Pricing of Random Payoffs at Fixed Future Dates

Một phần của tài liệu Continuous Stochastics calculus with Applications to Finance (Trang 268 - 293)

Chapter IV Application to Finance 1. The Simple Black Scholes Market

4. Pricing of Random Payoffs at Fixed Future Dates

LetB be a market containing zero coupon bonds of all maturitiesT (0, T] and ξ a local deflator for B such thatξBj is a martingale, for each zero coupon bond Bj inB.

4.a European options. Fix a timeT (0, T] and letB|T denote the market based on the filtered probabilityspace (Ω,(Ft)t[0,T], P) resulting from B byrestricting the securityprocesses in B to the interval [0, T]. Thus all trading stops at time T in the marketB|T.

Lemma. Let τ : Ω[0, T] be an optional time andφ a trading strategy satisfying Vt(φ) =t

τφ(s)ãdB(s),P-as. on the set[τ < t], for all t∈[0, T]. Then the trading strategy χ= 1]]τ,T]]φ is self-financing.

Proof. Note thatVt(χ) = 1[τ <t]Vt(φ) especiallyV0(χ) = 0. Thus we must show that Vt(χ) =t

0χ(s)ãdB(s),P-as., for allt∈[0, T]. Consider suchtand note thatχ= 0 and sot

0χ(s)ãdB(s) = 0 =Vt(χ),P-as. on the set [t≤τ] (III.2.d.4). Likewise on the set [τ < t] we have

Vt(χ) =Vt(φ) = t

τ

φ(s)ãdB(s) = t

0

1]]τ,T]](s)φ(s)ãdB(s) = t

0

χ(s)ãdB(s).

4.a.0. Let ψ12 be self-financing trading strategies with VT(ψ1) =VT(ψ2). Then (a) Vt(ψ1) =Vt(ψ2), for allt∈[0, T], or

(b) there is arbitrage in the marketB|T.

Proof. Assume that (b) is not true, set ψ =ψ1−ψ2 and let > 0. To establish (a) it will suffice to show that the optional timeτ = inf{t∈[0, T]|Vt(ψ)> } ∧T satisfies P(τ < T) = 0. Let ρ be the trading strategywhich buys one share of the zero coupon bond B(t, T) maturing at time T and holds this to timeT. Set Z =Vτ(φ)/B(τ, T) and consider the trading strategy

χ= 1]]τ,T]]Zρ−1]]τ,T]]ψ= 1]]τ,T]]φ,

where φ= 1]]τ,T]]Zρ−ψ. Following the strategyχ we wait until timeτ. If τ =T we do nothing. If τ < T we short the portfolio ψ (long ψ2, shortψ1) and invest the proceeds into the zero coupon bond B(t, T). The self-financing propertyofψ implies that

Vt(ψ) =V0(ψ) + t

0

ψ(s)ãdB(s), ∀t∈[0, T], and so Vτ(ψ) =V0(ψ) +

τ 0

ψ(s)ãdB(s).

Subtraction yieldst

τψ(s)ãdB(s) =Vt(ψ)−Vτ(ψ),P-as. on the set [τ < t]. Likewise the Fτ-measurabilityof Z and III.2.d.0.(i) implythat t

τ1]]τ,T]](s)(s)ãdB(s) =

252 4.a European options.

t

0Z1]]τ,T]](s)dB(s, T) =Z(B(t, T)−B(t∧τ, T)). It follows that t

τ

φ(s)ãdB(s) =Z(B(t, T)−B(τ, T))

Vt(ψ)−Vτ(ψ)

=ZB(t, T)−Vt(ψ) =Vt(φ),

P-as. on the set [τ < t]. The preceding Lemma now shows that the strategy χis self-financing. Since V0(χ) = 0 andVT(χ) =Z > 0, on the set [τ < T], we must have P(τ < T) = 0.

Remark. From example 1.c.3 we know that such arbitrage χ can coexist with the local deflatorξforB. Thus we cannot conclude alternative (a) in 4.a.0. Additional assumptions onφ,θ are necessary.

4.a.1 Law of One Price. Let φ, θ be trading strategies. If ξ(t)

Vt(φ)−Vt(θ) is a P-martingale, then VT(φ) =VT(θ)implies that Vt(φ) =Vt(θ), for allt∈[0, T].

Proof. SetDt=Vt(φ)−Vt(θ) and assume thatDT = 0. The martingale property ofξ(t)Dtthen implies thatDt= 0, that is,Vt(φ) =Vt(θ), for allt∈[0, T].

