The Reciprocal Relationship Between Military Conflict and Democracy

26 2 0
The Reciprocal Relationship Between Military Conflict and Democracy

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

The Reciprocal Relationship Between Military Conflict and Democracy August 2005 Abstract: Does democracy cause peace, or is democracy a consequence of peace? The burgeoning democratic peace literature has provided strong empirical evidence for the claim that democracies are a cause of peace However, several skeptics of the democratic peace have suggested that the statistical findings are spurious They contend that democracy is a consequence of peace That is, democratic institutions and norms grow more rapidly in a peaceful environment In this case, some other factor (e.g., geographic isolation) is the root cause of peace among democratic sates We test these competing claims using a simultaneous equation model Using a unique data set of all international disputes from 1960-1988, we find strong support for reciprocal causation As the democratic peace theorists claim, democracy causes peace even after controlling for military conflict in the system and region Conversely, peace in the region appears to encourage the development of democratic polities David L Rousseau Department of Political Science Rockefeller College of Public Affairs and Policy University at Albany (SUNY) 135 Western Avenue Albany, NY 12222 and Hyung Min Kim Department of Political Science University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill 361 Hamilton Hall, CB #3265 Chapel Hill, NC 27599-3265 Paper prepared for the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 1st – 4th, 2005, Washington, DC Please send comments to the first author INTRODUCTION Does democracy cause peace, or is democracy a consequence of peace? The enormous democratic peace literature claims democracy is a cause of peace Over the last decade a strong consensus has emerged supporting the claim that democracies not use large-scale violence against other democracies (i.e., the existence of a dyadic democratic peace) More recently, a number of scholars have demonstrated that democracies are often more peaceful in general (i.e., the existence of the monadic democratic peace) From the perspective of this literature, democratic institutions, norms or identities reduce the probably that democratic polities resort to military force to resolve international disputes But several skeptics of the democratic peace argue that democracy is a consequence of peace That is, democratic institutions and norms grow more rapidly in a peaceful environment In this case, some other factor (e.g., geographic isolation) is the root cause of peace among democratic sates Thus, skeptics such as Thompson (1996) and Layne (1994) argue that the statistical correlation between democracy and peace in the democratic peace literature is spurious The purpose of this paper is to sort out these completing claims Using a simultaneous equation model, we test both arguments in the same statistical model We find strong support for reciprocal causation As the democratic peace theorists claim, democracy causes peace even after controlling for military conflict in the system and region Conversely, the skeptics are correct in their narrow claim that peace in the region encourages the development of democratic polities However, the broader skeptical claim that the democratic peace will evaporate after controlling for conflict in the environment is not supported by our simultaneous equation model Our model contributes to the literature in five ways First, it is one of only a handful of models that directly tests for reciprocal causation Second, it employs a data set of international disputes that is broader in scope than analyses that are restricted to wars or militarized crises Third, unlike previous simultaneous equation models, the data set employs a directed dyad structure that allows us to test monadic and dyadic arguments simultaneously Fourth, the model directly compares explanations from the systemic, regional, dyadic, and monadic levels Fifth, the model employs a unique conflict initiation variable that allows a more theoretically precise test of the democratic peace side of the equation The remainder of the paper is divided into six sections The following section explores the causal mechanisms (or micro-foundations) of both halves the reciprocal relationship The second section explains the procedure and rationale for our simultaneous equation model The third section presents our hypotheses and the fourth section describes the data set The fifth section describes the results of the model and the sixth section summarizes our findings CAUSAL MECHANISMS IN THE LITERATURE Part I: Military Conflict Decreases (or Increases) Democracy Reflecting on the formation of national states in Western Europe, Tilly (1975) argues that war (and the tax systems created to pay for war) played a vital role in the development of strong states “War made the state and the state made war” (Tilly 1975, 42) Beginning with almost 500 independent political entities in 1500, Europe gradually consolidated into approximately twenty sovereign states by the start of the 20th century Many alternatives to the sovereign state, ranging from empires and city states to trading leagues and federations, fell by the wayside during the consolidation process (Spruyt 1994) Tilly argues that the costs of war increased rapidly due to three revolutionary factors: technical innovations in weapons (e.g., cannons and firearms), tactical changes in warfare (e.g., the rise of infantry), and an expansion in the size of armies Prior to these changes, rulers in the largely non-monetized feudal economic and military system had relatively few expenses and could typically manage affairs using the revenue produced from crown lands In the feudal system, land was exchanged for military service and the vassals were responsible for equipping and supplying their own troops After the technical and tactical innovations, the larger mercenary armies and their advanced weapons became horrifically expensive Desperate for additional revenue, rulers in Europe expanded the tax base and institutionalized the collection process The first bureaucratic structures were created for revenue collection The need for ever larger armies led to the extensive use of mercenaries from the 15th to the 18th century, and then to the use of conscripts during the Napoleonic Wars and the total wars of the 20th century Tilly also argues that the mobilization of fiscal and human resources triggered resistance He contends that states responded to this threat by increasing the coercive apparatus (e.g., police) to minimize disruptions For the region as a whole, the process was autocatalytic As rulers fielded even larger armies or equipped their artillery with even more accurate cannons, neighbors were forced to raise revenues in order to respond in kind The upward spiral continued in Europe for at least 600 years If war did in fact contribute to the state building process, a second question emerges: just what sort of sovereign state emerged from this violent environment? Hintze (1906), like Tilly, argues that state development is inextricably linked to military development While domestic factors such as the distribution of power between interest groups played an important role in state development, the level of external threat together with the state’s position in the international political hierarchy could be decisive "All state organization was military organization, organization for war" (1906, 181) Hintze also argues that external threats can lead to the development of autocratic institutions.1 England, with her insular security, was not directly exposed to the danger of these wars She needed no standing army, at least not one of Continental proportions, but only a navy which served commercial interests as much as war aims In consequence, she developed no absolutism Absolutism and militarism go together on the Continent just as self government and militia in England The main explanation for the difference in the way political and military organizations developed between England and the Continent one which became more and more distinct after the middle of the seventeenth century lies in the difference in the foreign situations (Hinze 1906, 199) England did not become democratic because it was