2564 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market DQDOWHUQDWLYHWR¿QGLQJDQVZHUVE\WKHPVHOYHV Therefore, the prices set by these consumers do QRWSURSHUO\UHÀHFWWKHYDOXHRIWKHLUTXHVWLRQV Nevertheless, for those consumers who utilize the knowledge market to derive additional utilities, their prices will be set according to Equation 5. The more utility they expect to get, the higher prices they will set. Following this rational, the consumers on the knowledge market can be dif- ferentiated into the following two categories: • Spin-off information consumer: those who are only interested in using the knowledge PDUNHWDVDQDOWHUQDWLYHWR¿QGLQJLQIRUPD- tion without value added to their utilities; and • Mainstream knowledge consumer: those who utilize the knowledge market to acquire knowledge to derive additional utilities. As we have assumed, the additional utility is UHODWHGZLWKWKHGLI¿FXOW\q m of the question, so DPRUHGLI¿FXOWTXHVWLRQZLOOJLYHDFRQVXPHU more additional utility, which, however, is only applicable to mainstream knowledge consumers, but not to spin-off consumers, because there is no additional utility attached to their questions no PDWWHUKRZGLI¿FXOWWKH\DUH,QIDFWWKHKLJKHVW price that a spin-off consumer with the skill level s j is willing to pay for the answer of a question m is just c(s j , q m ), whereas a mainstream consumer with the same skill level will be willing to pay an amount higher than c(s j , q m ) as long as he(she) may derive additional utility from the answer of his(her) question. The existence of the spin-off consumers has some negative effects on the knowledge market EHFDXVHSULFHVGRQRWUHÀHFWWKHLUWUXHYDOXHVDV they just post their questions by offering a very low price. As a former researcher of Google An- swers, West (2002) made the similar observations DVIROORZV³2IWKHTXHVWLRQV,SLFNHGVRPHIHOO in my areas of expertise—technical support is- sues, historical facts, etc.—and some were just plain odd. One person offered a few bucks for someone to tell him a joke he hadn’t heard be- fore. Another wanted psychic advice, or barring that, a humorous reply. People used the service as an impromptu temp agency, offering a few dollars for someone to test drive a Web site or to make business appointments for them. While the service was intended to offer answers to factual questions, people tried to push the envelope any way they could.” Although the group of spin-off consumers seems to cause some problems to the knowledge PDUNHW LW PD\ DOVR EHQH¿W WKH ¿UP WR UHWDLQ some of them for several reasons. First of all, spin-off consumers are usually those who keep abreast of the state-of-art technologies and new SKHQRPHQD7KH³ZRUGRIPRXWK´HIIHFWWKURXJK spin-off consumers can bring more customers to the market. Second, network effects require the ¿UPWRDWWUDFWPRUHTXHVWLRQVWRWKHNQRZOHGJH market so that more consumers may be enticed WR SDUWLFLSDWH LQ WKH ³DVNLQJDQGDQVZHULQJ´ process. Third, maintaining a certain volume of questions on the knowledge market may alleviate the malicious competition among researchers. Therefore, it is also necessary to welcome some spin-off consumers on the knowledge market. Minimal and Maximal Posting Prices In this subsection, we analyze the purpose of the ¿ U P V S HF L I \ LQ J WK H PL Q L PD OD QG P D[ L P DO S R VW LQ J prices on the knowledge market. First of all, designating a minimal posting price has two effects on the knowledge market. The next proposition illustrates the effect of a minimal posting price on the spin-off consumers of the knowledge market. Proposition 3: A spin-off consumer j will not post his(her) question m on the knowledge market if the minimal posting price p VSHFL¿HGE\WKH¿UP is greater than c(s j , q m ). 