Available online 20 December 2012 We exploit a large panel of Italian manufacturing firms observed over the period 1998-2003 to jointly assess the impact of cash flow and leverage on co
Trang 1Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 24 (2013) 34-44
Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect _ | STRUCTURAL
GEES AND ECONOMIC
“T= | YAS
a eh
SP
na
Joint analysis of the non-linear debt-growth nexus and cash-flow
sensitivity: New evidence from Italy
Massimo Molinari
Department of Economics and Management, University of Trento, via Inama 5, 38122 Trento, Italy
Article history: This paper conducts an empirical investigation of the finance-growth nexus at firm level Available online 20 December 2012 We exploit a large panel of Italian manufacturing firms observed over the period 1998-2003
to jointly assess the impact of cash flow and leverage on corporate growth measured in
cáo geneity and persistence by using a system GMM estimator fully developed by Blundell and
125 Bond (1998) We find an inverted U-shaped relationship between debt and growth: at low
levels, leverage exerts a positive influence on growth and yet there appears to be a nega- Keywords: tive relationship between growth and debt-exposure for fragile firms, i.e highly leveraged Firm growth ones This finding is consistent with the idea that debt initially enables firms to broaden Leverage their financing options and provides additional resources to growth Nevertheless, once
negatively affect firm expansion Highly leveraged firms are also endowed with relatively lower levels of internal cash flow and exhibit higher growth-cash flow sensitivity We con- clude that this latter result can be interpreted as evidence of the existence of financial constraints
© 2013 Elsevier B.V All rights reserved
cial constraints because internal cash-flow and debt are the
In recent years, empirical research on firm dynamics has
paid increasing attention to the finance—growth nexus, and
two streams of literature can be distinguished One the one
hand, several scholars have studied the effect of leverage
on firm performance; on the other hand, a large body of
works have focused on financial constraints and the inter-
pretation of the correlation between internal cash-flow and
investment or growth This study seeks to provide a bridge
between these two strands of research
We work with a large panel of small-medium Italian
manufacturing firms observed over the period 1997-2003
The vast majority of manufacturing firms in Italy are not
listed, and financial markets in Italy are less developed than
in the United States or other European countries Hence, the
E-mail address: massimo.molinari@unitn.it
0954-349X/$ - see front matter © 2013 Elsevier B.V All rights reserved
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/J.strueco.2012.11.003
primary sources of financing for most firms
In this context, we estimate a dynamic growth model augmented by cash-flow and a measure of leverage, and
we rely on a system GMM estimator to overcome prob- lems of unobserved firm-specific effects, persistence and endogeneity of explanatory variables
Our findings suggest that there is an important connec- tion between cash-flow and debt-structure More in detail,
we find an inverted U-shaped relationship between debt and growth: initially, leverage exerts a positive effect of growth and low-leveraged firms are not constrained (or are so to a much less extent) by internal funds Conversely, there seems to be a negative relationship between growth and debt-exposure for fragile firms, i.e highly leveraged ones
Our interpretation is that debt initially allows firms
to expand their financing options and provides additional
Trang 2resources to sustain investment plans and future growth
This is until negative liquidity and debt overhang effects
kick in and hamper firm growth In this respect, such firms
can be considered debt-constrained In addition, highly
leveraged firms also appear to be internally constrained
because they exhibit relatively lower levels of internal
funds Cash-flow, or the lack thereof, is more binding for
these firms, and this also explains why the sensitivity of
firm growth to cash-flow is found to increase with the level
of indebtedness
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 provides a review of the main contributions on
cash-flow sensitivities and financial constraints and puts
forward the first research hypothesis Section 3 outlines
the possible links between leverage and growth and form-
ulates the second research hypothesis Section 4 presents
the data-set and Section 5 focuses on the empirical analysis
Section 6 summarizes the main results and concludes
2 Cash flow sensitivities and financial constraints
Carpenter and Petersen (2002) put forth a model of
firm growth based on the internal finance theory If there
were perfect capital markets and no bankruptcy costs, the
supply of finance would be a flat schedule In this world,
firms facing a temporary shortage of internal funds could
simply resort to external finance, so that their growth pro-
cess should not be hampered by the lack of cash-flow Yet,
in practice, the debt portion of the supply schedule will
be upward sloping The supply is flat as long as the firm
exploits its internal resources at a given shadow cost Once
such funds are entirely used up, the firm must finance
additional projects through debt The more indebted a
firm is, though, the more incentives it will have to select
risky projects, and this increases the probability of default
Providers of external funds want to hedge against the
moral-hazard risk attached to the use of debt and charge
higher interest rates This explains why the cost of finance
increases with the degree of leverage and hence the upward
sloping part of the supply of funds.! In this world, a nega-
tive shock to cash flow would not be replaced one for one by
debt and will hence have a negative impact on investment
The standard empirical approach to testing this hypoth-
esis is to estimate either Tobin’s-Q investment equation
or firms’ growth models augmented by cash-flow A pos-
itive and significant coefficient on cash-flow would then
be interpreted as evidence of the existence of financial
constraints A vast empirical literature has tested this
hypothesis by focusing on the impact of cash flow on firms’
investment decisions and growth.”