either Protestant (Weber 1958), or industrialized (Smith 1965; Dahrendorf 1967), or agriculturally commercialized (Moore 1966) Rather, the lack of a persistent external threat allowed interest groups to maintain and expand political and economic privileges For Hintze, this path was simply impossible for a state such as Prussia, which had to centralize power and eliminate domestic opposition in order to efficiently mobilize the resources required to maintain independence in an anarchic world Lasswell (1941), writing at a time in which the world (but not yet the United States) had plunged into the Second World War, takes a similar position "The purpose of this article is to consider the possibility that we are moving toward a world of "garrison states" a world in which the specialists of violence are the most powerful group in society" (1941, 455) While not arguing the outcome was inevitable, Lasswell feared that mobilization for total war encouraged the authoritative allocation of resources at the expense of market allocation and the emphasis of the collective or the public at the expense of the individual or the private During war "decisions will be more dictatorial than democratic, and institutional practices long connected with modern democracy will disappear (1941, 461)." Throughout his essay, Lasswell emphasizes the role of propaganda in mobilizing resources, increasing morale, repressing dissent, socializing the young, and ritualizing democracy In sum, Lasswell echoes Hintze's contention that a hostile external environment leads to autocratic institutions but he focuses on the demise of existing modern democracies rather than the rise of embryonic autocratic states External threats can undermine pluralist institutions and norms in a number of ways First, the existence of a severe external threat can lead to the elimination of free and fair elections (e.g., the U.K suspends national elections during both World Wars) Second, during war decision-making power constitutionally vested in the legislature is often shifted to the executive branch (e.g., Germany during the First World War) Third, the hostile external environment can lead to a suspension of the rule of law in the hope of efficiently mobilizing resources (e.g., Lincoln's suspension of habeas corpus during the American Civil War (Rehnquist 1998)) Fourth, threats often lead to the expansion of the power of the military over economic and political decision making (e.g., Ludendorff's military dominated government in Germany during the First World War) Fifth, threats often lead to the barring (or removal) of individuals of suspect loyalties from holding public office (e.g., the removal of Jews from the provincial government in Vichy France in 1940) Sixth, in the face of an intense threat, even short of war, states often restrict the right of its citizens to form political parties and compete in the political arena (e.g., Communists in the United States during the early Cold War era) Seventh, severe threats often lead to restriction in the right to vote in national and local elections (e.g., Japanese-Americans during internment in the Second World War (Daniels 1981)) Finally, in the hope of minimizing opposition to extraction policies, governments often repress free speech (e.g., Espionage Act of 1917 in the United States) While threats and wars often result in a restriction of political rights, Downing (1992) argues that under certain conditions war may expand rather than contract political rights Downing focuses on the medieval origins of constitutional government in Europe Medieval customs and institutions (e.g., reciprocal rights between peasants and lords; the balance of power between the crown, the Catholic Church, nobles and burghers; prototype parliaments; and the rule of law) laid the foundation for participatory government As with Tilly, the military revolution plays a decisive role in Downing's story States that are forced to extract resources domestically are apt to develop autocratic structures capable of squeezing every last cent out of reluctant lords, merchants, and peasants In contrast, states that are capable of raising capital in markets or fighting on the territory of other states (where they can extract resources from the victims of aggression) are less likely to develop autocratic institutions In sum, the lack of a medieval legacy, the presence of severe security threats, and the reliance on domestic resources to finance military campaigns all increase the probability of an autocratic state Downing emphasizes that external threats and the need for wartime revenue often triggered an intense battle between the crown and its subjects New taxes were not dictated by rulers from above; they were negotiated with interest groups from below Feudal customs and institutions limited the crown’s ability to raise revenue When the crown "asked" for extraordinary revenue, it was often forced to reward interest groups for compliance [E]states were essential to finance and consensus building: they debated matters of war, foreign policy, trade, and justice … [E]states often took advantage of any upper hand they might have had by enhancing their privileges and liberties, and by expanding their role in the machinery of government In exchange for financial support, more often than not in time of war, estates assumed increasing control of law making (Downing 1992, 31) Moreover, this expansion of rights related to the extraction of human resources as well As the size of armies grew, the royal treasury simply could not afford to pay the mercenaries for their services The solution was to enlist volunteers and conscripts But why would a young peasant from Languedoc or Hanover volunteer for the hardship of military service or honor a conscription notice?2 They complied because they were citizens members of a community that provided rights and demanded obligations The Napoleonic Wars are considered a historical turning point because large “citizen” armies began to take the place of “mercenary” armies that had dominated in Europe since the end of the Middle Ages (Dupuy 1984, 156) Although Napoleon's Grand Armée assembled for the invasion of Russia in 1812 was dominated by foreign troops, it contained some 300,000 French conscripts and volunteers (Finer 1975, 146) "Citizen” armies would play a central role in the next global wars: World War I and World War II In sum, the Extraction School posits that raising revenues and armies requires political compromises and triggers social change.3 Mobilization for large-scale war can, therefore, have the unintended consequence of expanding political rights in the long run.4 Part II: Democracy Decreases Military Conflict The enormous democratic peace literature focuses on whether more inclusive and competitive polities are less likely to use military force to resolve international conflicts (Kant 1795) At least three distinct causal mechanisms have been proposed in the literature: 1) a structural explanation, 2) a political norms explanation, and 3) and an identity explanation The institutional structures school focuses on the relationship between political structures and the domestic political costs of using force (Morgan and Campbell 1991; Morgan and Schwebach 1992) According to this school, decisions to use military force are choices made by political leaders based on domestic and international cost/benefit calculations Foreign policy decisions can have costly domestic political repercussions The expenditure of resources and loss of human life can mobilize opposition groups or fracture a ruling coalition Relative to other political systems, democratic decision makers must be more sensitive to these potential domestic costs This constrains their behavior in comparison with leaders of non-democratic states Immanuel Kant, the first proponent of the democratic peace, uses this argument to support his claim that oligarchies are more likely to initiate war than republics (Kant 1795) The political norms school emphasizes the socialization of political leaders within their domestic political environment (Maoz and Russett 1993; Russett 1993; Dixon 1993, 1994; Huth and Allee 2002) This argument has two parts First, democratic political leaders are socialized within a system that emphasizes compromise and non-violence Leaders typically resolve political conflicts in democracies through negotiation and log-rolling Losing a political