2565 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market Proof:,IWKH¿UPVSHFL¿HVDPLQLPDOSRVWLQJSULFH as p , then a spin-off consumer’s expected payoff by posting a question m is S c = (u – c(s j , q m )) + [c(s j , q m ) – p](1 – ˆ i k ), whose second term is positive and decreasing in p when p < c(s j , q m ) and negative when p > c(s j , q m ). Therefore, the consumer will post a question if the minimal posting price p c(s j , q m ). Otherwise, he(she) is better off by not posting the question RQWKHNQRZOHGJHPDUNHW Ŷ 7KHDERYHSURSRVLWLRQLPSOLHVWKDWWKH¿UP can specify the minimal posting price p on the knowledge market to reduce the proportion of spin-off consumers. Given the minimal posting price p VSHFL¿HGE\WKH¿UPLWFDQEHLQIHUUHG that spin-off consumers with the skill level s j s j w i l l n o t b e s e r v e d o n t h e k no w le d ge m a r k e t , w h e r e c( s j , q m ) = p , and s j ( p ) is the threshold skill level for the minimal posting price. The minimal post- ing price p determines the proportion of spin-off consumers to be served on the knowledge market. :KHQWKH¿UPLQFUHDVHVWKHPLQLPDOSRVWLQJ price p , the threshold skill level s j ( p ) decreases, so more spin-off consumers will be eliminated from the knowledge market. In addition to its effect on the spin-off con- sumers, the minimal posting price also affects the mainstream consumers, but in a different way. The next proposition summarizes this effect. Proposition 4: All the mainstream consumers will be served by the knowledge market no matter what DPLQLPDOSRVWLQJSULFHLVVSHFL¿HG,QDGGLWLRQ for a minimal posting price p , those mainstream consumers with the skill level s j < I j s ( p )will be mandated to price their questions at p , where the skill level I j s ( p ) of mainstream consumers is determined by ˆ () 1 1 () ( () ) i I jm i p pu k pucspq p k ww c ' ' ˆ Proof:)RUTXHVWLRQVZLWKWKHGLI¿FXOW\W\SHDV q m , mainstream consumers with the skill level s j < I j s ( p ) will price their questions at p , where the threshold skill level I j s ( p ) of consumers is from () 1 1 () ( () ) i I jm i p pu k pucspq p k ww c ' ' ˆ +RZHYHUDVXI¿FLHQWFRQGLWLRQIRUDOOWKHFRQVXP- ers with the skill level s j (0, I j s ( p )] to remain served by the market is P j s ( p I j s ( p ), where the threshold skill level P j s ( p ) is determined from p = U( p )'u+c( P j s ( p ), q m ). This is to ensure that all the mainstream consum- ers with the skill level s j (0, s j ( p )] have positive surpluses by posting their questions with the minimal price p on the market. By comparing the WZRWKUHVKROGVNLOOOHYHOVLWLVQRWGLI¿FXOWWRVHH that consumers who are mandated to price their questions at the minimal posting price always have positive surpluses. First, it can be seen that at the minimal posting price, a customer whose skill level is I j s ( p ) always has a positive surplus because the maximal price for the skill level I j s ( p ) to have a positive surplus is greater than p . Sec- ond, for a consumer with the skill level s j < I j s ( p ), the maximal price for him(her) to have a positive surplus is greater than that for the skill level I j s ( p ), which is certainly greater than p Ŷ The above two propositions suggest that less s k i l l f u l c on s u m e r s , e i t he r s pi n - of f o r ma i n s t r e a m consumers, are generally less sensitive to the PLQLPDOSRVWLQJSULFHVSHFL¿HGE\WKH¿UPIRU the knowledge market. For spin-off consumers, the maximal price they are willing to pay to obtain a positive surplus from the market is c(s j , q m ), which decreases in the consumer’s skill level. For mainstream consumers, their maximal price for a positive surplus is determined from p = U( p )'u + c(s j , q m ), where p also decreases in the skill level s j . Therefore, a less skilled consumer for the 2566 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market knowledge market always has a larger support of price than a more skilled one. Intuitively, this result directly relates to our assumption that a less VNLOOHGFRQVXPHULQFXUVDKLJKHUFRVWIRU¿QGLQJ an answer to the question by himself(herself) than a more skilled one. Therefore, a less skilled consumer is willing to pay more for answers to his(her) question. In summary, by specifying a minimal posting price p IRUWKHNQRZOHGJHPDUNHWWKH¿UPFDQ eliminate some spin-off consumers and mandate some mainstream consumers to increase their posting prices to p . The reduced proportion of spin-off consumers on the knowledge market is thus s j ( p ) J, where J is the original estimated proportion of spin-off consumers. Having described the effects of the minimal SRVWLQJSULFHZHQH[WWXUQWRDQDO\]HWKHLQÀX- ence of a maximal posting price on the knowledge market. As we have illustrated, the existence of spin-off consumers is due to the fact that some consumers do not derive additional utilities from the market ('u = 0), so that the term U(p)'u is reduced into zero and a consumer’s additional surplus from the market ([c(s j , q m ) – p] – (1 – ˆ i k )) becomes a decreasing function of price p. In ad- dition to the effect of the additional utilities 'u, the probability function U(p) also has the similar effect when U(pĺ:KHQDFRQVXPHUUHDOL]HV that the probability function has such property that when p * ˆ p , U(p) = 1, and U'(p) = 0, he(she) will price his(her) question at ˆ p instead of p * when p * > ˆ p . Suppose a consumer is not aware of this property of the probability function, he(she) will still set a very high price p * for his(her) question. The consumer’s total surplus in this situation will be U c = (u – c(s j , q m )) + [U(p * )'u + c(s j , q m ) – p](1 – ˆ i k (p * )) §u – c(s j , q m )) + ['u + c(s j , q m ) – p](1 – ˆ i k (p * )). Since we know that U(p§ when p [ ˆ p , p * ), then the consumer will be better off by setting his(her) price at ˆ p , which barely reduces his(her) utility but increases the probability for his(her) question to be answered. Therefore, by announcing a maximal posting SULFHWKH¿UPLPSOLFLWO\LQIRUPVFRQVXPHUVRI the boundary price ˆ p so that they will be better RII,QDGGLWLRQWKH¿UPZLOODOVREHEHWWHURII which is shown in the following proposition. Proposition 5:7KH¿UPLVEHWWHURIIE\VSHFLI\LQJ a maximal posting price ˆ p such that when all p * > ˆ p , ˆ i k (p * ĺ. Proof:7KH¿UP¶VQHWEHQH¿WIRUDSRVWHGTXHV- tion m is S m (p * ) = (1 – D) p * (1 – ˆ i k (p * )). ,QVWHDGLIWKH¿UPVHWVDPD[LPDOSRVWLQJSULFH as ˆ p that is greater than p * WKHQWKH ¿UP¶VQHW EHQH¿WIRUWKLVTXHVWLRQPZLOOEH S m ( ˆ p ) = (1 – D) p (1 – ˆ i k (p)) It can be observed that S m (p * ĺZKHQ ˆ i k (p * ) ĺ 7KHUHIRUH WKH ¿UP ZLOO EH EHWWHU RII E\ specifying a maximal posting price ˆ p such that S m ( ˆ p ) > S m (p * ) Ŷ ,QVXPPDU\WKHVSHFL¿HGPD[LPDOSRVW- ing price not only may increase a mainstream FRQVXPHU¶V VXUSOXV EXW DOVR PDNHV WKH ¿UP better off. Firm’s Optimal Decisions )ROORZLQJRXUSULRUGLVFXVVLRQVWKH¿UPVKRXOG now determine the appropriate allocation to UHVHDUFKHUVEDVHGRQWKHVSHFL¿HGPLQLPDODQG maximal posting prices on the knowledge market, LQRUGHUWRPD[LPL]HLWVWRWDOH[SHFWHGSUR¿W 7KHUHIRUHWKH¿UP¶VGHFLVLRQSUREOHPFDQEH formulated as 2567 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market 1234 [] m q max E (7) where () 1 1 0() (1 ) ( ) ( ) j i p s ii jj p k pgkdkfsds ªº «» «» ¬¼ ³³ ˆ () 1 2 0() (1 ) (1 ) ( ) ( ) I j i sp ii jj p k pgkdkfsds ªº «» «» ¬¼ ³³ ˆ () 1 3 () ( ) (1 ) (1 ) ( ) ( ) j I j i p s ii jj sp p k pgkdkfsds ªº «» «» ¬¼ ³³ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ 11 4 () () (1 ) (1 ) ( ) ( ) j i ii jj pp s k pgkdkfsds ªº «» «» ¬¼ ³³ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ $VVKRZQLQ)LJXUHWKH¿UP¶VWRWDOSUR¿W FR Q VL V W V RI IRX UF RP S RQH QW V7 KH¿ U VWF RPS RQH QW S LVWKHSUR¿WIURPWKHUHPDLQLQJVSLQRIIFRQ- sumers by specifying the minimal posting price p , in which J is the initial proportion of spin-off consumers on the knowledge market. The second LVWKHSUR¿WIURPPDLQVWUHDPFRQVXPHUVZLWKWKH minimal