Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 642 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
642
Dung lượng
3,12 MB
Nội dung
THE ENCYCLOPÆDIA BRITANNICA
A DICTIONARY OF ARTS, SCIENCES, LITERATURE AND GENERAL
INFORMATION
ELEVENTH EDITION
VOLUME III
AUSTRIA LOWER to BISECTRIX
[E-Text Edition of Volume III - Part 1 of 2, Slice 3 of 3 - BANKS to BASSOON]
BANKS, GEORGE LINNAEUS (1821-1881), British miscellaneous writer, was
born at Birmingham on the 2nd of March 1821. After a brief experience in a variety of
trades, he became at the age of seventeen a contributor to various newspapers, and
subsequently a playwright, being the author of two plays, a couple of burlesques and
several lyrics. Between 1848 and 1864 he edited in succession a variety of
newspapers, including the Birmingham Mercury and the Dublin Daily Express, and
published several volumes of miscellaneous prose and verse. He died in London on
the 3rd of May 1881.
BANKS, SIR JOSEPH, Bart. (1743-1820), English naturalist, was born in Argyle
Street, London, on the 13th of February 1743. His father, William Banks, was the son
of a successful Lincolnshire doctor, who became sheriff of his county, and represented
Peterborough in parliament; and Joseph was brought up as the son of a rich man. In
1760 he went to Oxford, where he showed a decided taste for natural science and was
the means of introducing botanical lectures into the university. In 1764 he came into
possession of the ample fortune left by his father, and in 1766 he made his first
scientific expedition to Newfoundland and Labrador, bringing back a rich collection
of plants and insects. Shortly after his return, Captain Cook was sent by the
government to observe the transit of Venus in the Pacific Ocean, and Banks, through
the influence of his friend Lord Sandwich, obtained leave to join the expedition in the
"Endeavour," which was fitted out at his own expense. He made the most careful
preparations, in order to be able to profit by every opportunity, and induced Dr Daniel
Solander, a distinguished pupil of Linnaeus, to accompany him. He even engaged
draughtsmen and painters to delineate such objects of interest as did not admit of
being transported or preserved. The voyage occupied three years and many hardships
had to be undergone; but the rich harvest of discovery was more than adequate
compensation. Banks was equally anxious to join Cook's second expedition and
expended large sums in engaging assistants and furnishing the necessary equipment;
but circumstances obliged him to relinquish his purpose. He, however, employed the
assistants and materials he had collected in a voyage to Iceland in 1772, returning by
the Hebrides and Staffa. In 1778 Banks succeeded Sir John Pringle as president of the
Royal Society, of which he had been a fellow from 1766, and held the office until his
death. In 1781 he was made a baronet; in 1795 he received the order of the Bath; and
in 1797 he was admitted to the privy council. He died at Isleworth on the 19th of June
1820. As president of the Royal Society he did much to raise the state of science in
Britain, and was at the same time most assiduous and successful in cultivating friendly
relations with scientific men of all nations. It was, however, objected to him that from
his own predilections he was inclined to overlook and depreciate the labours of the
mathematical and physical sections of the Royal Society and that he exercised his
authority somewhat despotically. He bequeathed his collections of books and
botanical specimens to the British Museum. His fame rests rather on what his
liberality enabled other workers to do than on his own achievements.
See J. H. Maiden, Sir Joseph Banks (1909).
BANKS, NATHANIEL PRENTISS (1816-1894), American politician and soldier,
was born at Waltham, Massachusetts, on the 30th of January 1816. He received only a
common school education and at an early age began work as a bobbin-boy in a cotton
factory of which his father was superintendent. Subsequently he edited a weekly paper
at Waltham, studied law and was admitted to the bar, his energy and his ability as a
public speaker soon winning him distinction. He served as a Free Soiler in the
Massachusetts house of representatives from 1849 to 1853, and was speaker in 1851
and 1852; he was president of the state Constitutional Convention of 1853, and in the
same year was elected to the national House of Representatives as a coalition
candidate of Democrats and Free Soilers. Although re-elected in 1854 as an American
or "Know-Nothing," he soon left this party, and in 1855 presided over a Republican
convention in Massachusetts. At the opening of the Thirty-Fourth Congress the anti-
Nebraska men gradually united in supporting Banks for speaker, and after one of the
bitterest and most protracted speakership contests in the history of congress, lasting
from the 3rd of December 1855 to the 2nd of February 1856, he was chosen on the
133rd ballot. This has been called the first national victory of the Republican party.