battle does not result in the loss of political rights or exclusion from future battles Moreover, coercion and violence are not seen as legitimate means for resolving a dispute Conversely, nondemocratic political leaders are socialized in an environment in which politics is more akin to a zero sum game in which rivals and losers are regularly removed from the game Coercion and violence are more widely accepted as legitimate means for resolving political conflicts In general, political leaders are more likely to impose decisions rather than compromise when dealing with the opposition Second, the norms school assumes that domestic political norms are naturally externalized by decision makers when they confront international disputes Thus, democratic polities are expected to be less likely to use military force to resolve disputes The shared identity school argues that peace between democracies is a function of a common social identity (Hopf 1998; Kahl 1998/99) Social identities are bundles of shared values, beliefs, attitudes, norms, and roles that are used to draw a boundary between the "ingroup" and the "out-group" (Rousseau, forthcoming) Members of the in-group are viewed as less threatening than members of the out-group If democratic polities use democratic norms or values to define the in-group, then they will view the actions and capabilities of the other democracies as less threatening The shared identity will reduce the likelihood that either party quickly resorts to violence to resolve a political dispute The structural and political norms arguments imply that democratic polities should be less likely to use force regardless of the regime type of the opponent This is a purely monadic structural argument: the regime type of the state alone determines its behavior in international disputes However, the literature has proposed a dyadic explanation: due to the expectation that other democracies will be similarly constrained (by institutions or norms), democracies are only peaceful with other democracies This is referred to as the dyadic democratic peace in the literature While empirical evidence for the dyadic democratic peace is extensive, only recently has strong evidence emerged in support of the monadic democratic peace Finally, the shared identity argument is generally stated as a dyadic argument: if you are a member of the in-group, I am less likely to view your capabilities and actions as threatening In general, the construction of an identity requires an “other.”7 Part II: Reciprocal Causation Skeptics of the power of the democratic peace often suggest that reciprocal causation could explain the results.8 Case studies by Layne (1994) and Thompson (1996) suggest that the peaceful nature of the environment rather than the peaceful disposition of democracies best explains the democratic peace Over time, a handful of studies have attempted to explore the reciprocal relationship using a variety of data sets and estimation methods (see Table 1) In general, modeling the reciprocal relationship has been slowed by the lack of appropriate estimation tools that are able to simultaneously address all the problems with the data (e.g., one dichotomous and one continuous endogenous variable, time dependency, lag structures, weak instruments) As with any complicated statistical analysis, fixing one problem tends to raise a host of new and difficult issues Mousseau and Shi (1999) argue that the reciprocal relationship can be probed by focusing on “anterior” regime changes – that is, regime changes that occur as states prepare for war (as opposed to regime changes during war (concurrent changes) or after a war (posterior changes)) Using democracy data from Polity III and war data from the COW interstate war data base for the period from 1816 to 1992, they employ an interrupted time series analysis with a separate regression for each case Overall, they find only limited support for the anterior effect of war preparation decreasing democracy and conclude that the democratic peace is robust However, our ability to draw firm conclusions from the analysis is hampered by a number of problems: 1) only modeling one half of the reciprocal relationship; 2) extensive missing data; 3) short time series for each separate regression; and 4) a lack of control variables Crescenzi and Enterline (1999) examine the reciprocal relationship between democracy, democratization, and interstate conflict at the systemic level of analysis Using democracy data from Polity III and war data from the COW interstate war data base for the period from 1816 to 1992, they employ Granger causality and vector auto-regression techniques Overall, they find little support for the triangular relationship across time and space For example, systemic warfare does decrease the proportion democratic in the system at particular times (e.g., Europe from 1936-1992), but not at other times (e.g., Europe 1816-75) or in other places (e.g., Asia from 194592 or Africa from 1960-92) The results not conclusively resolve the debate because the systemic analysis does not shed light on the dyadic or monadic democratic peace and the lack of control variables raises the issue of omitted variables James et al (1999) attempt to explore the relationship between MID involvement and democracy using a simultaneous equation model However, they found the results “implausible” due to the rarity of conflict involvement and their multiple categorical dependent variable Therefore, James et al employ a standard two-step procedure to estimate one half of the reciprocal relationship (MID involvement decreases democracy) and multinomial probit model for the other half (democracy decreases MID involvement) Although James et al conclude that democracy is not an important cause of peace, their findings are severely criticized by Oneal and Russett (2000).9 Problems with the analysis include 1) the failure to model reciprocal causation directly, 2) the use of an extremely weak instrument for the two-step equation, 3) the use of a dyadic data structure; 4) the employment of a highly skewed multinomial dependent variable; 5) the absence of important control variables; and 6) the selection of a flawed level of democracy variable Reuveny and Li (2003) examine the reciprocal relationship using a three equation simultaneous equation model Using democracy data from Polity 98 and militarized dispute data from the COW Militarized Interstate Dispute (MID) data base for the period from 1950 to 1992, they find support for both sides of the reciprocal relationship: democratic dyads decrease MID involvement and MID involvement decreases democratic dyads While the analysis is an important contribution to the field, it cannot resolve the debate due to 1) the use of an involvement conflict variable, 2) the nondirected-dyad data structure, 3) the employment of lagged dependent variables (Achen 2000); 4) the use of the imprecise “weak link” assumption, 5) the neglect of the time series problem, and 6) an extremely complicated three equation design Rasler and Thompson (2004) examine the reverse casual arrow from military conflict to democracy using three separate equations modeling domestic resource inequality, democracy, and military disputes The data set consists of nine great powers (Austria-Hungary, Britain, China, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Russia, and the United States) from 1816 to 1992 Using data from Vanhanen (1997), Polity III, and the MID, they find that wars and threats decrease democracy and that democracy (using the Vanhanen but not Polity III) decreases MID dispute involvement As with the previous analyses, the article has a number of important limitations including 1) the limited number of countries in the data set; 2) the failure to model reciprocal causation directly; 3) the lack of control variables; 4) the use of lagged dependent variables; 5) the use of an involvement conflict variable; and 6) the averaging of variables over ten year periods In sum, a handful of authors have attempted to tackle the very difficult problem of reciprocal causation While each paper has important strengths and have added to our understanding of the problem, no paper has been able to resolve the debate We hope to contribute to this on-going discussion by presenting a new test which eliminates some (but certainly not all) of the problems arising in these earlier studies THE SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODEL Most studies of military conflict and democracy have restricted their focus to one half of the reciprocal relationship This is due both to subfield interests (e.g., comparative politics specialists are more interested in the cause of democracy and international relations specialists are more interested in the cause of military conflict) and the technical difficulty associated with modeling reciprocal causation Unfortunately, the failure to address simultaneity can lead to erroneous conclusions Gujarati (1995: 647) explains that simultaneity problems occur when the endogenous variable in one equation (e.g., military conflict) appears as an explanatory variable in another equation of the system (e.g., democracy) As a result, such an endogenous explanatory variable becomes stochastic and is correlated with the disturbance term of the equation where it appears as an explanatory variable In this situation, Gujarati argues that the classical OLS will produce estimators that are not consistent regardless of the size of the sample (see also Greene, 1997: chap 16) The rationale for avoiding the classical OLS (ordinary least squares) method in the presence of the simultaneity problem also applies to the case of the classical logit or probit method because key assumptions of the OLS method (such as nonstochasticity and the independent distribution of the explanatory variables) are also incorporated into logit and probit analyses Thus, employing a standard probit model in a situation with reciprocal causation will result in biased coefficients The ‘simultaneous equation’ model used to test our hypotheses is an instrumental variables, limited information two-stage probit least squares estimation method The model requires two steps First, we regress the endogenous explanatory variables (use of force and democracy) on all of the predetermined variables in the whole system to eliminate the likely correlation between those endogenous explanatory variables and the stochastic disturbance terms in each equation, which violates the assumptions of the classical OLS and probit methods This first step provides us a ‘proxy’ for each endogenous explanatory variable—called an instrumental variable—that is uncorrelated with the disturbance term in each equation Second, we regress our two original endogenous variables on these proxies (or instrumental variables) plus the other independent variables in each equation (Gujarati, 1995: 686-88) This two-stage probit least squares method gives us an unbiased and efficient estimator of each parameter in the equations (Amemiya, 1978; Heckman, 1978; Maddala, 1983) In general, the simultaneity problem has been explored with one of two estimation approaches: 1) simultaneous equation models or 2) distributed lag models As just discussed, the simultaneous equation approach involves estimating two (or more) equations with each endogenous variable appearing as an exogenous variable in the other equation(s) In the democracy and military conflict literature, Reuveny and Li (2003) employ a simultaneous equation model using a two-stage least squares method In the interdependence and war literature, Keshk, Pollins, & Reuveny (2004), Mansfield (1994), Polachek (1997), and Kim (1998) use simultaneous equations estimation methods In contrast, distributed lag and related estimation models are time series methods that allow the researcher to relax assumptions such as right hand variable exogeneity and fixed lag structures In the democracy and military conflict literature, Crescenzi and Enterline (1999) employ a distributed lag model at the system level In the interdependence and war literature, Oneal, Russett, & Berbaum (2003), Reuveny (2001), and Reuveny & Kang (1996, 1998) use the distributed lags or other related estimation methods Although the distributed lag approach has a number of advantages (e.g., permits a richer modeling of temporal dependence), we have selected the simultaneous approach for three reasons First, distributed lag and related models tend to be very sensitive to the length of the lag selected by the modeler (Geweke, 1984) Second, the conclusion drawn from the bilateral Granger causality models may depend on the inclusion of a third variable (Granger, 1980) Third, detrending a series may either change its dynamic properties or lead to different causality conclusions (Kang, 1985) Thus, in this paper we will restrict our analysis to a simultaneous equation model HYPOTHESES Figure illustrates the hypotheses tested in this paper according to their level of analysis The two endogenous variables are the Level of Democracy and Aggressive Use of Force The Level of Democracy variable was constructed by subtracting the Polity IV autocracy index from the democracy index to produce a variable which ranges from -10 to +10 To ease interpretation of the statistical results, this variable was rescaled from to 20 The Polity democracy index is comprised of four components: openness of executive recruitment, competitiveness of executive recruitment, competitiveness of participation, and legislative constraints on the executive The autocracy index contains all the elements in the democracy index plus a fifth component, the regulation of participation For example, using the Polity data and this method, the United States receives a score of 20 for all years in the data set while the Soviet Union receives a score of for all years after the death of Stalin Aggressive Use of Force is defined as the use of military force on the territory of another sovereign state The variable codes for both uses of force by a state’s regular armed forces and through third parties on the territory of another state (e.g., the American support for the Mujahideen in Afghanistan during the 1980s).10 The Aggressive Use of Force variable differs from a conflict involvement variable in that the target of aggression is not coded as having used force For example, while autocratic Germany used aggressive force in 1914, democratic Belgium did not Aggressive Use of Force is also superior to a conflict initiation variable for our particular data set because the rarity of initiation undermines our ability to derive meaningful results from the statistical analysis Systemic Level Variables The relationship between democracy and military conflict has been explored at the systemic level in several articles (McLaughlin 1996; Crescenzi and Enterline 1999) The causal mechanism in these systemic variables involves demonstration effects For example, the more violence there is in the international system, the more likely a state leader is to view violence as a legitimate means for resolving a dispute Similarly, the greater the proportion of democracies in the system, the more likely a state is to view democracy as a legitimate and effective form of government This demonstration effect should encourage the development of democratic institutions and norms.11 In our model, Systemic War, measured as the total number of wars in the international system in a given year, is expected to decrease the Level of Democracy and increase the Aggressive Use Force Data on wars are from the MID data set System Democracy Average, measured as the average level of democracy using the 0-20 Polity scale in a given year, is expected to increase the Level of Democracy and decrease the Aggressive Use Force Finally, Systemic Trade Openness, measured as the average level of trade interdependence in the international system in a given year, is expected to increase the Level of Democracy and decrease the Aggressive Use Force Interdependence is measured as exports plus imports divided by gross national product using the Expanded Trade and GDP Data Version 3.0 by Gleditsch (2002a) Regional Level Variables Gleditsch (2002b) argues that powerful regional effects have been neglected in the literature Therefore, we have created a parallel set of regional variables for our conflict, democracy, and interdependence variables Regional coding relied on the Correlates of War region variable which divides the world into five regions (Europe, Middle East, Africa, Asia, and North/South America) The operationalization of the regional variables is identical to the systemic variables Dyadic Variables The dyadic variables capture the interaction of states (e.g., shared alliance) or relative measures (e.g., the balance of power) In our model, all the dyadic variables