Remark. If φ, θ are self-financing, then the processesξ(t)Vt(φ) andξ(t)Vt(θ) and hence the differenceξ(t)

Vt(φ)−Vt(θ)

areP-local martingales (3.c.0). If in addition the maximal function supt[0,T]ξ(t)Vt(φ)−Vt(θ)is integrable, then ξ(t)

Vt(φ) Vt(θ)

is a P-martingale (I.8.a.4).

Options and replication. AEuropean optionexercisable at timeT is a nonnegative, FT-measurable random variableh. The quantityh(ω) is the payoff received by the option holder at time T if the market is in state ω. The nonnegativityof h is the mathematical expression of the fact that holders of options traded in existing financial markets do not exercise an option unless it is in the money, that is, unless this results in a positive payoff. TheFT-measurabilitycorresponds to the fact that the uncertaintyregarding the payoff h(ω), if exercised, is resolved bytimeT.

A trading strategy θ in B|T is said to replicate the option h, if it is self- financing, ξ(t)Vt(θ) is a martingale and VT(θ) = h. Necessarilythen ξ(t)Vt(θ) = EP

ξ(T)VT(θ)|Ft

, that is

Vt(θ) =ξ(t)1EP

ξ(T)h|Ft

, t∈[0, T]. (0)

The optionhis said to bereplicableif and onlyif there exists a trading strategyθ inB|T replicatingh. Recall that for a self-financing trading strategyθ, the process ξ(t)Vt(θ) is automaticallya P-local martingale; however to obtain formula (0) we need the stronger martingale condition.

Assume now thathis replicated bythe trading strategyθ. To determine what the priceπt(h) of the claimhat timet≤T should be, let us assume that we decide to tradehin our market according to some price processπ(t). To avoid arbitrage we must haveπ(T) =h=VT(θ) and soπ(t) =Vt(θ) =ξ(t)1EP

ξ(T)h|Ft

, for all

t [0, T] (4.a.0 with ψ1 =θ and ψ2 being the buyand hold strategyinvesting in h). This leads us to define thearbitrage priceofhas

πt(h) =ξ(t)1EP

ξ(T)h| Ft

, t∈[0, T]. (1)

For later use we define πt(h) as in (1), even if his not replicable. However then πt(h) can no longer be interpreted as the arbitrage price process of the claim h.

Using 3.d.0.(d) withA(t) =B(t, T) (thenA(T) = 1), we see that πt(h) =B(t, T)EPT

h|Ft

, t∈[0, T], (2)

wherePT denotes the forward martingale measure at dateT. IfBcontains a riskless bondB0 such thatξB0is a martingale (and hence the spot martingale measureP0

is defined), a similar application of 3.d.0.(d) withA(t) =B0(t) yields πt(h) =B0(t)EP0

h/B0(T)| Ft

, t∈[0, T]. (3)

Formula (2) points to the importance of the forward martingale measure PT. The switch between forward martingale measures at different dates S < T is made as follows:

4.a.2. Let 0≤t≤S < T and assume thathisFS-measurable. Then

(a) B(t, S)EPS[B(S, T)h| Ft] =B(t, T)EPT [h| Ft], if h≥0 orh∈L1(PT).

(b) B(t, S)EPS[h|Ft] =B(t, T)EPT[h/B(S, T)| Ft], if h≥0 orh∈L1(PS).

Remark. Looking at formula (a) considerhas a random payoff occurring at time T. The right hand side evaluates this payoff at timetaccording to (2). The left hand side first discounts this payoff back to time S and then evaluates the discounted payoff at time t according to (2). A similar interpretation is possible for formula (b). Consider has a payoff occurring at timeS.

Proof. (b) Applythe symmetric numeraire change formula 3.d.1.(d) to the market B|S and the numerairesA(t) =B(t, S) andC(t) =B(t, T). Noting thatA(S) = 1 the symmetric numeraire change formula 3.d.1.(d)

A(t)EPA[h/A(S)|Ft] =C(t)EPC[h/C(S)|Ft] yieldsB(t, S)EPS[h|Ft] =B(t, T)EPT[h/B(S, T)|Ft].

(a) SimplyreplacehwithB(S, T)hin (b).

4.a.3. Let θ be a self-financing trading strategy such thatVT(θ) =hand A∈ S+ a numeraire such thatξA is a martingale. Thenθreplicateshif and only ifVtA(θ) = Vt(θ)/A(t) is aPA-martingale.