1 In the original model outlined by Carpenter and Petersen, the firm
may turn to external equity at a flat rate once the cost of debt becomes
sufficiently high Yet, in the case of small business enterprises (SME), we
can safely neglect this portion of the supply because the vast majority of
firms are not publicly listed
2 See, among others, Carpenter and Petersen (2002) for a study on US
small (listed) firms; Audretsch and Elston (2002) use data on German
listed firms; Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006) rely on Italian data on manufac-
turing firms; Oliveira and Fortunato (2006a) exploit a panel of Spanish
manufacturing firms
This empirical approach has been criticized on sev- eral grounds A wide array of studies have documented that cash flow matters, but several authors have pointed out that the cash flow could be significant in an invest- ment or growth regression simply because of the bias that arises when cash flow is positively correlated with (not properly controlled for) investment opportunities.? Should this be the case, one could not interpret positive cash flow sensitivities as an evidence that financial con- straints are binding Nonetheless, as discussed in Carpenter and Guariglia (2008), one would expect this effect to be constant across all groups of firms, while the severity of capital markets imperfection may vary within the sample Hence, researchers have started to sort firms into groups characterized by an increasing likelihood of being finan- cially constrained The detection of higher sensitivity to cash flow for firms a priori categorized as constrained is believed to provide stronger support for the financial con- straint hypothesis
Several authors have proposed alternative criteria with which to identify such financially constrained firms.* It appears that different segmenting strategies could lead to different results, and a shared consensus has not yet been reached The view according to which ex ante constrained firms should exhibit higher sensitivity to cash flow first came under attack when Kaplan and Zingales published
an influential paper in 1997 as a response to Fazzari et al (1988) The former authors re-examined the samples of low-dividend firms used by Fazzari et al (1988) and re- classified firms according to some qualitative information provided by the management, together with some infor- mation on liquidity statements They showed that firms classified as constrained appeared to be less sensitive to cash flow than other firms This controversy has spurred
a number of follow-up publications and a lively and still unresolved debate, and researchers are still arguing on the- oretical and empirical grounds.°
As far as the theory is concerned, economists are debat- ing over the conditions under which one can expect to have
3 See Chirinko and Schaller (1995) or Carpenter and Guariglia (2008)
4 In their seminal paper, Fazzari et al (1988) split the sample according
to dividend payout, on the assumptions that a high dividends payout ratio signals the absence of financial constraints Among others, Gilchrist and Himmelberg (1995) use bond rating, whereas Devereux and Schiantarelli (1990) consider group membership Most of this information is only avail- able for listed firms, however Cabral and Mata (2003) proxy financial constraints with age, on the assumption that young firms are endowed with less cumulated wealth, or have access to a narrower set of external sources Gertler and Gilchrist (1994) use firms size to identify financial constraint, relying on the idea that smaller firms typically can have access
to fewer external finance options Hoshi et al (1991) work with Japanese firms and distinguish between firms on the basis of whether or not they belong to a keiretsu, and as such have a main-bank relationship Bond
et al (2003) use countries in which the firm is based as a sample-splitting criterion
” See, among others, Fazzari et al (2000), Kaplan and Zingales (2000) and Cleary (1999) To be noted is that this unresolved debate has stim- ulated some researchers to steer away from analyses based on cash flow sensitivities and opt for a more encompassing measure of finan- cial constraints See for instance, Musso and Schiavo (2008), who develop
a time-varying multivariate continuous index to identify the degree of financial constraints.
Trang 3a monotonic positive relation between the degree of finan-
cial constraints and the cash flow sensitivity.®
Empirical studies are still arguing over the soundness of
the ex ante criteria used to identify constrained and non-
constrained firms More specifically, much of the dispute
between Kaplan and Zingales and Fazzari, Petersen and
Hubbard revolves around the notion and the operational
definition of financial constraints For example, Fazzari and
co-authors claim that what Kaplan and Zingales called
financially constrained firms are actually financially dis-
tressed and constrained firms The difference is important
because a financially distressed firm may be prevented by
creditors from making normal use of cash flow and that
would reduce the sensitivity of investment to cash flow In
this particular case, a financial constraint may not be cap-
tured by the cash flow coefficient in a regression analysis.’
This paper contributes to this debate by focusing on
the degree of indebtedness as a useful variable with which
to discriminate between constrained and non-constrained
companies Debt and cash flow are the two main channels
of financing for most firms, and it makes sense to jointly
assess the direct effect of leverage on growth, evaluate the
degree to which leverage affects cash flow sensitivities, and
finally discuss why this can be interpreted in favor of the
financial constraint hypothesis
Several authors have previously associated the level of
indebtedness with the firm’s financing constraints status.®
We wish to revisit and build on the argument for this
choice The basic idea is that highly leveraged firms can
be considered (debt) constrained because they are closer
to the exhaustion of their maximum debt capacity Hence
they may not be able to raise additional external finance
(at least not at reasonable borrowing terms) when needed
For obvious reasons, an excessively high cumulated debt
increases the likelihood of default and therefore calls for a
higher risk premium that ultimately accounts for a steeper
supply schedule As explained, this would then make firms
more sensitive to cash flow
Other authors, such as Fazzari et al (2000), assert that
leverage is an ambiguous prior, and that cannot be used
to distinguish the degree of financing constraints In fact, a
firm may have low debt simply because it cannot obtain
external finance from lenders If this were the case, the
low debt (not the high) firm would be constrained This
argument implicitly assumes that the causality between