Re-elected in 1856 as a Republican, he resigned his seat in December 1857, and was
governor of Massachusetts from 1858 to 1861, a period marked by notable
administrative and educational reforms. He then succeeded George B. McClellan as
president of the Illinois Central railway. Although while governor he had been a
strong advocate of peace, he was one of the earliest to offer his services to President
Lincoln, who appointed him in 1861 major-general of volunteers. Banks was one of
the most prominent of the volunteer officers. When McClellan entered upon his
Peninsular Campaign in 1862 the important duty of defending Washington from the
army of "Stonewall" Jackson fell to the corps commanded by Banks. In the spring
Banks was ordered to move against Jackson in the Shenandoah Valley, but the latter
with superior forces defeated him at Winchester, Virginia, on the 25th of May, and
forced him back to the Potomac river. On the 9th of August Banks again encountered
Jackson at Cedar Mountain, and, though greatly outnumbered, succeeded in holding
his ground after a very sanguinary battle. He was later placed in command of the
garrison at Washington, and in November sailed from New York with a strong force
to replace General B. F. Butler at New Orleans as commander of the Department of
the Gulf. Being ordered to co-operate with Grant, who was then before Vicksburg, he
invested the defences of Port Hudson, Louisiana, in May 1863, and after three
attempts to carry the works by storm he began a regular siege. The garrison
surrendered to Banks on the 9th of July, on receiving word that Vicksburg had fallen.
In the autumn of 1863 Banks organized a number of expeditions to Texas, chiefly for
the purpose of preventing the French in Mexico from aiding the Confederates, and
secured possession of the region near the mouths of the Nueces and the Rio Grande.
But his Red River expedition, March-May 1864, forced upon him by superior
authority, was a complete failure. In August 1865 he was mustered out of the service,
and from 1865 to 1873 he was again a representative in congress, serving as chairman
of the committee on foreign affairs. A personal quarrel with President Grant led in
1872, however, to his joining the Liberal-Republican revolt in support of Horace
Greeley, and as the Liberal-Republican and Democratic candidate he was defeated for
re-election. In 1874 he was successful as a Democratic candidate, serving one term
(1875-1877). Having rejoined the Republican party in 1876, he was United States
marshal for Massachusetts from 1879 until 1888, when for the ninth time he was
elected to Congress. He retired at the close of his term (1891) and died at Waltham on
the 1st of September 1894.
BANKS, THOMAS (1735-1805), English sculptor, son of a surveyor who was land
steward to the duke of Beaufort, was born in London on the 29th of December 1735.
He was taught drawing by his father, and in 1750 was apprenticed to a wood-carver.
In his spare time he worked at sculpture, and before 1772, when he obtained a
travelling studentship and proceeded to Rome, he had already exhibited several fine
works. Returning to England in 1779 he found that the taste for classic poetry, ever
the source of his inspiration, no longer existed, and he spent two years in St
Petersburg, being employed by the empress Catherine, who purchased his "Cupid
tormenting a Butterfly." On his return he modelled his colossal "Achilles mourning
the loss of Briseis," a work full of force and passion; and thereupon he was elected, in
1784, an associate of the Royal Academy and in the following year a full member.
Among other works in St Paul's cathedral are the monuments to Captain Westcott and
Captain Burges, and in Westminster Abbey to Sir Eyre Coote. His bust of Warren
Hastings is in the National Portrait Gallery. Banks's best-known work is perhaps the
colossal group of "Shakespeare attended by Painting and Poetry," now in the garden
of New Place, Stratford-on-Avon. He died in London on the 2nd of February 1805.