are on the right-hand side of the figure and only impact the state’s propensity to use military force First, the shared alliance hypothesis predicts that if two states are members of an alliance against a common foe, they will be less willing to use military violence to resolve a dispute (Gowa 1999) This dummy variable takes the value of when the two states in the dispute share a defense pact, neutrality pact, or an entente Otherwise the value is The sources for this variable is the Correlates of War (COW) Formal Alliances data set, Version 3.03 (Gibler & Sarkees, 2004) Second, the balance of power hypothesis predicts that the stronger state in the dyad will be more likely to resort to military violence (Huth 1996) Each state’s military capability is the average of three components—number of troops, military expenditures, and military expenditures per soldier— from the COW National Material Capabilities data set (ICPSR 9903, Singer & Small, 1993) The final product ranges from to A value of more than 0.50 indicates that the state’s military capability is superior to its opponent, while a value of less than 0.50 indicates military inferiority Third, the preferential trading area (PTA) hypothesis predicts that if both states are members of the same trading organization they will be less likely to use violence because of the costs associated with disrupting the economic relationship The dummy Shared PTA variable is coded as if both states in a dispute share at least one preferential trading agreement identified by Pevehouse and Mansfield (2003) Fourth, the joint democracy hypothesis predicts that the more democratic a state, the less likely it is to use military force to resolve the dispute against other democracies (Russett and Oneal, 2001) This hypothesis tests the dyadic version of the democratic peace In order to isolate the impact of level of democracy when facing a democratic opponent, we introduce an interactive term which multiplies the state’s Level of Democracy by a dummy variable indicating whether or not the opponent is a democratic state If a state’s opponent scores 17 or greater on the democracy scale, the dummy variable is coded Otherwise the variable is coded Thus when the opposing state is not democratic, this variable takes on a value of When the opposing state is a democracy, however, this variable is equal to the state’s Level of Democracy score Including this interaction as a separate variable in the analysis will allow an identification of the additional effect that the Level of Democracy score has on a state’s behavior because the opposing state is democratic The final two dyadic variables control for Contiguity and Distance In both cases, we predict that geographic proximity increases the probability of using force because it is easer to project power across short distances If the two states in a dispute share a boundary on land or are separated by less than 150 miles of water either directly or through their colonies or other dependencies, the variable Contiguity is coded 1; otherwise, it is coded The variable Distance is the natural logarithm of the great circle distance between the two states in a dispute Monadic Variables As Figure illustrates, seven monadic variables influence a state’s level of democracy First, membership in the global liberal trade organization known as GATT (General Agreements on Tariffs and Trade) increases the probability that a state adopts a liberal political structure 12 The open trading system created by GATT aided many states in increasing income very rapidly during the post-World War II period Both the rise in income and the growing legitimacy of the “trading state strategy” (versus the military expansion strategy) facilitated transitions to democracy (Rosecrance 1985) Second, the per capita income hypothesis predicts that rising income will increase the level of democracy The creation of a strong middle class, the expansion of education, and the desire to protect private property all contribute to demands for a more inclusive and competitive political system Third, the greater the percentage of arable land in a country will be associated with higher levels of democracy Arable land tends to be positively correlated with a greater percentage of independent farmers in society; the independent land owners are often the backbone of a democratic polity Fourth, the openness hypothesis predicts that the more a state trades, the more likely it is to have a high level of democracy Historically, economic liberalism is highly correlated with political liberalism (Russett and Oneal 2001; Rousseau, forthcoming) Fifth, the growth hypothesis predicts that positive economic growth in terms of gross domestic product will be positively associated with the level of democracy (Reuveny and Li 2003) Conversely, economic decline should decrease democracy Sixth, the inflation hypothesis predicts that the economic turmoil caused by high inflation will undermine democracy (Reuveny and Li 2003) Finally, the model includes a lagged level of democracy dependent variable and a “years” variable in order to address temporal dependency The data for Per Capita Income and Openness are from the Expanded Trade and GDP Data Version 3.0 by Gleditsch (2002a) The data for Member of GATT are from Reinhardt (1999); the data for Arable Land are from Central Intelligence Agency (2004); the data for Growth Rate and Inflation are from Heston, Summers, and Aten (2002) Finally, Figure indicates that two monadic variables influence a state’s propensity to use force aggressively First, the satisfaction hypothesis predicts that states which are satisfied with the status quo are less likely to use aggressive force This variable is coded if a state is satisfied with the status quo regarding the issue at stake in the dispute at the time the crisis begins Otherwise it is coded For example, in a territorial dispute, if the defending state is content with the current distribution of territory, it is coded as satisfied In several disputes, both states are dissatisfied (e.g., India versus China in 1962) Second, we predict that major powers will be more likely to resort to military violence to resolve a dispute The variable is coded as if a state is a major power identified by the COW Project: for the entire time period of our analysis, the U.S., France, Great Britain, the Soviet Union, and China qualify as major power The data for Major Power are taken from EUGene (Expected Utility Generation and Data Management program) Version 2.40 by Bennett & Stam (2000a) The data for Satisfaction are from Rousseau (2005) Equations (1) and (2) summarize the model that will be tested below.13 10 by the same logic, most international crises not escalate into wars in which one or both parties use large military forces to resolve the crisis.17 Therefore, most previous empirical studies that have focused on crises or wars capture only a small sub-set of the population of international conflicts The issue is important with respect to the liberal peace because if democracies choose not to escalate a political dispute into a militarized crisis or war, then analyses restricted to the subset of crises and wars will underestimate the pacifying impact of each pillar of the liberal peace Second, many other scholarly work on the conflict and democracy relationship use a state’s conflict involvement rather than a state’s conflict initiation as their dependent variable (Reuveny and Li 2003) Conflict involvement is an acceptable dependent variable for the war causes autocratization side of the reciprocal relationship because target states often have to raise huge armies and restrict political rights However, conflict involvement is a poor dependent variable for the democracy causes peace side of the equation because it groups victims of aggression (e.g., Belgium 1914) with the aggressors (e.g., Germany 1914) Given the absence of a theoretically ideal variable, we employ a conflict initiation variable in our primary analysis and a conflict involvement variable in our sensitivity analysis Third, much of the work on the liberal peace in general (e.g., Russett & Oneal, 2001) and the conflict-democracy relationship in particular (e.g., Reuveny and Li 2003) employ nondirected dyad structures This data structure makes it impossible to test monadic arguments and encourages the use of conflict involvement variables In order to distinguish the monadic