leverage and financing constraints goes the other way
round, i.e the observed level of leverage is the result of
financing constraints
Some observations on this critique are in order This lat-
ter argument is not necessarily in contradiction with the
6 Kaplan and Zingales (1997) make a first attempt with a simple static
one-period model, and Cleary et al (2007) develop a more complicated
dynamic framework in which costs and revenue effects counteract each
other In this model, the observed sign of cash flow sensitivity ultimately
depends on which effect dominates
7 For this reason we deliberately discard distressed firms, i.e firms with
negative net-worth By doing so, we lose 399 observations on the balanced
panel
8 See, for instance, D’Espallier and Guariglia (2009), Whited and Wu
(2006), Kaplan and Zingales (1997) and Whited (1992)
previous one In fact the former relies on the notion of cumulated, whereas the latter implicitly refers to newly- issued debt At any point in time, the observed leverage ratio mainly reflects cumulated debt, and it may well be that a firm does not gain access to additional loans precisely because it already has too much debt and hence is debt- constrained This is precisely our argument Alternatively,
it may be that the firm exhibits a persistently low cumu- lated debt and hence a low leverage ratio If this were the case though, there must be some other factors that account for this condition For example, size or age consideration may have a role It is well documented that small and young firms pay a considerably higher risk-premium (pos- sibly because they lack of collateral), and therefore their growth process is hampered by a limited access to external funds This would explain low debt and a constrained sta- tus, and it would invalidate the initial argument because this would bias the monotonic positive relation between debt and the severity of financial constraints Hence, we attempt to attenuate this possible bias by controlling first for age and then for size in our regression analysis Moreover, Fazzari et al (2000) do not offer an explicit alternative explanation for why highly leveraged firms would display higher sensitivity to cash flow In fact, if leverage does not necessarily pick up differences in the degree of financial constraint, at best no significant pattern should be detected when comparing cash flow sensitivi- ties across samples sorted by the leverage ratio If low debt firms are constrained (as Fazzari et al., 2000 suggest may
be the case), then one should find that these firms are the ones most responsive to cash flow fluctuations
Empirical analysis can be used to discriminate between these two competing views For the reasons put forward in this discussion, our first research hypothesis is that lever- age captures the degree of financial constraints and this is captured by highly indebted firms being more responsive
to cash flow shocks
3 Leverage and growth
In this section we introduce the literature studying the impact of leverage on firm’s performance, we then intro- duce the second hypothesis that will be tested in our empirical analysis in Section 5 There are several channels through which leverage can impact on growth One possi- bility is that debt overhang has a negative effect because it creates a conflict between shareholders and bondholders.? According to this view, managers are assumed to act in the best interest of shareholders A manager of a low- leveraged firm has a stronger incentive to take advantage of positive growth opportunities because most gains will be enjoyed by shareholders By contrast, a manager of a highly indebted firm may pass up on positive net-present value projects because most revenues would accrue to bondhold- ers For these reasons, excessive debt overhang is believed
to induce under-investment and has a negative impact on growth
° See Myers (1977)
Trang 4A liquidity effect may work as a further impediment to
corporate growth.!° Typically, a firm committed to large
debt repayments is expected to fewer less internal liquid
resources to finance investment In addition, such firms
can find it harder to obtain additional loans and therefore
to grow In other words, when the existing debt reaches
the maximum debt-capacity of the firm, it becomes bind-
ing and limits the ability of the firm to raise more external
finance, de facto curtailing future growth
These negative effects are likely to be stronger for
unlisted firms In fact, unlisted firms lack the (exter-
nal) equity channel and as such their mode of operation
inevitably exhibits a higher dependence on debt The same
logic applies to a liquidity effect
That said, it is important to draw a further distinction
between listed and unlisted firms Listed firm choose the
desired level of debt to minimize agency conflicts The pre-
diction of a negative association between debt and growth
or investment is driven by the way managers respond to
minimize the risk related to the debt-overhang As pointed
out by Lang et al (1996), firms with high growth oppor-
tunities are likely to self-select into a low debt state in
order to take advantage of future investment opportunity
They essentially substitute debt for (external) equity Firms
with high investment opportunities choose low-debt states
in order to minimize the risk of under-investment (high
debt leads to under-investment) Another argument is dis-
cussed by Jensen (1986) and applies more to firms with
limited growth opportunities Managers are believed to
have a strong preference for increasing firm scale irrespec-
tively of the quality of the projects undertaken The extent
to which managers can undertake his suboptimal expan-
sion depends on the amount of free cash flow available
Higher leverage imposes more financial pressure on man-
agers and reduces the amount of funds that could be used
to finance poor investment projects Such funds are in fact
put aside to meet interest payments under the threat of
bankruptcy (see Nickell and Nicolitsas, 1999) Leverage is
tailored to reduce undesired poorly-planned investment
(especially in firms with low investment opportunities) and
induce managers to pursue efficiency and select only prof-
itable investment plans This ultimately should improve
firm’s performance and increase its value Even in this
case, though, the assumption is that firms enjoy substantial
degrees of freedom when setting their financial structure
In the case of listed firms, their investment capacity does
not depend (or not only) on the level of debt because they
can collect outside funds via the issue of new stocks, and
the choice of the most appropriate level of debt is made
to tame agency conflicts The empirical evidence seems
to support the theoretical predictions delivered by these
agency models: Lang et al (1996), Aiavazian et al (2005)
and Hovakimian (2009) have found a negative relationship
