Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 50 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
50
Dung lượng
326,33 KB
Nội dung
i
ABSTRACT
This paper is an empirical analysis ofthe gains from contract farming inthecase
of poultry production inthe state of Andhra Pradesh in India. The paper finds that
contract production is more efficient than noncontract production. Theefficiency surplus
is largely appropriated by the processor. Despite this, contractgrowers still gain
appreciably from contracting in terms of lower risk and higher expected returns.
Improved technology and production practices as well as the way in which the processor
selects growers are what make these outcomes possible. In terms of observed and
unobserved characteristics, contractgrowers have relatively poor prospects as
independent growers. With contract production, these growers achieve incomes
comparable to that of independent growers.
Keywords: Contract Farming, Contracting, Poultry, Vertical Integration
ii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
1. Introduction 1
2. ThePoultry Industry in Andhra Pradesh 3
3. Contracting inPoultry Production 4
4. Data and Descriptive Statistics 5
5. Is Contract Production more Efficient? 11
6. Do ContractGrowers Earn More than Noncontract Growers? 18
7. Correcting for Self-Selection 20
8. Risk Shifting from Contracting 27
9. Concluding Remarks 32
References 35
iii
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1: Access to Infrastructure 6
Table 2: Characteristics ofPoultry Producers 7
Table 3: Input Use by Poultry Producers: Averages Per Production Cycle 8
Table 4: Output and Revenues: Averages Per Production Cycle 9
Table 5: Input Sharing: Averages per Production Cycle 10
Table 6: Cost structure ofPoultry Production: Averages per Production Cycle 12
Table 7: Cost function ofPoultry Producers 13
Table 8: Feed-Conversion Ratios 17
Table 9: Returns to Poultry Producers: Average Income Per Production Cycle
(Rs/Kg) 22
Table 10: Income Equation: Ordinary Least Squares 23
Table 11: OLS estimates of Treatment Effects Under Varying Interest Rates 24
Table 12: Probit Equation: Factors Influencing Participation in Contracting 26
Table 13: Income Equation: Instrument Variables 26
Table 14: IV estimates of Treatment Effects Under Varying Interest Rates 27
Table 15: Variability of Returns 28
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1: Cost Function for Noncontract Producers 13
Figure 2: Cost Function for Contract Producers 14
1
EFFICIENCY ANDDISTRIBUTIONINCONTRACTFARMING:
THE CASEOFINDIANPOULTRYGROWERS
Bharat Ramaswami
1
, Pratap Singh Birthal
2
, and P.K. Joshi
3
1. INTRODUCTION
A feature of low productivity agricultural economies is the dominance of
subsistence production especially among small growers. Even though commercialization
can yield substantial gains, the transition from subsistence farming to market driven
production is fraught with perils (von Braun and Kennedy, 1994). First, market volatility
is an enduring feature of commodity and livestock markets. This makes cultivation of
cash crops and livestock risky. Second, as incomes grow, consumer taste shifts in favor
of processed foods. Small farmers are too remote from consumers to track their
preferences. Third, small farmers typically lack capital and technical expertise to
undertake cash crop and livestock production, which are usually more input intensive
than subsistence crops. These problems are serious enough that they could effectively
choke off participation in markets by all except the large farmers.
In principle, contract farming could be an institutional arrangement that enables
farmers to access markets. While contractual arrangements can vary by crop and by
country, contracting is a form of joint production where the grower supplies tools, land,
labor and management while the processor supplies technical assistance, some inputs
such as seeds or pesticides and undertakes to buy the grower’s output at a pre-determined
1
Professor, Indian Statistical Institute, New Delhi, India.
2
National Fellow, National Centre for Agricultural Economics and Policy Research, New Delhi, India.
3
Research Fellow, IFPRI New Delhi Office, New Delhi, India.