posting price; the third is from main- stream consumers who set their optimal prices in between the minimal and maximal posting prices; and the fourth is again from mainstream consumers who are forced to have their questions priced at the maximal level ˆ p . According to our previous analysis, when WKH¿UPLQFUHDVHVWKHPLQLPDOSRVWLQJSULFH p and decreases the maximal posting price ˆ p , s j ( p ) decreases, I j s ( p ) increases, and s ˆ j ( ˆ p ) decreases. Therefore, less consumers will be able to price their questions at their optimal ones p * and more mainstream consumers will price their questions at either the minimal or maximal price, while mo re spi n- of f con su me rs wi ll be el im inat ed f rom WKH PDUNHW 7KHUHIRUH WKH ¿UP PD\ UHJXODWH the knowledge market by designating different minimal and maximal posting prices. 'XHWRWKHFRPSOH[QDWXUHRIWKH¿UP¶VPD[L- mization problem, the closed-form solution of D is not available. However, Table 2 demonstrates KRZWKHSUR¿WVWUXFWXUHRIHDFKFRPSRQHQWZLOO change when the allocation D to researchers in- FUHDVHVZKLFKJLYHVWKHLQWXLWLRQIRUWKH¿UPWR practically assign the allocation D. Essentially, WKH¿UPKDVWREDODQFHWKHWUDGHRIIEHWZHHQWKH gross revenue of each question and the payment to researchers; by increasing the allocation to UHVHDUFKHUVWKH¿UPPD\LQFUHDVHWKHWRWDOJURVV revenue from each question, but may have to al- locate more to researchers. 7KH¿UP¶VSUR¿WDOVRFKDQJHVZLWKWKHLQLWLDO proportion of spin-off customers on the knowledge market. As the example to show the intuition, we investigate the following special case. If we consider that all the questions posted on the knowledge market are homogeneous with respect WRWKHLUGLI¿FXOWLHVEXWKHWHURJHQHRXVLQWHUPVRI their originators, and when JĺRUDOPRVWDOO the consumers belong to the spin-off type, the ¿UP¶VSUR¿WZLOOEHFRPH )LJXUH7KH¿UP¶VSUR¿W)RXUFRPSRQHQWV Mainstream consumers Spin-off consumers eliminated 1 ()p () j sp 2 ()p 3 (*)p 4 ()p ˆ () I j sp () j sp ˆˆ 2568 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market () 1 0() (1 ) ( ) ( ) j i p s ii jj p k pgkdkfsds ªº «» «» ¬¼ ³³ (1 ) (1 ( )) ( ) j i ppp s k ZKRVH ¿UVWRUGHU FRQGLWLRQ ZLWK UHVSHFW WR D yields () 1 11() i i p k p k ww which indicates that there exists an optimal proportion for a given minimal posting price p because the LHS of the above equation increases and the RHS decreases in D. In addition, when WKHVSHFL¿HGPLQLPDOSRVWLQJSULFH p increases, the threshold knowledge level ˆ i k ( p ) increases and ˆ i k ( p D decreases, resulting in a larger optimal allocation D. This implies that when the majority of consumers are not serious about the knowledge PDUNHWRUEHORQJWRWKHVSLQRIIW\SHWKH¿UP s h o u l d a l lo ca t e m o r e t o r e se a r c h e r s w h e n i t t r i e s t o eliminate more spin-off consumers by increasing the minimal posting price. Intuitively, when there are less spin-off consumers on the knowledge market, researchers deserve more from answer- ing each question. CONCLUSION The development of Web and information tech- nologies provides real-time access for people to seek and acquire information and knowledge from online sources. Viewing knowledge transaction as WKHQHZSUR¿WPDNLQJRSSRUWXQLW\FRPSDQLHVDUH trying to set up online marketplaces for potential knowledge buyers and sellers to meet and thereby make transactions. Based on the best practice from Google Answers, we present an analytical model of an online knowledge market, where knowledge re- searchers and consumers trade knowledge. The ¿UPPDLQWDLQVWKHRQOLQHNQRZOHGJHPDUNHWDQG charges fees for all the questions that have been answered. We analyze the pricing strategies from ERWKFRQVXPHUV¶DQGD¿UP¶VSHUVSHFWLYHV First, a consumer’s optimal strategy to price his(her) question is studied. Based on whether the knowledge market is used to derive additional utilities, two types of consumers on the market can be