effect of democracies from the dyadic effect of two democracies, we employ the directed dyad design (Bennett & Stam, 2004) RESULTS Our simultaneous equation model is an instrumental variables, limited information twostage probit least squares estimation method 18 Table displays the results from three alternative model specifications: Model employs a traditional single equation OLS model with the Level of Democracy dependent variable, Model employs a traditional single equation probit model for the Aggressive Use of Force dependent variable, and Model employs the simultaneous equation model The results in Model clearly indicate a reciprocal relationship between conflict and democracy The Aggressive Use of Force Instrument in the top half of Model is negative and statistically significant (B=-0.190, SE=0.07, t-statistic=2.64) As Lasswell and Hintze expected, using military force can lead to a decrease in a state’s level of democracy Conversely, the Level of Democracy Instrument in the lower half of Model is negative and statistically significant (B=-0.020, SE=0.01, t-statistic=2.61) In addition, the dyadic Joint Democracy variable remains negative and strongly significant in the lower half of Model The model refutes the skeptics’ claim that controlling for conflict in the environment will cause the democratic peace to evaporate Given our focus on the reciprocal model, we will restrict our discussion to Model The marginal impacts of the variables in the top half of the table can be interpreted just like any OLS regression The marginal impacts for the variable in the Aggressive Use of Force equation can be found in Table The top half of Model provides strong support for several hypotheses purporting to explain the level of democracy in a state As expected, Systemic War decreases the level of democracy and System Democratic Average and Systemic Trade Openness increase the level of democracy At the regional level, the results are more mixed While the Regional Democratic Average variable is positive as expected, the Regional War variable is significant in the wrong direction: at the regional level violence seems to increase democracy However, the marginal impact of all these systemic and regional variables are quite small compared to other levels of analysis For example, a one standard deviation increase in the amount of regional war only increases the level of democracy by 0.33 on the to 20 Polity scale At the monadic level, trade openness, high per capita income, membership in GATT, and the level of democracy last 12 year all increase the level of democracy in the current year Finally, Years and Growth have a statistically significant negative but substantively unimportant impact on the level of democracy While the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable is common in simultaneous equation models in international relations (e.g., Reuveny and Li 2003), Achen (2000) argues that the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable can depress the size of the estimated coefficients for the other independent variables In our model, while the removal of the lagged dependent variable still produces support for the reciprocal model, the size of the coefficients of many (but not all) variables increases dramatically (e.g., Systemic War by 2.1 times, monadic Openness by 3.5 times, Membership in GATT by 3.8 times) While we have included the lagged dependent variable in order to address dependency across time and to significantly increase the power of the instrument, we recognize that it limits our ability to draw strong conclusions about the marginal impacts of other variables in the democracy equation The lower half Model in Table provides the simultaneous equation results for the Aggressive Use of Force half of the reciprocal relationship As expected, the amount of Systemic War has a positive impact on the use of aggressive force by a state However, unexpectedly, Systemic Trade Openness also is positively associated with military violence At the regional level, both the Regional Democratic Average and the Regional Trade Openness are negatively associated with the use of force At the dyadic level, Joint Democracy and Satisfaction with the Status Quo decrease the probability of military force For example, the marginal analysis in Table indicates that a shift from autocracy (0) to full democracy (20) when facing a democratic opponent decreases the predicted probability of using force from 6.10 to 1.18 percent Similarly, a shift from dissatisfied to satisfied with the status quo decreases the predicted probability of using force from 5.31 to 1.58 percent Finally, Balance of Forces, at the dyadic level, increases the probability of military force Increasing the level of balance of forces from one standard deviation below the mean (0.21) to one standard deviation above the mean (0.79) increases the probability of military force by 1.94 percent (i.e., a shift in the predicted probability of using aggressive force from 4.41 to 6.35 percent) We conducted a number of sensitivity analysis in order ensure our findings are robust The primary results (i.e., statistical significance in the expected direction for both halves of the reciprocal relationship) are stable when (1) replacing MIDs for wars in the systemic and regional conflict measures, (2) dropping the lagged democracy variable from the model, (3) employing alternative operationalizations for the economic interdependence variables, and (4) dropping the temporal corrections (i.e., peace years and splines) from the model When using conflict involvement in place of aggressive use of force, the Level of Democracy Instrument decreases the Aggressive Use of Force (B=-0.19, SE=0.005, t-statistic=3.53) but the Aggressive Use of Force Instrument falls just short of statistical significance Thus, the monadic and dyadic democratic peace variables remain robust in all analyses and the conflict decreases democracy hypothesis in most analyses As with any two-step model, a strong instrument is vital In our model, the instruments are quite powerful for both the democracy equation (R of 0.74) and the aggressive use of force equation (pseudo R2 of 46) Although the findings are stable using a wide variety of independent variables, removing a large number of statistically significant variables from the instrument can in some specifications cause the monadic democracy variable in the use of force equation to drop below statistical significance Unfortunately, most researchers employing simultaneous equation models in international relations fail to report the goodness of fit for the instruments CONCLUSIONS Skeptics of the democratic peace have argued that the empirical literature has discovered a spurious correlation Democratic polities are not less likely to use force (against other democracies or in general) Rather, the skeptics claim that democratic states tend to be nurtured in peaceful environments While this causal story may be true for some democratic states, the 13 simultaneous equation model presented in this paper refutes the skeptics’ argument Even after controlling for the amount of violence in the area, democracies were less likely to use force against other democracies (i.e., support for the dyadic democratic peace) and less likely to use force against other states in general (i.e., support for the monadic democratic peace) Future analysis of the reciprocal relationship should focus in three areas First, the robustness of the results needs to be tested with a distributed lag model Both simultaneous equation models and distributed lag models have strengths and weaknesses If the results are robust using either method, we can be much more confident of our findings Second, although the use of a dispute data set is an important step forward for this literature, the time frame of the dispute data set remains relatively short at 29 years Future analysis should extend this data set, particularly after the Cold War in order to ensure the reciprocal relationship is stable across time Third, more work needs to done comparing liberal and realist explanations across levels of analysis While we have shown that regional and systemic variables cannot wipe out the monadic and dyadic democratic peace, we did discover some anomalous findings that must be explored in future analysis For example, why might regional war increase transitions to democracy and why might systemic openness increase the probability of the use of force? Will future qualitative (or quantitative) analysis support Downing’s causal story for the first finding and Waltz’s causal story for the second finding? 