2
price. From the point of view ofthe processor, this arrangement ensures raw material
supplies ofthe desired quality (subject, of course, to production uncertainty). From the
point of view ofthe grower, such an arrangement provides an assured market and hence
reliable income (to the extent permitted by production risks). Without a contract, risks
would be too much and few small growers would want to produce these crops. For this
reason, Glover (1987) described contract farming as an institutional arrangement that
combined the advantages of plantations (quality control, coordination of production and
marketing) andof smallholder production (superior incentives, equity considerations).
These theoretical benefits, notwithstanding, contract farming has been
controversial and has been criticized for being exploitative (Little and Watts, 1994).
Between the giant corporation andthe small farmer, bargaining power surely lies with the
former. Also, in practice, growers have encountered problems with respect to
manipulation of quality standards, poor technical assistance, and sometimes plain
cheating and deliberate default (Glover, 1987). As a result, Glover (1987) concluded that
research must “systematically examine successes and failures and from then draw
generalizations about the conditions under which CF (contract farming) can operate
profitably and to the benefit of small farmers” (p 447).
Taking this imperative seriously, this paper is an empirical analysis ofthe gains
from contract farming, to both farmers and processors, inthecaseofpoultry production
in the state of Andhra Pradesh in India. The literature on contract farming is largely
anecdotal possibly because of lack of data. Knoeber and Thurman (1995) and Warning
and Key (2002) are two exceptions. Knoeber and Thurman analyzed the redistribution of
3
risk because of contracting in hog production in U.S.A. Warning and Key estimated the
change in producer incomes from contracting by peanut producers in Senegal. Here we
draw upon a survey ofcontractand noncontract poultry producers to analyze both of
these issues. Neither of these papers, however, considers the gains to the processors from
contracting.
2. THEPOULTRY INDUSTRY IN ANDHRA PRADESH
The poultry industry has seen rapid growth in India. Between 1980/81 and
1998/99, poultry meat production increased about 3 times from 250,000 tons to about
770,000 tons.
4
Correspondingly, its share of total meat output rose from 20% to 27%.
During the same period, egg production increased from 10,000 to 29,000 million. Andhra
Pradesh is the leading poultry meat producing state within India. It accounts for over
one-fifth ofpoultry meat as well as egg production inthe country. The growth ofpoultry
industry in Andhra Pradesh has been even more remarkable than the national growth
rates. For the period 1980/81 to 1998/99, poultry meat production increased by 4.5 times
while egg production rose by 3.5 times. About 30% of its broiler output and 15% of egg
output are exported to other states within India.
The impressive growth inthepoultry meat industry is the result of technological
breakthroughs in breeding, feeding and health, and sizeable investments from the private
sector. The expansion in supply has been spurred by rising incomes and has resulted in
lower poultry prices in south India where much ofthe growth has occurred (USDA,
4
The USDA estimates poultry production in 2002 to be ofthe order of 1.4 million tons, which is higher
than the official estimates (USDA, 2004).
4
2004). Thepoultry sector is, however, highly prone to production and market risks,
which periodically affect the profitability of broiler production particularly on the small
farms. These risks also threaten the profitability ofthe industry engaged in breeding of
chicks and manufacturing of feed, vaccines and medicines. In order to minimize the risks
to the producers and sustain the profitability ofthe industry, some large poultry firms (for
example, Venkateshawara Hatcheries Ltd., Suguna Hatcheries, Pioneer Hatcheries,
Diamond Hatcheries, etc.) began integrating their activities with that of broiler
production through the institution ofcontract farming as early as in late 1980s. A large-
scale integrated operation would typically include the raising of grandparent and parent
flocks, rearing of day-old-chicks, feed milling, provision of veterinary services and
contract production. Such integrators are most common in southern and western regions
of the country (USDA, 2004).