differentiated. Spin-off consumers utilize the knowledge market just to quickly retrieve information without any additional utilities. Compo- nent Organi- zational proportion Selling price Mar- ket share Probability of questions being answered ʌ 1 decrease same Same increase ʌ 2 decrease same de- crease increase ʌ 3 decrease increase in- crease increase ʌ 4 decrease same in- crease increase 7DEOH&KDQJHVRISUR¿WVWUXFWXUHZLWKUHVSHFWWRDOORFDWLRQD 2569 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market %HFDXVHSULFHVGRQRWUHÀHFWWUXHYDOXDWLRQVRI their questions, spin-off consumers always price their questions as low as possible. Mainstream consumers use the knowledge market to acquire knowledge to obtain additional utilities. Mostly, the more utilities they expect to get, the higher they will be prepared to pay for an answer of their questions. In addition, a more knowledgeable consumer tends to set a higher price for his(her) question. Second, the purpose of specifying the mini- mal and maximal posting prices on the market is analyzed. Basically, the minimal posting price is used to control the proportion of spin-off consumers on the market so that the negative ef- fects of spin-off consumers on the entire market can be alleviated. The maximal posting price is used to improve the welfare of both mainstream FRQVXPHUVDQGWKH¿UP%\VSHFLI\LQJGLIIHUHQW PLQLPDODQGPD[LPDOSRVWLQJSULFHVWKH¿UPFDQ effectively moderate the structure of the online knowledge market. Finally, the firm’s optimal allocation to researchers is investigated. Contingent on the VSHFL¿HGPLQLPDODQGPD[LPDOSRVWLQJSULFHV WKH ¿UP¶V SUR¿W FDQ EH FDWHJRUL]HG LQWR IRXU components. When the allocation to researchers F K DQ J HV WK H¿ U P¶V S UR ¿ W V W U X F WX UH FK DQ JH VD VZ H O O Essentially, the increased allocation to researchers improves the gross revenue from each question RQWKHPDUNHW7KHUHIRUHWKH¿UPKDVWREDODQFH the tradeoff between its payment to researchers DQGLWVLQFUHDVHGEHQH¿WLQRUGHUWRFKRRVHWKH best allocation to researchers. This study serves as our initial attempt to fully understand the pricing mechanism on the NQRZOHGJHPDUNHW'XHWRWKHGLI¿FXOWLHVRIRE- taining researchers’ data from Google Answers, the empirical validation of our analytical results is still in preparation. We plan to conduct a de- tailed analysis to not only verify the results in this research, but also make extensions to reveal more hidden facts on knowledge marketplaces. In addition, future study may also include network effect in the model and explore the variations of pricing strategies on the knowledge market. REFERENCES Anderson, S., & Palma, A. (1992). The logit as a model of product differentiation. Oxford Eco- nomic Papers, 44, 51-67. Ba, S., Stallaert, J. & Whinston A. B. (2001). 2SWLPDOLQYHVWPHQWLQNQRZOHGJHZLWKLQD¿UP using a market mechanism. Management Science, 47(9), 225-239. Bakos, Y. (1997). Reducing buyer search costs: Implications for electronic marketplaces. Manage- ment Science, 43(12), 1676-1692. Bakos, Y. (1998). The emerging role of electronic marketplaces on the Internet. Communications of the ACM, 41(8), 35-42. Bockem, S. (1994). A generalized model of horizontal product differentiation. Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 287-298. Cohen, M., & Whang, S. (1997). Competing in product and service: A product life-cycle model. Management Science, 43, 535-545. Davenport, H. T., & Prusak, L. (1998). Working knowledge: How organizations manage what they know. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. D e so u z a , K . C. , & Aw a z u , Y. (2 0 03) . C o n s t r u c t i n g internal knowledge markets: Considerations from mini cases. International Journal of Information Management, 23, 345-353. Desuoza, K., Awazu, Y., Yamakawa, S., & Umezawa, M. (2005). Facilitating knowledge market mechanism. Knowledge and Process Management, 12(2), 99-107. 