation on ASEAN' s competitive position in major export markets... devaluation and perhaps none is more important than the impact on US-China economic and trade relations The US has effectively become the “importer of last resort” as a result of the Asian crisis and the weakness of the Japanese economy The rising trade imbalance has triggered protectionist reactions from the US Just to cite some recent examples, there has been a proliferation of anti-dumping actions on. .. devaluation, which may then lead to further trade pressures on the ASEAN countries The second issue has to do with the possible rise of US protectionism if the renminbi devaluation leads to a surge of Chinese imports and a deterioration in the US trade balance We examine this last issue in greater detail below Effect on US Trade Balance There are important political dimensions to a renminbi devaluation. .. China between 10% to 25% to simulate a range of possible renminbi devaluation scenarios The results suggest that while a renminbi devaluation only has a small effect on total ASEAN exports, there is substantial sectoral impact on exports of textiles and apparel as well as other manufactures This suggests that individual ASEAN countries may experience a significant negative impact since textiles and other . Inflation InflationInflation Inflation Real Real Real Real Devaluation DevaluationDevaluation Devaluation ASEAN 67.3% 80% 14.3% Indonesia Malaysia Philippines Singapore Thailand Vietnam. 1 Nominal Devaluation and Rates of Inflation in ASEAN and Korea, 1997-99 REGION REGIONREGION REGION Nominal Nominal Nominal Nominal Devaluation DevaluationDevaluation Devaluation CPI CPI. AFTER 10% DEVALUATION (Simulation Result) SECTOR SECTORSECTOR SECTOR ASEAN ASEANASEAN ASEAN USA USAUSA USA Japan JapanJapan Japan EU EUEU EU China ChinaChina China Korea KoreaKorea Korea Rest

Ngày đăng: 23/07/2014, 15:27

TỪ KHÓA LIÊN QUAN

TÀI LIỆU CÙNG NGƯỜI DÙNG

TÀI LIỆU LIÊN QUAN