between leverage and investment/growth Yet, these stud-
ies are all based on samples of listed firms By contrast, the
extent to which unlisted firms can adjust their financial
structure in response to such conflicts is much more limited
as long as they do not have access to outside equity Also,
10 See Bernanke et al (1996) and Lang et al (1996)
for an unlisted firm, there is a much tighter link between its investment capacity-growth and debt finance Suppose that a firm with limited internal resources has a new profit- able investment opportunity It will respond to it by trying
to obtain the outside funds (i.e loans) necessary to real- ize the positive net-present-value investment Cooley and Quadrini (2001) recognize that “more debt allows them to expand the production scale and increase their expected profits” It is natural to think that fast growing firms will have a greater demand for finance, as acknowledged by Fazzari et al (2000) In similar vein, Guariglia et al (2008) associate leverage with the availability of more resources and hence growth As long as these firms do not fully pay off their debt at the end of each period, they will build up cumulated debt over time and their growth process will be for the most part debt-driven Hence we expect to observe
a positive association between growth and leverage Empirical evidence in support of this argument is start- ing to emerge from studies on small medium enterprises For instance, Guariglia et al (2008), working on a large sample of unlisted Chinese firms, find that leverage has a strong positive effect on asset growth Honjo and Harada (2006) use data on Japanese manufacturing firms and find that leverage has a positive effect on sales growth The same positive effect of leverage on sales growth has been detected by Huynh and Petrunia (2010) working
on Canadian manufacturing firms The present discussion shows that there are counteracting dynamics that can ulti- mately account for the observed relationship between debt and growth A positive association between leverage and growth should be expected at lower levels of debt up to the point where excessive exposure triggers some perverse dynamics (liquidity effect—debt overhang) that depress the firm performance For this reason, our second research hypothesis is that the relationship between growth and debt-exposure should follow an inverted U-shape
4 Data and descriptive statistics
We employ a dataset provided by the Italian Account Data Service Centrale dei Bilanci, CeBi.11 CeBi was founded
in the early 1980s and it is now recognized by the Italian banking system as an institutional provider of information
on firms, and its long-term reputation guarantees the reli- ability of the data Our sample comprises limited liability firms whose accounting books must by law be made pub- licly available at the Chambers of Commerce CeBi collects information, organizes it and performs preliminary clean- ing In particular, only balance sheets complying with the IV EEC directive are considered For these reasons, we expect the bias due to measurement errors to be relatively small and the information reported to be reliable
The database contains records of balance sheets and asset structure for firms operating in the manufactur- ing sector from 1998 to 2003 Firms have been grouped together according to their ATECO code of principal
1 All the data have been made available to us by the Research Office
“Pianificazione, Strategie e Studi” at Unicredit Bank under the mandatory condition of censorship of any individual information.
Trang 5activity: manufacturing sector includes firms that have the
two-digits ATECO code from 15 to 36.12
The dataset to which we have access contains firms with
total sales larger than 1 million euros and with at least
two employees As pointed out in previous works based
on the same dataset (see Bottazzi et al., 2008), one should
try to focus on entities characterized by a minimum level
of organizational structure and leave self-employment-
related phenomena out of the picture Moreover, Bottazzi
et al (2008) explain how firms with only one employee
appear to be very different from the rest of the population
in terms of structure of production The 1 million euros cut-
off is another restriction imposed to identify true firms,
and this is a fairly standard threshold.!? In addition to
these filters, we discarded those firms with a growth rate
of employees larger than 200 percent and lower than —100
percent, in order to eliminate outliers due to badly reported
data and minimize the probability of including anomalous
growth rates possibly due to mergers
Firms that did not have complete records on our main
regression variables were also dropped.'* After applying
these filters, we are left with a sample of 9274 firms sur-
viving from 1998 to 2003 continuously observed for six
years
Note that as we are dealing with ratios, we need not take
explicitly into account the issue of inflation Given the short
time dimension, this is likely not to be a major problem
anyway
For the purpose of the analysis, we focused on two key-
variables In first place we considered cash flow (CF) as a
flow measure of firm liquidity
Cash flow is defined as the sum of net profits, amortiza-
tion and depreciation and proxies the firm’s self-financing
capacity
As in Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006), we use cash flow scaled
by firm sales (SCF) This seems to be a better proxy for
firm liquidity since it is less sensitive than cash flow (CF)
to shifts in firm size We verify that the correlation coeffi-
cient between firm cash flow and size is large Once cash
flow is scaled by firm size, the correlation coefficient falls
to almost zero This explains why we have decided to adopt
scaled cash flow instead of cash flow s a measure of firm
liquidity
We employ the leverage ratio (LEV) as a stock measure
of indebtedness Following the empirical literature, LEV is
computed as total (non-equity) liabilities/total assets.!5
12 The ATECO classification is released by the Italian Statistical Office and
by and large is equivalent to the European NACE 1.1 taxonomy
13 Among others, recent studies using the same filter are Fagiolo and
Luzzi (2006) and Bottazzi et al (2011)
14 The original dataset containing information on financial and real vari-
ables consists of a sample of about 146.000 firm-year observations The
sample drastically shrinks to 96,883 observation when firms with less
than 2 employees and less than 1 million sales are discarded Once suspi-
cious growth rates are removed, we only keep observations with complete
records, and the final unbalanced filtered sample comprises, on average,
slightly more than 13.300 firms per year We compared the descriptive
statistics of the unbalanced and balanced panel and the two samples
appeared to be very similar Therefore we regard survival bias as a minor