[v.03 p.0334]
BANKS AND BANKING. The word "bank," in the economic sense, covers various
meanings which all express one object, a contribution of money for a common
purpose. Thus Bacon, in his essay on Usury, while explaining "how the
discommodities of it may be best avoided and the commodities retained," refers to a
"bank or common stock" as an expression with which his readers would be familiar.
Originally connected with the idea of a mound or bank of earth—hence with that of a
monte, an Italian word describing a heap—the term has been gradually applied to
several classes of institutions established for the general purpose of dealing with
money.
The manner in which a bank prospers is explained by David Banking as a business.
Ricardo, in his Proposals for an Economical and Secure Currency, in a passage where
he tells us that a bank would never be established if it obtained no other profits but
those derived from the employment of its own capital. The real advantage of a bank to
the community it serves commences only when it employs the capital of others. The
money which a bank controls in the form of the deposits which it receives and
sometimes of the notes which it issues, is loaned out by it again to those who desire to
borrow and can show that they may be trusted. A bank, in order to carry on business
successfully, must possess a sufficient capital of its own to give it the standing which
will enable it to collect capital belonging to others. But this it does not hoard. It only
holds the funds with which it is entrusted till it can use them, and the use is found in
the advances that it makes. Some of the deposits merely lie with the bank till the
customer draws what he requires for his ordinary everyday wants. Some, the greater
part by far, of the deposits enable the bank to make advances to men who employ the
funds with which they are entrusted in reproductive industry, that is to say, in a
manner which not only brings back a greater value than the amount originally lent to
them, but assists the business development of the country by setting on foot and
maintaining enterprises of a profitable description. It is possible that some part may be
employed in loans required through extravagance on the part of the borrower, but
these can only be a small proportion of the whole, as it is only through reproductive
industry that the capital advanced by a banker can really be replaced. A loan
sometimes, it is true, is repaid from the proceeds of the sale of a security, but this only
means a transfer of capital from one hand to another; money that is not transferred in
this way must be made by its owner. Granted that the security is complete, there is
only one absolute rule as to loans if a bank desires to conduct its business on safe
lines, that the advance should not be of fixed but of floating capital. Nothing seems
simpler than such a business, but no business requires closer attention or more strong
sense and prudence in its conduct. In other ways also, besides making loans, a well-
conducted bank is of much service to the business prosperity of a country, as for
example by providing facilities for the ready transmission of money from those who
owe money to those to whom it is due. This is particularly obvious when the debtor
lives in one town or district and the creditor in another at a considerable distance, but
the convenience is very great under any circumstances. Where an easy method of
transmission of cash does not exist, we become aware that a "rate of exchange" exists
as truly between one place and another in the same country as between two places in
different countries. The assistance that banking gives to the industries of a community,
apart from these facilities, is constant and most valuable.
With these preliminary remarks on some main features of the Historical development.
business, we may pass on to a sketch of the history of modern banking. Banks in
Europe from the 16th century onwards may be divided into two classes, the one
described as "exchange banks," the other as "banks of deposits." These last are banks
which, besides receiving deposits, make loans, and thus associate themselves with the
trade and general industries of a country. The exchange banks included in former
years institutions like the Bank of Hamburg and the Bank of Amsterdam. These were
established to deal with foreign exchange and to facilitate trade with other countries.
The others—founded at very different dates—were established as, or early became,
banks of deposit, like the Bank of England, the Bank of Venice, the Bank of Sweden,
the Bank of France, the Bank of Germany and others. Some reference to these will be
made later. The exchange banks claim the first attention. Important as they were in
their day, the period of their activity is now generally past, and the interest in their
operations has become mainly historical.