14 BIBLIOGRAPHY Achen, Christopher H., 2000 ‘Why Lagged Dependent Variables Can Suppress the Explanatory Power of Other Independent Variables.’ Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association, July 20-22, Los Angeles Amemiya, Takeshi, 1978 ‘The Estimation of a Simultaneous Equation Generalized Probit Model’, Econometrics 46(5): 1193-1205 Beck, Nathaniel; Jonathan N Katz & Richard Tucker, 1998 ‘Taking Time Seriously in Binary Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis', American Journal of Political Science 42(4): 12601288 Bennett, D Scott and Allan C Stam, 2000a ‘EUGene: A Conceptual Manual,’ International Interactions 26(2): 179-204 Website: http://eugenesoftware.org Bennett, D Scott & Allan C Stam, 2000b ‘Research Design and Estimator Choices in the Analysis of Interstate Disputes,’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 44(5): 653-685 Bennett, D Scott & Allan C Stam, 2004 The Behavioral Origins of War Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press Bremer, Stuart A 1992 "Dangerous Dyads: Conditions Affecting the Likelihood of Interstate War, 1816-1965." Journal of Conflict Resolution 36(June):309-41 Central Intelligence Agency, 2004 The World Factbook Washington, D.C.: Central Intelligence Agency Cohen, Raymond 1995 "Pacific Unions: A Reappraisal of the Theory that Democracies Do Not Go to War With Each Other." Review of International Studies 20 (July):207-23 Crescenzi, Mark J C and Andrew J Enterline 1999 “Ripples from the Waves? A Systemic, Time-Series Analysis of Democracy, Democratization, and Interstate War.” Journal of Peace Research, 36/1, 75-94 Dahrendorf, Ralf 1967 Society and Democracy in Germany New York: W W Norton Daniels, Roger 1981 Concentration Camps: North America, Japanese in the United States and Canada During World War II Second Edition Malabar, FL: Robert E Krieger Publishing Dixon, William J 1993 "Democracy and the Management of International Conflict." Journal of Conflict Resolution 37/1 (March):42-68 Dixon, William J 1994 "Democracy and the Peaceful Settlement of International Conflict." American Political Science Review 8/1 8(March):14-32 Dixon, William J and Paul D Senese 2002 "Democracy, Disputes, and Negotiated Settlements." Journal of Conflict Resolution 46/4 (August): 547-571 Downing, Brian M 1992 The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Doyle, Michael W., 1986 'Liberalism and World Politics', American Political Science Review 80(4): 1151-1169 Dupuy, Trevor N 1984 The Evolution of Weapons and Warfare New York: Da Capo Finer, Samuel E 1975 “State- and Nation-Building in Europe: The Role of the Military.” In Charles Tilly (ed.) The Formation of National States in Western Europe Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Geweke, John, 1984 ‘Inference and Causality in Economic Time Series Models’ in Zvi Griliches & Michael D Intriligator, eds., Handbook of Econometrics, Volume New York, NY: North-Holland (1101-1144) Gibler, Douglas M., & Meredith Sarkees, 2004 ‘Measuring Alliances: the Correlates of War Formal Interstate Alliance Data set, 1816-2000,’ Journal of Peace Research 41(2): 211-222 Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede, 2002a ‘Expanded Trade and GDP Data,’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 46(5): 712-724 Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede 2002b All International Politics is Local: The Diffusion of Conflict, Integration,and Democratization Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press 15 Gowa, Joanne 1999 Ballots and Bullets: The Elusive Democratic Peace Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Granger, C W J., 1980 ‘Testing for Causality: A Personal Viewpoint’, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2(4): 329-352 Greene, William H, 1997 Econometric Analysis 3rd ed Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall Gujarati, Damodar N., 1995 Basic Econometrics 3rd ed New York, NY: McGraw-Hill Heckman, James J., 1978 'Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System', Econometrica 46(4): 931-959 Heston, Alan; Robert Summers & Bettina Aten, 2002 Penn World Table Version 6.1 Center for International Comparisons at the University of Pennsylvania (CICUP) Hinze, Otto 1906 [1975] Historical Essays of Otto Hintze New York: Oxford University Press Hopf, Ted 1998 "The Promise of Constructivism in International Relations Theory." International Security, 23:171-200 Huth, Paul K 1996 Standing Your Ground Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press Huth, Paul K and Todd L Allee 2002 The Democratic Peace and Territorial Conflict in the Twentieth Century New York, NY: Cambridge University Press Ireland, Michael J and Scott Sigmund Gartner 2001 “Time to Fight: Government Type and Conflict Initiation in Parliamentary Systems.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 45/5 (October), 547-568 James, Patrick, Eric Solber and Murray Wolfson 1999 “An Identified Systemic Model of the Democracy and Peace Nexus.” Defence and Peace Economics, 10, 1-37 James, Patrick, Eric Solber and Murray Wolfson 2000 “Democracy and Peace: Reply to Oneal and Russett.” Defence and Peace Economics, 11, 215-229 Kahl, Colin H 1998/99 “Constructing a Separate Peace: Constructivism, Collective Liberal Identity, and Democratic Peace.” Security Studies 8/2 (Winter) 94-119 Kang, Heejoon, 1985 ‘The Effects of Detrending in Granger Causality Tests’, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 3(4): 344-349 Kant, Immanuel, [1795] 1991 'Perpetual Peace: A Philosophical Essay', in Hans Reiss, ed., 2nd ed., Kant’s Political Writings New York, NY: Cambridge University Press (93-130) Keshk, Omar M G., 2003 ‘CDSIMEQ: A Program to Implement Two-Stage Probit Least Squares’, Stata Journal 3(2): 157-167 Keshk, Omar M G.; Brian M Pollins, & Rafael Reuveny, 2004 ‘Trade Still Follows the Flag: The Primacy of Politics in a Simultaneous Model of Interdependence and Armed Conflict,’ Journal of Politics 66(4): 1155-1179 Kim, Hyung Min and David L Rousseau 2005 “The Classical Liberals Were Half Right (or Half Wrong): New Tests of the Liberal Peace, 1960-88." Journal of Peace Research, forthcoming September 2005 Kim, Soo Yeon, 1998 Ties That Bind: The Role of Trade in International Conflict Process, 1950-1992, PhD dissertation, Yale University, New Haven, CT Klinkner, Philip A and Rogers M Smith 1999 The Unsteady March: The Rise and Decline of Racial Equality in America Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press Lasswell, Harold D 1941 “The Garrison State.” The American Journal of Sociology 46/4 (January), 455-468 Layne, Christopher 1994 “Kant or Cant: The Myth of the Democratic Peace.” International Security 19(Fall): 5-94 Levi, Margaret 1997 Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism Cambridge: Cambridge University Press Maddala, G S., 1983 Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics New York, NY: Cambridge University Press Mansfield, Edward D., 1994 Power, Trade, and War Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Maoz, Zeev and Bruce M Russett 1993 "Normative and Structural Causes of Democratic Peace, 1946-1986." American Political Science Review 87(September):624-38 16 McLaughlin, Sara 1996 “Endogeneity and the Democratic Peace.