problem here
15 A non-exhaustive list of papers that rely on this measure would cer-
tainly include Lang et al (1996), Heshmati (2001), Oliveira and Fortunato
The descriptive statistics in Table Al in appendix show
that scaled cash flow fluctuates around 0.07.!° It is worth
noting a negative trend from 1999 onwards with cash flow falling more markedly in 2003 together with real GDP growth.!” Cash flow is a largely pro-cyclical variable and, not surprisingly, its evolution over time follows those of average growth rates The worsening of cash-flow avail- ability towards the end of the time-span is confirmed by the percentage of firms exhibiting negative cash-flow In fact this is around 3 percent in the first years but reaches
7 percent in 2003 The average for the leverage ratio is around 75 percent.!® This is substantially higher than is observed in countries such as the US Berger and Udell (1998) report that the average value for US small medium enterprises is slightly higher than 50 percent Michaelas
et al (1999) find a leverage ratio of slightly more than 40 percent in the UK for small business enterprises operat- ing in all sectors Nonetheless, Italy is not the only country whose firms exhibit a high reliance on debt.!9 For instance, similar levels of leverage are found by Honjo and Harada (2006) working on Japanese manufacturing firms, Huynh and Petrunia (2010) using Canadian data on manufactur- ing firms, Guariglia et al (2008) on Chinese (state-owned) firms, Heshmati (2001) on Swedish data, and Oliveira and Fortunato (2006b) on Spanish firms A negative trend is rather evident in the evolution of the leverage ratio This is likely to be due to the fact that over the period 1998-2003 the tax-advantage of debt reduced in Italy as new limits on the amount of passive interests deductible were introduced
with a new system based on DIT — Irap.2°
5 Empirical analysis Following Guariglia et al (2008), we initially estimated a dynamic growth model, augmented for cash-flow Firm growth rate was computed as:
model reads as follows:
GROWTH; ; = 8 GROWTH; ;¢-1 + Bo SCFi.t—1
(2006b, 2008), Guney et al (2007), Guariglia et al (2008), Aiavazian et al (2005), Honjo and Harada (2006) and Huynh and Petrunia (2010)
16 This level of scaled cash-flow is quite in line with previous evidence from other European countries See Fagiolo and Luzzi (2006), Carpenter and Petersen (2002), Oliveira and Fortunato (2006a), Michaelas et al (1999) and Hernando and Martinez-Carrascal (2003)
17 Real GDP growth constantly fell from 3.7 in 2000 to 0 in 2003 Source: http://www.imforg
18 This finding is in line with previous works on the financial structure
of non-financial firms in Italy For instance, see Di Majo et al (2005), Rajan and Zingales (1995) or Guiso (2003)
13 Tt is well known that in Italy it is very hard to raise external capital, so that firms are forced to resort to debt finance Venture Capital investment
in Italy in 2000 was 7 percent of GDP while in the US it was up to 78 per- cent (Bottazzi and Da Rin, 2002) In a recent research study performed by Capitalia, only 0.7 percent of firms had a capital structure characterized
by a shared ownership Furthermore, venture capital amounts to only 2 percent of such a tiny subset L’Associazione Italiana degli Investitori Isti- tuzionali nel Capitale di Rischio (Aifi) reports that venture capital operation were remarkably few and even decreasing in the period considered, from
646 in 2000 to 301 in 2002
20 See Bontempi et al (2004) for a detailed review of the tax-reform.
Trang 6where the error term 7;; may contain both unobservable
time-invariant individual effects (œ;), and an idiosyncratic
error I.1.D (€;;), that is: nj; =a; + €¡; Following earlier stud-
ies, such as Oliveira and Fortunato (2006a), Fagiolo and
Luzzi (2006) or Evans (1987), we first concentrate on
growth in terms of firm employment Employment is a con-
venient choice because data are readily available in real
terms More importantly, it is certainly a variable of inter-
est because it is the main target of labor market policies
Employment can be seen as an input in the production
process, and we complement the analysis by also checking
the robustness of our findings with respect to an output
measure of growth To this end, as in Huynh and Petrunia
(2010), we use sales growth as an alternative indicator of
firm performance.?!
The econometric specification in all of our regres-
sions features the variable CONTROLS, which includes time
dummies to control for business cycle and macroeconomic
effects, sectoral dummies to control for industry effects and
firm localization.22 For the reason discussed in Section 2,
we also add to our set of controls some firm-specific char-
acteristics such as age and size.”3
Following, the literature, our preferred estimation
method consists of the system GMM system.”4 The choice
can be justified on three grounds: first, these models con-
trol for individual fixed effects by estimating the equation
both in levels and in first differences Second, the GMM sys-
tem is also known to yield consistent coefficient estimates
in the presence of endogenous regressors.*° More specif-
ically, endogeneity is tackled by instrumenting regressors
with their own lagged levels for the first-differenced equa-
tion and with their own lagged first differences for the
equation in levels Finally, the GMM system should be
preferred to the difference GMM because our explanatory
variables are heavily persistent and show high levels of
serial correlation In this case, lagged variables in levels
are poor instruments of the variables in first differences
Adding the levels-equation and using lagged differences
of the explanatory variables as instruments significantly
improve the efficiency of the model by reducing the weak-
instrument bias
We check the validity of instruments using a Hansen J-
test for over-identifying restrictions and the test for serial
21 Sales growth is log difference of total sales measured at constant
prices
22 Sectoral dummies are defined as the first two digits in ATECO classifi-
cation The ATECO sector classification mirrors to a great extent the NACE
one Firms localization is captured by adopting a set of dummy variables,
corresponding to geographical macro areas North-East, North-West, Cen-
ter and South of Italy
23 We initially only control for age The results are reported in Table 1
They do not change qualitatively when size is added as control The esti-
mates are set out in Table A3 (columns I and II) in the appendix
24 The estimator was fully developed by Blundell and Bond (1998) For
an application of this econometric method on firm-level data, see Oliveira
and Fortunato (2006a), D’Espallier and Guariglia (2009) and Coad (2007)
25 Endogeneity can arise from reverse causation For instance, one could