In one respect, and that a very important one, the business carried on by the exchange
banks differed from banking as generally understood at the present time. No exchange
bank had a capital of its own nor did it require any for the performance of the
business. The object for which exchange banks were established was to turn the values
with which they were entrusted into "current money," "bank money" as it was called,
that is to say, into a currency which was accepted immediately by merchants without
the necessity of testing the value of the coin or the bullion brought to them. The
"value" they provided was equal to the "value" they received, the only difference
being the amount of the small charge they made to their customers, who gained by
dealing with them more than equivalent advantages.
Short notices of the Bank of Amsterdam, which was one of the most important, and of
the Bank of Hamburg, which survived the longest, its existence not terminating till
1873, will suffice to explain the working of these institutions.
The Amsterdamsche Wisselbank, or exchange bank, known later as the Bank of
Amsterdam, was established by the ordinance of the city of Amsterdam of 31st
January 1609. The increased commerce of Holland, which made Amsterdam a leading
city in international dealings, led to the establishment of this bank, to which any
person might bring money or bullion for deposit, and might withdraw at pleasure the
money or the worth of the bullion. The ordinance which established the bank further
required that all bills of 600 gulden (£50), or upwards—this limit was, in 1643,
lowered to 300 gulden (£25)—should be paid through the bank, or in other words, by
the transfer of deposits or credits at the bank. These transfers came afterwards to be
known as "bank money." The charge for making the transfers was the sole source of
income to the bank. The bank was established without any capital of its own, being
understood to have actually in its vaults the whole amount of specie for which "bank
money" was outstanding. This regulation was not, however, strictly observed. Loans
were made at various dates to the Dutch East India Company. In 1795 a report was
issued showing that the city of Amsterdam was largely indebted to the bank, which
held as security the obligations of the states of Holland and West Friesland. The debt
was paid, but it was too late to revive the bank, and in 1820 "the establishment which
for generations had held the leading place in European commerce ceased to exist."
(See Chapters on the Theory and History of Banking, by Charles F. Dunbar, p. 105.)
Similar banks had been established in Middelburg, (March 28th, 1616), in Hamburg
(1619) and in Rotterdam (February 9th, 1635). Of these the Bank of Hamburg carried
on much the largest business and survived the longest. It was not till the 15th of
February 1873 that its existence was closed by the act of the German parliament
which decreed that Germany should possess a gold standard, and thus removed those
conditions of the local medium of exchange—silver coins of very different intrinsic
values—whose circulation had provided an ample field for the operations of the bank.
The business of the Bank of Hamburg had been conducted in absolute accordance
with the regulations under which it was founded.
The exchange banks were established to remedy the inconvenience to which
merchants were subject through the uncertain value of the currency of other countries
in reference to that of the city where the exchange bank carried on its business. The
following quotation from Notes on Banking, written in 1873, explains the method of
operation in Hamburg. "In this city, the most vigorous offshoot of the once powerful
Hansa, the latest representative of the free commercial cities of medieval Europe,
[v.03 p.0335]there still remains a representative of those older banks which were once
of the highest importance in commercial affairs. Similar institutions greatly aided the
prosperity of Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam and Nuremberg. The Bank of Hamburg is
now the last survivor of these banks, whose business lay in the assistance of
commerce, not by loans, but by the local manufacture, so to speak, of an international
coinage. In a city of the highest rank of commercial activity, but greatly circumscribed
in territory, continually receiving payments for merchandise in the coin of other
countries, a common standard of value was a matter of primary necessity. The
invention of bank money, that is, of a money of account which could be transferred at
pleasure from one holder to another, enabled the trade of the place to be carried on
without any of those hindrances to business which must have followed on the delay
and expense attendant on the verification of various coins differing from each other in
weight, intrinsic value, standard of purity of metal, in every point in fact in which
coins can differ from each other. By supplying a currency of universal acceptation the
Bank of Hamburg greatly contributed to the prosperity of that city." The regulations
being strictly carried out, the currency was purely metallic; the "Mark Banco" being
merely the representative of an equal value of silver.