Proof. According to 3.d.0.(b),VtA(θ) is aPA-martingale if and onlyifξ(t)Vt(θ) is a P-martingale.

254 4.c Option to exchange assets.

4.b Forward contracts and forward prices. Af orward contract for deliveryof an assetZinB at dateT with strike priceKobliges the holder of the contract to buy this asset at timeT forK dollars therebyinducing a single cash flowh=ZT −K at time T. The f orward price at time t for deliveryof the asset Z at time T is defined to be that strike price K, which makes the value of the forward contract equal to zero at time t. The payoffh=ZT−K at timeT can be implemented at time zero via the following self-financing trading strategy θ:

At time t buyone unit of the asset Z, sell K units of the zero coupon bond maturing at timeT and hold until timeT.

The Law of One Price suggests that the arbitrage priceπt(h) of this forward contract at time t≤T be defined as πt(h) =Vt(θ) = Zt−KB(t, T). Setting this equal to zero and solving for K, we obtain the forward priceFZ(t, T) at time tfor delivery of the asset Z at timeT as

FZ(t, T) = Zt

B(t, T). (0)

IfZt/B(t, T) is in fact aPT-martingale (rather than onlya local martingale), then (0) can be rewritten as

FZ(t, T) =EPT

ZT|Ft

. (1)

4.c Option to exchange assets. Fix K > 0 and let h be the European option to receive one unit of the asset S1 in exchange forK units of the assetS2 at timeT. The payoffhof this option is given byh= (S1(T)−KS2(T))+. IfS2(t) =B(t, T) is the zero coupon bond maturing at timeT, thenh= (S1(T)−K)+ is the European call on S1 with strike price K exercisable at timeT, that is, the payoff at time T of the right to buyone share of S1forK dollars at timeT.

Let us introduce the exercise set A = | S1(T)(ω) > KS2(T)(ω)}, that is the set of all states in which our option is exercised at time T. Then h= (S1(T)−KS2(T)) 1A and, assuming that this claim is replicable, its arbitrage price processπt(h) can be written as

πt(h) =ξ(t)1EP[ξ(T)S1(T)1A| Ft]−Kξ(t)1EP[ξ(T)S2(T)1A| Ft]. (0) Let us now use the assets S1, S2 themselves as numeraires. Assume that the processes ξS1, ξS2 are martingales and hence the probabilities PS1, PS2 defined.

Using 3.d.0.(d) with h = Sj(T)1A, we can write ξ(t)1EP[ξ(T)Sj(T)1A| Ft] = Sj(t)EPSj[1A|Ft],j= 1,2, and thus (0) becomes

πt(h) =S1(t)EPS1[1A|Ft]−KS2(t)EPS2[1A|Ft]. (1) To get a more specific formula we need to make further assumptions on our market model. Assume that we are in the setting of the general Black-Scholes model of 3.g with a deflator ξsatisfying

(t)

ξ(t) =−r(t)dt−φ(t)ãdW(t),

whereWtis a Brownian motion with respect to the market probabilityPgenerating the (augmented) filtration (Ft). The assetsSj are assumed to follow the dynamics

dSj(t)

Sj(t) =àj(t)dt+σj(t)ãdW(t), j = 1,2. (2)

Then d(ξSj)(t)

(ξSj)(t) =

σj(t)−φ(t)

ãdW(t), j= 1,2 (3) (see 3.g.eq.(4)). Set Zt=log

S1(t)/S2(t)

and write the exercise setA as A=

ZT > log(K)

. (4)

To evaluate the conditional expectations in (1) we must find the distribution ofZT under the probabilitiesPSj, j= 1,2. From (3) it follows that

d log ξSj

(t) =1

2αj(t)2dt+αj(t)ãdW(t), (5) where αj(t) =σj(t)−φ(t). Thus

dZ(t) =d log(ξS1)(t)−d log(ξS2)(t)

= 1 2

α2(t)2− α1(t)2

dt+ (α1(t)−α2(t))ãdWt. (6) To determine the conditional expectationEPS

1[1A|Ft] we use III.4.c.0 to determine the dynamics of Z under the measure PS1. Bydefinition of the measure PS1 we have

Mt:= d(PS1|Ft)

d(P|Ft) = (ξS1)(t)