argue that cash-flow is clearly endogenous because high-growth firms
will generate high profits and therefore high cash-flow GMM estimators
account for this potential endogeneity bias and have been regularly used
in the financing constraints literature See, for example, Bond et al (2003)
and D’Espallier and Guariglia (2009)
correlation First-order and second-order serial correlation
in the first-differenced residuals is tested using m1 and m2 statistics The validity of the dynamic model is ver- ified if there is no second-order serial correlation in the differenced residuals (meaning that the €;; are serially uncorrelated) and the J-test accepts the null of instruments validity Both conditions appear to be valid in our model The estimates of the baseline model are presented in
Table 1 column 1.76
In line with similar studies (Fagiolo and Luzzi, 2006; Oliveira and Fortunato, 2006a), we find that cash flow is positively correlated with firm growth
The point estimate (0.183 in column! in Table 1) implies that the elasticity evaluated at sample means is around 0.88, suggesting that a 10 percent increase in cash-flow brings about a 8.8 percent increase in employment growth
In order to test our hypotheses, we proceed as fol- lows: first we estimate the same model adding LEV as explanatory variable As we believe in a inverted U-shape relationship between employment growth and leverage,
we add a quadratic term LEV2, to capture possible non-
linearities.27
GROWTH; + = By GROWTH; ¢_1 + BoSCF; t-4 + B3LEV; +4
+aLEVỆ,_¡ + ÿ CONTROLS,_ + 1c — (2)
Our Họ, consistently with the hypothesis outlined at the end of Section 3, ¡is that Ø64>0 and Ø6s<0, and the non- linear effect may be so strong that the marginal effect switches sign Table 1 column II reports the estimates for this model-specification The results confirm that the effect
of debt-exposure is non-linear over the support of LEV In more detail, we see that LEV initially engenders a positive effect for firms but such influence turns negative for other highly indebted firms We can compute the marginal effect
OEMP _GRI/OLEV, and this becomes negative for values of LEV larger than 0.642.2° Note that only about 25 percent of
firms exhibit a leverage ratio below this threshold In other words, most firms are to some extent debt-constrained in that their current level of debt proves to be detrimental to growth
In the previous section, we discussed the possible interactions among cash-flow, leverage and investment opportunities, and we made the point that an omitted vari- able bias could arise simply because we do not control
26 In Table A2 in appendix, one can compare the GMM-system estimates with the pooled OLS and fixed-effect estimates In dynamic panels with endogenous variables, it has been shown that OLS and fixed-effects yield biased (upward and downward, respectively) estimators The GMM esti- mate of the coefficient on the lagged dependent variable is found to be
in between the OLS and the fixed-effects estimates, and this suggests no serious finite sample bias A coefficient attached to lagged growth close to
or higher than the FE estimates could also raise doubts as to the strength
of instruments (see Carpenter and Guariglia, 2008) This does not seem to
be the case here
27 This specification follows Guney et al (2007), who examine the non- linear effect of leverage on cash-holdings
28 This threshold has been computed using the point estimates displayed
in column II of Table 1
Trang 7
Table 1
Main regression table part
EMP _GRit-1 —0.041”” (0.013) —0.041”” (0.013) —0.042””(0.013) —0.041”” (0.013) —0.041”” (0.013)
SChịt | 0.183" (0.058) 0.17777(0.059) 0.174” (0.059) 0.107” (0.045)
(SCF x HighLEV);¿_¡
(SCF x LowLEV);¿_¡
LEV; 4-1 0.606" (0.191) 0.620” (0.1 90)
interacted with
ind dummies
Number of firms 36,627 36,627 36,627
Hansen Jj-test [0.501] [0.280] [0.925]
(P-value)
m2(P-value) [0.795] [0.751] [0.748]
0.374” (0.079)
~0.574"" (0.150) —0.460””(0.122) -—0.4717” (0.165) -0.563” (0.165)
Notes: All results in this table are obtained using a system GMM estimator The figures reported in parentheses are robust standard errors Instruments
in all columns are lags two or three of all regressors except age in the differenced equation, and lag one or two of the difference of all regressors except age in the levels equation In column V, we report the estimates obtained by adding further lags as instruments Lagged age is assumed to be exogenous Firm’s age, time, sectoral and geographical dummies are used as controls The m1 and m2 statistics are tests for first and second-order serial correlation
in the first-differenced residuals and they are asymptotically distributed as N(O, 1) under the null of no serial correlation; P-values are reported in square brackets The Hansen’s J statistics, under the null of instrument validity, is asymptotically distributed as a x? with degrees of freedom equal to the number
of instruments less the number of parameters J is employed to test the validity of overidentifying restrictions; P-values are reported in square brackets
*P<0.1
7” P<0.05
7” P<0.01
for future investment opportunity The positive coefficient
attached to cash-flow could simply pick up this bias, and
hence it would not be informative about the extent of finan-
cial constraints
Following Carpenter and Guariglia (2008) and Guariglia
et al (2008), we attempt to control for investment opportu-
nities as follows We use the time dummies interacted with
industry dummies as our proxy These dummies account
for all time-varying demand shocks at the industry level
One can think of this as an indirect way to control for invest-
ment opportunities, or more in general demand factors
In Table 1 column III we show the results on Eq (2)
augmented to control for investment opportunities The
coefficient attached to cash flow remains positive and
significant, even after accounting for investment opportu-
nities, and the size of the coefficient is very similar We
conclude that the investment opportunities are not a great
source of bias The same applies to the leverage ratio
As discussed at the end of Section 2, we now want to
assess the extent to which cash flow sensitivity depends
on the level of leverage
To this end, we also add two interaction terms
extent to which being highly leveraged makes the firm
more sensitive to internal cash-flow.?9
Our third and final specification takes the following
form:
22 More specifically, LowLEV is a dummy variable that takes value 1 if
leverage is below the median and 0 otherwise HighLEV takes value 1 if
leverage is above the median and zero otherwise This empirical approach
is similar to that used by Carpenter and Guariglia (2008) and others
+ B3 (SCF x LowLEV); +1 + Ba LEV;_1 + Bs LEV? 4
+ € CONTROLS; ¢-1 + Nit (3)
Our Hg is that $2 > 63, so that the marginal effect of cash- flow on growth increases with leverage Table 1 column IV reports the estimated coefficients and indeed shows that the more firms are leveraged, the more growth is sensitive