For the earliest example of a bank for the receipt of deposits carrying on a business on
modern lines, we must turn, as in the case of the exchange banks, to a great
commercial city of the middle ages. Private banking in Venice began as an adjunct of
the business of the campsores or dealers in foreign moneys. "As early as 1270 it was
deemed necessary to require them to give security to the government as the condition
of carrying on their business, but it is not shown that they were then receiving
deposits. In an act of the 24th of September 1318, however, entitled Bancherii
scriptae dent plegiarias consulibus, the receipt of deposits by the campsores is
recognized as an existing practice, and provision is made for better security for the
depositors." From this act it becomes clear that between 1270 and 1318 the money-
changers of Venice were becoming bankers, just as the same class of men became in
Amsterdam a couple of centuries later, and as later still the goldsmiths in London.
Of the early banks in Europe, the bank in Venice, the Banco The first public bank in
Europe. di Rialto, was established by the acts of the Venetian senate of 1584 and
1587. This appears to have been the first public bank in that city and in Europe. The
senate by the act of the 3rd of May 1619
[1]
established by the side of the Banco di
Rialto a second public bank known as the Banco Giro, or Banco del Giro, which
ultimately became the only public bank of the city and was for generations famous
throughout Europe as the Bank of Venice. Earlier than this the campsores or dealers in
foreign moneys had carried on the business. The Bank of Venice (Banco del Giro)
appears to have been called into existence by the natural developments of trade, but
some banks have been established by governments and have been of great service to
the development of the countries in which they have carried on their business. Of
these, the Bank of Sweden (the Riksbank), established in 1656, is the earliest. This
bank still exists and has always been the state bank of Sweden. It was founded by a
Swede named Palmstruck, who also invented the use of the bank note—perhaps
adapted for use in Europe is the better expression to employ, as notes were current in
China about A.D. 800. The first bank note was issued by the Riksbank in 1658. An
enquête made by the French government in 1729 recognizes the priority of Sweden in
this matter, and declares the bank note to be an admirable Swedish invention,
designed to facilitate commerce.
European Countries
United Kingdom.—English banking may be traced back to the dealings in money
carried on by the goldsmiths of London and thus certainly to the 16th century; but it
has been so greatly influenced by the working of the Bank of England and by the
Foundation of the Bank of England. acts of parliament connected with that institution,
that a reference to this bank's foundation and development must precede any attempt
at a detailed history of banking in the United Kingdom. The Bank of England was
founded in 1694.
[2]
As in the case of some of the earlier continental banks, a loan to
the government was the origin of its establishment. The loan, which was £1,200,000,
was subscribed in little more than ten days, between Thursday, 21st June, and noon of
Monday, 2nd July 1694. On Tuesday, 10th July, the subscribers appointed Sir John
Houblon the governor, and Michael Godfrey (who was killed during the siege of
Namur on the 17th of July 1695) deputy-governor. Michael Godfrey wrote a pamphlet
explaining the purposes for which the bank was established and the use it would be to
the country. The pamphlet supplies some curious illustrations of the dangers which
some persons had imagined might arise from the establishment of the bank and its
connexion with William III., deprecating the fear "lest it should hereafter joyn with
the prince to make him absolute and so render parliaments useless."