2570 Pricing Strategy of Online Knowledge Market Edelman, B. (2004). Earnings and ratings at Google Answers (Working Draft). Harvard Law School, Harvard University. Kenney, A. R., McGovern, N. Y., Martinez, I. T., & Heidig, L. J. (2003). Google meets eBay What academic librarians can learn from alternative information providers. D-Lib Magazine, 9(6). Lancaster, K. (1990). The economics of product variety: A survey. Marketing Science, 9, 189- 206. Matson, E., Patiath, P., & Shavers, T. (2003). Stimulating knowledge sharing: Strengthening your organization’s internal knowledge market. Organizational Dynamics, 32(3), 275-285. MÄuller, R. M., Spiliopoulou, M., & Lenz, H. -J. (2002). Electronic marketplaces of knowledge: Characteristics and sharing of knowledge assets. Proceedings of the International Conference on Advances in Infrastructure for e-Business, e-Education, e-Science, and e-Medicine on the Internet (SSGRR 2002w). West, J. (2002). Information for sale: My experi- ence with Google Answers. Searcher - The Maga- zine for Database Professionals, 10(9), 14. This work was previously published in the International Journal of E-Business Research, edited by I. Lee, Volume 4, Issue 1, pp. 55-68, copyright 2008 by IGI Publishing (an imprint of IGI Global). 2571 Copyright © 2009, IGI Global, distributing in print or electronic forms without written permission of IGI Global is prohibited. Chapter 8.13 Evolving E-Health System Symbiosis: Theoretical Constructs in International Realpolitik Space Denis H. J. Caro Université d’Ottawa, Canada ABSTRACT The 21 st century continues to witness the trans- formation of organizational systems globally through the deployment of information and com- munication technologies (ICT). The emerging IXWXUHLVZLWQHVVLQJWKHFRQYHUJHQFHRIDUWL¿FLDO intelligence, biotechnology, nomadic informa- tion systems, and nano-technology. This prom- ises to further compel inter-organizational and inter-sectorial interactive transformations. The health care sector is no exception to the inter- organizational dynamic imperatives driven with ICT innovative advances. This article proposes a conceptual model of symbiotic e-health networks in a meta-cultural domain that goes beyond the realm of extant literature on dyadic relation- ships. The model dimensions are posited on a key informant approach and content analysis of the strategic perceptions of international ICT and health care executives interacting through dyadic SDUWQHUVKLSV 7KH ¿QGLQJV DQG LPSOLFDWLRQV RI the study for the model and further information management research are underscored. The un- derlying meta-cultural frame is characterized by public governance values and the article explores its perceived role in sustaining symbiotic e-health networks in Canada and Sweden. INTRODUCTION The 21 st century continues to witness the transfor- mation of organizational systems globally through information and communication technologies (ICT), which drive and evolve systemic goals. The implementation of ICT, such as business in- telligence systems, knowledge management, data mining and warehousing, supply chain manage- ment, systems development and implementation, systems integration, and security systems continue to compel different sectors to engage in chal- 2572 Evolving E-Health System Symbiosis lenging inter-organizational relationships (Senge, Carstedt, & Porter, 2001). With the cogent and ub iquitous developments in nomadic information systems and wireless and wearable technologies, the emerging IXWXUHLVZLWQHVVLQJWKHFRQYHUJHQFHRIDUWL¿FLDO intelligence, biotechnology, and nano-technology (Orlikowski & Iacono, 2001; Pearson, 2001). This promises to further propel inter-organizational and inter-sectorial interactions. Strategic dyadic partnerships, with its characteristics of longev- ity, management control and direction, mutual EHQH¿FHQFH DQG VWDELOLW\ H[HPSOLI\ RQH