3. CONTRACTING INPOULTRY PRODUCTION
In a poultry contract, hatcheries provide day-old chicks, feed and medicines to contract
growers. Thecontractgrowers supply land, labor and other variable inputs (like
electricity). At the end ofthe production cycle, the farmer receives a net price (by
weight) that is pegged to an industry price set by a group of hatcheries (not the retail
price). The industry price fluctuates within a narrow range and is a lot more stable than
the retail price. Thus, the farmer receives considerable price insurance. For sharp
upward deviations ofthe retail price from the industry price, farmers receive an incentive.
[...]... labor, and other variable inputs such as electricity and disinfectants Using the information on input sharing, Table 5 computes the total value of variable inputs andthe value of inputs supplied by the grower For the farmers not on contract, the two figures are the same But this is not so for contractgrowers For them, the processor supplies most of the inputs measured in value terms On average, the. .. The final section ofthe survey is relevant only to contract farmers and it obtained information about thecontract between the producer andthe processor In particular, this section contains information about the nature of input sharing between the producer andthe processor As noted inthe earlier section, processors supply chicks, medicine, feed and veterinary services Growers supply land, buildings,... noncontract growers respectively They are estimated as the sample means ofthe σ i ’s and vi’s and are reported inthe first two rows (and second and third columns) of Table 15 The computations assume the lowest possible interest rate of 15% per annum The table also reports the standard errors of these estimates The figures show that the variability of returns of noncontract growers exceed that ofcontract growers. .. ofthe actual series For each individual grower we compute the ratio ofthe standard deviation ofthe simulated series to the standard deviation ofthe observed series For the 25 contract growers, the average of this ratio is 13.4 The median ratio is 8.25 andthedistribution ranges from a minimum value of 2.7 to a maximum value of 91 At the median level, growers under contracting bear only 12% of the. .. veterinary fees, labor, electricity and disinfectants For contact growers, however, the processor advances most ofthe value of inputs Compared to the noncontract grower, thecontract grower needs less working capital and therefore incurs lower interest costs Information on the opportunity cost of funds for contractand noncontract farmers is, however, missing inthe survey From studies of rural finance,... CONTRACTING Calculating the mean income gains from contracting provides only a partial picture of the change in utility for contracting producers As mentioned before, a fundamental feature ofcontract farming is the shifting of risk from producers to processors Inthe broiler contract, much of the price risk is reduced by the use ofthe bro-mark (set by the processors) rather than the market price The most straightforward... price andthe feed quantity used by contractgrowers to recalculate their feed and medicine costs that would obtain if they were charged the same prices for feed and medicine as noncontract growers To these costs, we add the observed costs for chicks and other inputs that are incurred by contractgrowersand we thus obtain a simulated figure for total costs for each production cycle of thecontract 2 The. .. (81) Output x Contract -.029 (-3.9) Dummy 0.983 R2 # Observations 145 t-statistics in parentheses 17 6 DO CONTRACTGROWERS EARN MORE THAN NONCONTRACT GROWERS? Inthe earlier section, we analyzed the relative efficiency of thecontract production system taking into account the costs to both growersand processors Here we consider contracting from the point of view ofgrowers alone Do contractgrowers earn... evaluate production efficiency from the point of view ofthe processor As a processor has the choice of contracting with growers or procuring the bird from noncontracted growers, contract production should reduce processor’s costs if it is to be observed Theefficiencyofcontract production is therefore evaluated relative to the production costs of independent growers Costs incontract production... ofthe simulated series for the ith producer Also let sc denote the mean standard deviation for the group ofcontractgrowers This is reported inthe last column of Table 15 The variability ofthe simulated series is ofthe same order of magnitude as the variability of returns for noncontract growers On average, the standard deviation ofthe simulated series is more than 8 times greater than that of . analysis of the gains from contract farming in the case
of poultry production in the state of Andhra Pradesh in India. The paper finds that
contract. breeding of
chicks and manufacturing of feed, vaccines and medicines. In order to minimize the risks
to the producers and sustain the profitability of the industry,