The governor and the deputy-governor, having thus been appointed, the first twenty-
four directors were elected on Wednesday, 11th July 1694. Two of them were brothers
of the governor, Sir John Houblon. They were descended from James Houblon, a
Flemish refugee who had escaped from the persecution of Alva. All the directors were
men of high mercantile standing. The business of the bank was first carried on in the
Mercers' chapel. It continued there till the 28th of September, when they moved to
Grocers' Hall. They were tenants of the Grocers' Hall till 1732. The first stone of the
building now occupied by the bank was laid on the 1st of August 1732. The bank has
remained on the same site ever since. The structure occupied the space previously
covered by the house and gardens of Sir John Houblon, the first governor, which had
been bought for the purpose. Between 1764 and 1788 the wings were erected. In 1780
the directors, alarmed at the dangerous facilities which the adjacent church of St
Christopher le Stocks might give to a mob, obtained parliamentary powers and
[...]... Palmerston, then premier, and Sir G C Lewis, which allowed a temporary relaxation of the Bank Act of 1844 The public alarm, however, was so great that it was not until the 21 st of November that the severity of the pressure was in any way diminished On the 20 th of November the notes issued to the public on securities beyond the statutory limit (then £14,475,000) reached the sum of £ 928 ,000 By the next week the. .. remained the banker of the government ever since The interest on the stock in which the debt is inscribed has always been paid by the bank, originally half-yearly, now quarterly, and the registration of all transfers of the stock itself is carried on by the bank, which assumes the responsibility of the correctness of these transfers The dignity which the position of banker to the government gives; the monopoly... whatever the amount of specie in the "issue department" may be Three times since the passing of the Bank Act— during the crises of 1847, 1857 and 1866—authority has been given for the suspension of that act On one of these dates only, in 1857, the limits of the act were exceeded; on the other two occasions the fact that the permission had been given stayed the alarm It should be remembered, whenever the. .. increase in the number of those fluctuations on the Bank Act alone would not be justifiable, but the working of the act appears to have an influence in that direction, as the effect of the act is to cut the specie reserve held by the bank into two parts and to cause the smaller of these parts to receive the whole strain of any demands either for notes or for specie Meanwhile the demands on the English... to 9% at the end of the term In another from being 22 % it had diminished to 1½% of the total In all cases where the detail was given it had diminished greatly The Bank Act of 1844 was arranged with the intention of concentrating the note issues on the Bank of England in order to secure the monopoly of that bank as the one issuer in England and Wales The result was that nearly all the provincial banks... the legal limit, do not make the coin held a security for them The legislation of 1879 which made the note issues a first charge, with unlimited liability, on the total assets of the joint-stock banks which accepted the principle of limited liability for the rest of their business, has been the only recognition by the state of the duty to the note-holders of rendering them secure It has been a real... before the 27 th of April 1844 The number of the banks to which the privilege of circulation was then allowed and the amount of notes permitted were, in England:— 20 7 private banks with an authorized issue of £5,153,417 72 joint-stock banks with an authorized issue of 3,478 ,23 0 £8,631,647 The actual circulation of the country in October 1844 was as follows:— Notes in Circulation. The monthly return of the. .. circulation ending the 12th of October 1844 (stamps and taxes, 25 th October); England Bank of England 20 ,22 8,800 Private banks 4,674,1 62 Joint-stock banks 3,331,516 Scotland Chartered, private and joint-stock banks 2, 987,665 Ireland Bank of Ireland 3,597,850 Private and joint-stock banks 2, 456 ,26 1 Total £37 ,27 6 ,25 4 In May 1907 the number and amounts were reduced to:— Authorized Issue Actual Issue 12 private... private banks £4 82, 744 17 joint-stock banks 1,084,836 £ 122 ,536 437,693 The reason why the actual circulation of these banks is so far below the authorized issue is that under existing circumstances their circulation can only extend over a very limited area The notes of country banks are now almost unknown except in the immediate neighbourhood of the places where they are issued; though they may all be... other banks £ 922 ,29 7,000 Scotland 135,0 42, 000 Ireland 73,707,000 Isle of Man 898,000 £1,131,944,000 The progressive growth in bank deposits since it has been possible to keep a record of their amounts, affords some means of checking roughly the correctness of the estimates of 1851 and 18 72 Broadly speaking, it may be said that the bank deposits of the United Kingdom have about doubled since 18 72 The . continued there till the 28 th of September, when they moved to
Grocers' Hall. They were tenants of the Grocers' Hall till 17 32. The first stone of the.
the development of the countries in which they have carried on their business. Of
these, the Bank of Sweden (the Riksbank), established in 1656, is the