to cash-flow.39
We also performed a number of robustness checks and the results are presented in Table A3 in appendix First, we re-estimate the model adding size to the set of controls and we do not find any significant difference.?! Second, we check how cash flow sensitivity changes with leverage by stratifying the sample in three subgroups We construct three dummy variables as follows: LEVq; takes value 1 if firm’s leverage is in the bottom 25 percent of the distribu- tion LEVqy_);7 is equal to 1 when firm’s leverage falls into the second or third quartile of the distribution, and finally LEVqyy is set equal to 1 for firm being in the top quartile of the leverage distribution As before, we let these dummies interact with cash flow and the estimates are reported in column III of Table A3 Results are consistent and provide even stronger evidence that cash flow sensitivities increase with leverage As will be seen, the firms in the bottom
30 In column V of Table 1, we also report the estimates obtained with a larger set of instruments The results are qualitatively the same
31 Size at time t—1 is defined as log(SALES);.-1
Trang 8
Low Leverage —-—-— Medium Leverage .rem High Leverage
Fig 1 Cash-flow distribution conditional to leverage
quartile of the leverage distribution are not sensitive to
cash flow at all, and such firms are also those for which
leverage appears to exert a positive effect on growth Lastly,
we also check the estimates using the unbalanced panel
The results, displayed in columns IV and V in Table A3,
remain consistent.32
Highly indebted firms are not only more sensitive to
cash-flow, but they are also endowed with less internal
funds, as documented in Fig 1.37
It is interesting to compare these results with those
obtained using sales growth as dependent variable
Table 1 columns VI and VII show that the previous
findings carry over when we measure growth with
respect to sales Two remarks are in order First, we
see that sales growth is somewhat less sensitive to
cash flow than employment growth Second, the critical
threshold above which the marginal effect of lever-
age becomes negative is found at an even lower value
(0.53)
6 Conclusions
In this paper, we have provided a unified framework to
jointly assess the debate on cash-flow sensitivities and the
debt-growth nexus at firm level More in detail, two main
hypotheses have been discussed and verified empirically
First, we believe that the degree of financial constraints
increases with leverage and therefore more indebted firms
should exhibit higher growth-cash flow sensitivity Second,
we have examined the channels through which leverage
can impact on growth with particular emphasis on the role
of leverage for unlisted small medium enterprises In this
32 By unbalanced panel we mean a sample in which the number of time
periods available is not necessarily the same for all firms and the points
in time to which the observations correspond may also be different We
also restrict the sample to firms that are continuously observed with no
gaps for at least 4 contiguous observations
33 In line with our robustness check, low-leverage firms are those in the
first quartile of the leverage distribution, medium leverage firms are those
in the second, and third quartile and high-leverage firms are those in the
top quartile
world, leverage represents the primary means of exter- nal financing and as such it should favor firm’s expansion and ultimately promote growth Nonetheless, there may
be a critical level above which excessive debt exposure can trigger negative dynamics induced by debt overhang and liquidity effects that act as a drag on growth Thus
we maintain that a non-linear inverted U-shape relation- ship is likely to be detected between growth and leverage Using a large sample of Italian manufacturing firms tracked over the period 1998-2007, we have found robust evidence that there is a non-linear impact of debt on growth As hypothesized, leverage initially exerts a positive effect of growth Our analysis shows that only about 20-25 per- cent of firms have a level of indebtedness that turns out
to be growth-enhancing The estimates suggest that a tip- ping point for leverage does exist, and it stands at around 0.65 and 0.53 for the employment growth regression and sales growth regression respectively Above this threshold, debt constrains growth, and this is found to be the case for the vast majority of firms in our sample We think of these firms as being debt-constrained Overall, one can charac- terize fragile firms as heavily indebted and endowed with relatively little cash-flow This lack of cash-flow is more likely to be binding and explains why such firms appear to
be more sensitive to internal funds Our results are robust
to measuring growth in terms of both sales and number
of employees, to controlling for firm’s specific character- istics and investment opportunities, and to using either
a balanced or an unbalanced panel The message is that Italian firms are too indebted, and the policy implication
is that efforts should be made in order to ease the access
to financing options based on external equity and venture capital These interventions are likely to be most effec- tive if targeted on highly leveraged firms Summing up, the present analysis contributes to the existing literature
in two ways: first it sheds some light on the complex non- linear financial structure-growth nexus Second, it enters the debate on the interpretation of cash-flow sensitivity by providing evidence that, within this framework, such dif- ferences in sensitivities are indeed meaningful and can be viewed as the result of some firms being constrained both internally and externally There is much scope for further research For example, it would be interesting establish the extent to which this inverted U-shape between growth and leverage is detected in other industries or countries Provided that a tipping point exists, it would be impor- tant to understand what factors account for its empirical value
Acknowledgements
I wish to thank Alessandro Ghillino for his support with the data, and the members of the Research Office
“Pianificazione, Strategie e Studi” at Unicredit Research Centre I am indebted to Frank Windmeijer for invaluable help on econometric issues Thanks go to Giorgio Fagi- olo, Silvia Giannangeli, Graziano Coller, Stefano Schiavo, Alex Coad, Claudia Vittori, Fabio Monteforte and Marcela Umana-Aponte for their comments at various stages of the research process The paper has also greatly benefited from the comments made by three anonymous referees Finally,
Trang 9
Appendix A
See Tables A1-A3
Table Al
Descriptive statistics
EMP_GR
SALES _GR
LEV
SCF
Table A2
Baseline model
See explanatory notes to Table 1 *P<0.1 **P<0.05
7” P<0.01.