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Peace Science Society (International) Houston, TX, October 1996 Moore, Barrington 1966 Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy Boston, MA: Beacon Morgan, T Clifton and Sally H Campbell 1991 "Domestic Structure, Decisional Constraints, and War" Journal of Conflict Resolution 35/2 (June), 187-211 Morgan, T Clifton, and Valerie L Schwebach 1992 "Take Two Democracies and Call Me in the Morning: A Prescription for Peace?" International Interactions 17(4):305-20 Mousseau, Michael and Yuhang Shi 1999 “A Test for Reverse Causality in the Democratic Peace Relationship.” Journal of Peace Research, 36/6, 639-663 Oneal, John R & Bruce M Russett, 1997 'The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950-1985', International Studies Quarterly 41(2): 267-294 Oneal, John R and Bruce Russett 2000 “Comment: Why “An Identified Systemic Model of the Democracy-Peace Nexus” Does Not Persuade.” Defence and Peace Economics, 11, 197-214 Oneal, John R.; Bruce M Russett & Michael L Berbaum, 2003 ‘Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations, 1886-1992’, International Studies Quarterly 47(3): 371-393 Pevehouse, Jon C & Edward D Mansfield, 2003 Preferential Trading Arrangements Dataset Polachek, Solomon W., 1997 'Why Democracies Cooperate More and Fight Less: The Relationship between Trade and International Cooperation’, Review of International Economics 5(3): 295-309 Ramirez, Francisco O., Yasemin Soysal, and Suzanne Shanahan 1997 “The Changing Logic of Political Citizenship: Cross-National Acquisition of Women's Suffrage Rights, 1890 to 1990." American Sociological Review 62 (October), 735-45 Rasler, Karen and William R Thompson 2001 “Rivalries and the Democratic Peace in the Major Power System.” Journal of Peace Research 38/6, 659-683 Rasler, Karen and William R Thompson 2004 “The Democratic Peace and a Sequential, Reciprocal, Causal Arrow Hypothesis.” Comparative Political Studies 37/8 (October), 879908 Rehnquist, William H 1998 All the Laws But One: Civil Liberties in Wartime New York: Alfred A Knopf Reinhardt, Eric, 1999 GATT/WTO Membership Dataset Website: http://userwww.service.emory.edu/~erein/data/membership.zip Reuveny, Rafael, 2001 ‘Bilateral Import, Export, and Conflict/Cooperation Simultaneity’, International Studies Quarterly 45(1): 131-158 Reuveny, Rafael & Heejoon Kang, 1996 ‘International Trade, Political Conflict/Cooperation, and Granger Causality’, American Journal of Conflict Resolution 40(3): 943-970 Reuveny, Rafael & Heejoon Kang, 1998 ‘Bilateral Trade and Political Conflict/Cooperation: Do Goods Matter?’, Journal of Peace Research 35(5): 581-602 Reuveny, Rafael and Quan Li 2003 “The Joint Democracy-Dyadic Conflict Nexus: A Simultaneous Equations Model.” International Studies Quarterly, 47, 325-346 Risse-Kappen, Thomas 1995 Cooperation Among Democracies: The European Influence on U.S Foreign Policy Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Rosecrance, Richard N 1985 The Rise of the Trading State New York: Basic Books Rousseau, David L 2005 Democracy and War: Institutions, Norms, and the Evolution of International Conflict Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press Rousseau, David L forthcoming Identifying Threats and Threatening Identities: The Social Construction of Realism and Liberalism Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press Rousseau, David L.; Christopher Gelpi, Dan Reiter, and Paul K Huth, 1996 'Assessing the Dyadic Nature of the Democratic Peace, 1918-88', American Political Science Review 90(3): 512-533 17 Rousseau, David L and Bruce Newsome 2004 “Women, Minorities And War: The Impact Of Wartime Mobilization On Political Rights In Europe, 1900-1955." Unpublished manuscript Russett, Bruce M 1993 Grasping the Democratic Peace: Principles for a Post-Cold War World Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Russett, Bruce M & John R Oneal, 2001 Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations New York, NY: Norton Schultz, Kenneth A 1999 "Do Democratic Institutions Constrain or Inform? Contrasting Two Institutional Perspectives on Democracy and War." International Organization 53/2 (Spring), 233-266 Schultz, Kenneth A 2001 Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press Sherman, Frank L., 1994 'SHERFACS: A Cross-Paradigm, Hierarchical and Contextually Sensitive Conflict Management Data Set', International Interactions 20(1-2): 79-100 Singer, J David & Melvin Small, 1993 National Material Capabilities Data, 1816-1985 [computer file] ICPSR Study 9903 Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research Small, Melvin, and J David Singer 1982 Resort to Arms: International and Civil Wars, 18161980 Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications Smith, Adam 1965 The Wealth of Nations New York: Modern Library Spiro, David E 1994 “The Insignificance of the Democratic Peace,” International Security 19/2 (Fall):50-86 Spruyt, Hendrik 1994 The Sovereign State and Its Competitors Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Stein, Arthur A 1980 The Nation at War Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Tilly, Charles (ed) 1975 The Formation of States in Western Europe Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Tilly, Charles 1990 Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992 Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Thompson, William R 1996 “Democracy and Peace: Putting the Cart Before the Horse?” International Organization, 50, 141-174 Vanhanen, T 1997 Prospects of Democracy: A Study of 172 Countries London: Routledge Weber, Max 1958 The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism Translated by Talcott Parsons New York: Scribner 18 Military Conflict (-) Proportion Democratic (+) Trade Interdependence (+) (-) (-) (+) Level of Democracy (-) Dyadic (-) or (+) Monadic (+) (+) Member of GATT Per capita Income Arable Land Openness Growth Rate Inflation Last Year’s Democracy Aggressive Use of Force Military Conflict Proportion Democratic Trade Interdependence (+) Military Conflict (-) Proportion Democratic (-) Trade Interdependence (-) (+) Shared Alliance (-) Balance of Power Shared PTA (-) Joint Democracy (+) Contiguity (-) Distance (+) (+) (+) (-) (+) Major Power (-) Satisfaction Systemic (+) (+) Regional (-) Dyadic Military Conflict Proportion Democratic Trade Interdependence Monadic Regional Systemic Figure 1: Hypotheses Ordered by Level of Analysis (+) 19 Table 1: Empirical Analysis of the Reciprocal Relationship Between War and Military Conflict Author -Mousseau & Shi Journal -JPR 1999 Method Single Equation Finding War Does Not Decrease Democracy Crescenzi & Enterline JPR 1999 Distributed Lag Model Great Regional and Temporal Variance; No Clear Pattern in Either Direction James et al DPE 1999 Hybrid Approach War Decreases Democratization Reuveny & Li ISQ 2003 Simultaneous Model Joint Democracy Reduces Conflict; Conflict Reduces Joint Democracy Rasler & Thompson CPS 2004 Single Equations Threat Decreases Democracy; Democracy Decreases Conflict Notes: Journal of Peace Research (JPR), Defense and Peace Economics (DPE), International Studies Quarterly (ISQ), and Comparative Political Studies (CPS) 20 Table 2: Statistical Results Comparing OLS, Probit, and Simultaneous Equation Models Endogenous Variable Aggressive Use of Force Systemic War Systemic Democratic Average Systemic Trade Openness Regional War Regional Democratic Average Regional Trade Openness Openness Per Capital Income Arable Land Member of GATT Lagged Level of Democracy Year Growth Inflation Constant Model 1: OLS Beta SE Level of Democracy -0.102 -0.092 0.595 0.454 0.181 0.092 -0.032 0.032 0.0003 0.771 1.392 0.738 -0.036 -0.016 -0.005 65.021 Endogenous Variable *** *** *** *** * * * SE 0.17 0.02 0.15 0.25 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.004 0.00003 0.51 0.17 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 34.28 -0.014 0.030 0.041 0.509 0.073 -0.014 -0.011 -0.039 0.357 -0.050 -0.637 -0.147 0.028 -0.292 -1.260 -0.120 0.027 -0.001 -1.109 4069 0.73 Model 3: Simultaneous Equation Beta SE Level of Democracy -0.190 -0.090 0.616 0.488 0.184 0.075 -0.036 0.032 0.0003 0.766 1.347 0.733 -0.034 -0.019 -0.006 60.473 Aggressive Use of Force Level of Democracy Systemic War System Democratic Average Systemic Trade Openness Regional War Regional Democratic Average Regional Trade Openness Joint Democray Balance of Forces Shared Alliance Satisfaction w/ Status Quo Contiguity Distance Major Power Peace Years Spline Spline Spline Constant Number of observations R-squared Log Likelihood *** *** * *** *** Model 2: Probit Beta 5593 1073 ** ** *** *** *** ** *** * ** *** *** *** * 0.005 0.010 0.070 0.068 0.017 0.012 0.014 0.011 0.122 0.080 0.079 0.077 0.028 0.113 0.079 0.012 0.003 0.001 0.793 ** *** *** * *** ** *** *** *** *** * * * 0.07 0.02 0.14 0.24 0.04 0.03 0.03 0.01 0.00003 0.52 0.15 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.01 34.80 Aggressive Use of Force -0.020 0.049 0.076 0.662 0.034 -0.030 -0.030 -0.036 0.306 0.115 -0.533 -0.026 0.052 0.031 -1.146 -0.109 0.024 -0.001 -1.995 ** *** *** * * *** * *** *** *** *** * * 0.01 0.01 0.09 0.08 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.16 0.10 0.09 0.11 0.03 0.14 0.09 0.01 0.004 0.001 0.98 4056 0.73 713 Notes: All significance tests are one-tailed: *p

Ngày đăng: 18/10/2022, 04:11