W\SH inter-organizational relationship. The literature underscores the critical role of strategic inter- VHFWRULDO SDUWQHUVKLSV LQ IRVWHULQJ HI¿FLHQFLHV sectorial growth, and social actualization through innovation and mutual organizational learning (Burgelman & Doz, 2001; Etemad, Wright, & Dana, 2001; Kodama, 2001; Nooteboom, 2000; Oliver, 2001; Robinson, Savage, & Campbell, 2003). These linkages have the potential to liberate thinking beyond closed organizational paradigms and embrace complex changes and uncertainty extra-organizationally and proactively (Dickson, Farris, & Verbeke, 2001). The health care sector is no exception to the inter-organizational change imperatives driven through ICT innovative advances. Regionally integrated e-health networks promise less re- source duplication, lower operational costs, reduced clinical waiting times, and lengths of stay and greater quality care in the face of care provider and clinician shortages. E-health is the t ra nsfor mat ion al wave of t he f ut u re i n healt h ca re systems (Adewale, 2004; Gutierrez, 2001; Sahney, 2003). The upcoming generation of consumers and providers instinctively understand the trans- formational power of ICT to improve delivery HI¿FLHQFLHVDQGTXDOLW\RIKHDOWKFDUHUHJLRQDOO\ through inter-organizational interactions. On the basis of extant literature, this article proposes a conceptual model of symbiotic e-health networks. The model dimensions are posited on a key infor- mant approach and content analysis of the strategic perceptions of international ICT and health care executives interacting through dyadic partner- VKLSV7KH¿QGLQJVDQGLPSOLFDWLRQVRIWKHVWXG\ underscore directions for future international research in information management. INTER-SECTORIAL DYADIC RELATIONSHIPS: GENERIC AND THEORETICAL PERSPECTIVES This article posits that strategic partnerships and alliances are, in essence, symbiotic information networks. These are, in essence, mutually advan- tageous inter-organizational systems between informational cultures differing in values, mis- sions, perceptions, and evolutions. Moreover, these informational cultures incubate and thrive in informational cultural polities, which are ar- ticulated through the governance organizations. Networks are systems of interconnected individu- als and organizations through which informational DQGUHVRXUFHVÀRZ)RUG:HOOV%DLOH\ These networks interact and coalesce through an exchange of informational, relational, and trans- actional capital, and sustained through transac- tional and transformational processes. Moreover, these processes are articulated through skills sets exercised through system participants, called executives. Tight coupling of different sectors occurs when relational capital and transactional capital is leveraged through transactional and transformational skill sets. Where the capital and process resources are inadequate, a supra-level (governance agents) foster and leverage evolving symbiotic information network. Symbiotic infor- mation networks are the result of the interplay of management and technical processes. The extant literature on strategic partnerships and alliances is germane to the evolution of inter- sectorial symbiotic information networks that incubate in meta-cultural information domains. In so doing, the article subsumes a realist approach, 2573 Evolving E-Health System Symbiosis rather a strictly positivistic, or phenomenological, one to the exploration of inter-sectorial networks (Stiles, 2003). It responds to the call for a polity system perspective, where social-political ele- PHQWVLQÀXHQFHLQWHUVHFWRULDOQHWZRUNEHKDYLRU and integrate elements of trust within economic, political, socio-cultural and strategic dimensions. 