Trang 10
Table A3
Additional regressions
with ind dummies
Notes: See also explanatory notes to Table 1 All results in this table are obtained using a system GMM estimator Estimates reported in columns | to III are obtained using the balanced panel Columns IV and V show the results obtained with the unbalanced panel Columns I and II report the estimates obtained when firm’s size was also included as an additional control *P< 0.1
™ P<0.05
™ P<0.01
References
Audretsch, D., Elston, J., 2002 Does firm size matter? Evidence on
the impact of liquidity constraints on firm investment behaviour
in Germany International Journal of Industrial Organization 20,
1-17
Aiavazian, V.A., Ge, Y., Qiu, J., 2005 The impact of leverage on firm
investment: Canadian evidence Journal of Corporate Finance 11,
277-291
Berger, A.N., Udell, G.F., 1998 The economics of small business finance:
the roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth
cycle Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 613-673
Bernanke, B.S., Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1996 The financial accelerator
and the flight to quality The Review of Economics and Statistics 78,
1-15
Blundell, R., Bond, S., 1998 Initial conditions and moment restrictions in
dynamic panel data models Journal of Econometrics 87, 115-143
Bond, S., Elston, J., Mairesse, J., Mulkay, B., 2003 Financial factors and the
investment in Belgium, France, Germany, and the United Kingdom: a
comparison using company panel data The Review of Economics and
Statistics 85, 153-165
Bontempi, E., Giannini, S., Golinelli, R., 2004 Corporate taxation and its
reform: the effects on corporate financing decisions in Italy Working
Papers 501, Dipartimento Scienze Economiche, Universita’ di Bologna
Bottazzi, L, Da Rin, M., 2002 Venture capital in Europe and the
financing of innovative companies Economic Policy 17, 229-
270
Bottazzi, G., Secchi, A., Tamagni, F., 2008 Productivity profitability and
financial performance Industrial and Corporate Change, Oxford Uni-
versity Press 17, 711-751
Bottazzi, G., Grazzi, M., Secchi, A Tamagni, F., 2011 Financial and
economic determinants of firm default Journal of Evolutionary Eco-
nomics 21, 373-406
Cabral, L., Mata, J., 2003 On the evolution of the firm size distribution:
facts and theory American Economic Review 93, 1075-1090
Carpenter, R.E., Petersen, B.C., 2002 Is the growth of small firms con-
strained by internal finance? The Review of Economics and Statistics,
MIT Press 84, 298-309
Carpenter, R.E., Guariglia, A., 2008 Cash flow investment and investment
opportunities: new tests using UK panel data Journal of Banking and
Finance 32, 1894-1906
Chirinko, R., Schaller, H., 1995 Why does liquidity matter in investment
equations? Journal of Money Credit and Banking 27, 527-548
Cleary, S., 1999 The relationship between firm investment and financial
status Journal of Finance 54, 673-692
Cleary, S., Povel, P., Raith, M., 2007 The U-shaped investment curve:
theory and evidence Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,
Cambridge University Press 42, 1-39
Coad, A., 2007 Testing the principle of growth of the fitter: the relationship between profits and firm growth Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 18, 370-386
Cooley, T.F., Quadrini, V., 2001 Financial markets and firm dynamics American Economic Review 91, 1286-1310
D’Espallier, B., Guariglia, A., 2009 Does the investment opportunities bias affect the investment-cash flow sensitivities of unlisted SMEs? Open Access publications from Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven
Devereux, M., Schiantarelli, F., 1990 Investment, financial factors and cash flow: evidence from U.K panel data In: Hubbard, G (Ed.), Information, Capital Markets and Investment University of Chicago Press
Di Majo, A., Pazienza, M.G., Tirberti, A., 2005 Scelte di Finanziamento delle Imprese Minori Teorie e Analisi del Caso Italiano Working Paper 7, DISEFIN-Dipartimento di Scienze Economiche e Finanziarie, Univer- sity of Genova
Evans, D., 1987 The relationship between firm growth, size and age: estimates for 100 manufacturing industries Journal of Industrial Eco- nomics 35, 567-581
Fagiolo, G., Luzzi, A., 2006 Do liquidity constraints matter in explaining firm size and growth? Some evidence form the Italian manufacturing industry Industrial Corporate Change 15, 1-39
Fazzari, S.M., Hubbard, R.G., Petersen, B.C., 1988 Financial constraints and corporate investment Brooking Papers on Economic Activity 1, 141-206
Fazzari, S.M., Hubbard, R.G., Petersen, B.C., 2000 Financial constraints and corporate investment: response to Kaplan and Zingales NBER Work- ing Papers 5642, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc Gertler, M., Gilchrist, S., 1994 Monetary policy business cycles and the behavior of small manufacturing firms Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics 109, 309-340
Gilchrist, S., Himmelberg, C.P., 1995 Evidence on the role of cash flow for investment Journal of Monetary Economics 36, 541-572
Guariglia, A., Liu, X., Song, L., 2008 Internal finance and growth: microe- conometric evidence on Chinese firms IZA Discussion Papers 3808, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA)
Guiso, L., 2003 Small Business Finance in Italy EIB PAPERS 2, vol.7 Guney, Y., Ozkan, A., Ozkan, N., 2007 International evidence on the non-linear impact of leverage on corporate cash holdings Journal of Multinational Financial Management 17, 45-60
Hernando, I., Martinez-Carrascal, C., 2003 The impact of financial vari- ables on firms real decisions: evidence from Spanish firm-level data Banco de Espana Working Papers 0319
Heshmati, A., 2001 The dynamics of capital structure: evidence from Swedish micro and small firms SSE-EFI Working Paper Series in Eco- nomics and Finance, 440
Honjo, Y., Harada, N., 2006 SME policy financial structure and firm growth: evidence from Japan Small Business Economics 27, 289-300.