0RUHRYHUWKHXQGHUO\LQJPRGHOUHÀHFWVDSOXUDO- ist epistemology, where the emphasis is on an XQGHUVWDQGLQJ ³RIWKHEHFRPLQJ´ GH 5RQG Bouchikhi, 2004). Moreover, it views the orga- nizational and national cultures as heterogeneous elements that interact dialectically and dynami- cally in the evolution of information networks (Townsend, 2003). The literature points to management control factors that implicitly form the basis for effec- tive inter-sectorial strategic dyadic partnerships (Dyer, Prashant, & Singh, 2001; Judge & Ry- man, 2001; Weech-Maldonado & Merrill, 2000). Such elements include leadership with executive vision, solid strategic and operational planning constructs, rigorous feasibility studies and cost- EH QH¿WD QDO\ VH V V W D EOH¿ QDQFL QJW K URX J KDU D QJH RILQQRYDWLYHDQGÀH[LEOH¿QDQFLDOLQVWUXPHQWV DQG VSHFL¿F SHUIRUPDQFH PHWULFV DQG WDUJHWV Other extant elements to effective inter-sectorial dyadic links, or strategic partnerships, include the mutual understanding of business models, motivations, priorities, resource strengths, and OLPLWDWLRQVWKHFOHDUDQGH[SOLFLWGH¿QLWLRQRI PXWXDOEHQH¿WVH[SHFWDWLRQVDQGSULRULWLHV DQGWKHPXWXDOVKDULQJRI¿QDQFLDODQGSROLWLFDO risks (Das & Teng, 2001). Structural bonding (economic and functional factors that involve H[SOLFLWEHQH¿WVDQGVRFLDOERQGLQJHPRWLRQDO and affective resources) are the prerequisites to relationship cohesion (Rodriquez, 2002). Mutual t r u s t , o r r e l a t i o n a l c a p i t a l , f o s t e r s a c l i m a t e o f g o o d faith and open collaboration in forging congruent goals and objectives. Perception, mutuality, trust, and understanding are the drivers of organizational system behaviour. This points to the critical need to understand the inter-sectorial cultural and organizational cli- mates. Zhu’s Wu-Shi-Ren (WSR) Li-stage model underscores the perspectives, sensing and the psycho-cognitive elements (Shi-Li) which interact synergistically with socio-political elements or power structures (Ren-Li) to release technical ICT UHVRXUFHV:X/LIRUFHV=KX³6HQVLQJ DQGFDULQJ´WUDQVIRUPWKH³NQRZLQJ´=KX This study explores inter-sectorial informational networks transcending national cultural contexts. It extends Zhu’s WSR-Li framework into the Realpolitik of e-health systems transnationally. In particular, the proposed model in this study FHQWHUV RQ ¿YH V\PELRWLFLQIRUPDWLRQ QHWZRUN dimensions, which are not explicitly reported in the extant literature. 1. Relational capital (Shi-Li) dimension: The extent to which inter-sectorial executives harmonize perceptions, values and motiva- WLRQVLQDQDWPRVSKHUHRIWUXVWDQGEHQH¿W to effect symbiotic information networks; 2. Transactional capital (Wu-Li) dimension: The extent to which inter-sectorial execu- tives effectively avail and access strategic resources to effect symbiotic information networks; 3. Transactional skills (Ren-Li) dimension: The extent to which inter-sectorial execu- tives mobilize internal power resources to effect symbiotic information networks; 4. Transformational skills (Ren-Li) dimen- sion: The extent to which inter-sectorial executives exercise vision and strategic leadership to effect external symbiotic in- formation networks; and 5. Supra-network transgenic (Supra-Ren- Li) dimension: The extent to which external third parties engage, enable, and sustain symbiotic information networks through transactional capital and fostering transfor- mational skills externally. . e r s a c l i m a t e o f g o o d faith and open collaboration in forging congruent goals and objectives. Perception, mutuality, trust, and understanding are the drivers of organizational. relationships (Senge, Carstedt, & Porter, 2001). With the cogent and ub iquitous developments in nomadic information systems and wireless and wearable technologies, the emerging IXWXUHLVZLWQHVVLQJWKHFRQYHUJHQFHRIDUWL¿FLDO intelligence,. to liberate thinking beyond closed organizational paradigms and embrace complex changes and uncertainty extra-organizationally and proactively (Dickson, Farris, & Verbeke, 2001). The