(ξS1)(0), t∈[0, T], and consequently, from (3), dMt

Mt

=α1(t)ãdWt. According to III.4.c.0 it follows that WtS1 = Wtt

0α1(s)ds is a PS1-Brownian motion on

,F,(Ft), PS1

. Obviously dWt =α1(t)dt+dWtS1. Substituting this into (6) we find that

d Z(t) = 1 2

α22− α12

+ (α1−α2)ãα1

dt+ (α1−α2)ãdWtS1

= 1

2α1−α22dt+ (α1−α2)ãdWtS1,

(7)

with respect to the measure PS1 (i.e., for a PS1-Brownian motion WtS1). We now make the following assumption: The process α1(t)−α2(t) = σ1(t)−σ2(t) is nonstochastic. Then III.6.c.3 can be applied to the dynamics (7) to compute

256 4.c Option to exchange assets.

the conditional expectationEPS

1

1A|Ft

. Because of the special nature of the drift term in (7) the quantitiesm(t, T), Σ(t, T) from III.6.c.3 become

Σ2(t, T) =T

t (α1−α2)(s)2ds and m(t, T) = 12Σ2(t, T) and it follows that

EPS1

1A|Ft

=N(d1) where d1= log

S1(t)/KS2(t)

+12Σ2(t, T)

Σ(t, T) .

A similar computation starting from the equation d Z(t) =1

2(α1−α2)2dt+ (α1−α2)ãdWtS2 under the measure PS2 yieldsEPS

2[1A|Ft] =N(d2), where d2=log

S1(t)/KS2(t)

12Σ2(t, T)

Σ(t, T) =d1Σ(t, T).

Thus we have the option price

πt(h) =S1(t)N(d1)−K S2(t)N(d2),

where d1,d2 are given as above. We can summarize these findings as follows:

4.c.0 Margrabe’s Formula. Assume that the asset prices Sj(t), j = 1,2, follow the dynamics (2) above and that the process σ1−σ2 is deterministic and satisfies Σ2(t, T) = T

t (σ1 −σ2)(s)2ds > 0, for all t [0, T). Then the option h = S1(T)−KS2(T)+

to exchange assets has arbitrage price process πt(h) =S1(t)N(d1)−KS2(t)N(d2), t∈[0, T),

where N is the standard normal cumulative distribution function and d1,d2 are as above.

Remark. From (6) it follows that the quantityΣ2(t, T) can also be written as Σ2(t, T) =ZTt =

log S1/S2

T t

and is thus a measure of the aggregate (percentage) volatilityof S1/S2 on the interval [t, T] under the market probability P, that is, realized in the market. If S2(t) is the zero coupon bond B(t, T), then h =

S1(T)−K+

is the European call onS1with strike priceK. In this case the quotientS1(t)/S2(t) is thef orward price FS1(t, T) of S1 deliverable at time T and consequentlythe crucial quantity (σ1−σ2)(t)the volatilityof the forward price ofS1and not ofS1 itself.

The reader will note that the term structure of interest rates does not enter our formula unless one of the assets S1, S2 is a zero coupon bond. The reason is that the claim hcan be replicated bya trading strategyθ investing in the assets S1,S2only. Indeed our formula for the priceπt(h) indicates as possible weights

θ1=N(d1) and θ2=−KN(d2)

forS1 andS2respectively. Let us verifythat this strategyis self-financing. Bythe numeraire invariance of the self-financing condition it will suffice to show that θis self-financing in the marketξB, that is, thatd

θã(ξB)

=θãd(ξB). Now in general d

θã(ξB)

=θãd(ξB) +ξBãdθ+dθ, ξB (8) and so we must show that ξBãdθ+dθ, ξB= 0. (9) Since

θã(ξB)

(t) =ξ(t)πt(h) =EP

ξ(T)h| Ft

is a martingale,d

θã(ξB) and θãd(ξB) are known to be the stochastic differentials of local martingales. Thus (8) shows that the bounded variation terms on the left of (9) automaticallycancel. It will thus suffice to show that the local martingale part of the stochastic differential Bãdθ=S11+S22vanishes. We mayassume thatK= 1. Then

θ1=N(d1) = 1

2π

d1(t,S1,S2)

−∞

eu2/2du, θ2=−N(d2) = 1

2π

d2(t,S1,S2)

−∞

eu2/2du, where

d1(t, s1, s2) =log(s1)−log(s2) +12Σ2(t, T)

Σ(t, T) , and

d2(t, s1, s2) =log(s1)−log(s2)12Σ2(t, T)

Σ(t, T) , fors1, s2∈R.

WritingX ∼Y ifX−Y is a bounded variation process and using similar notation for stochastic differentials, Ito’s formula yields

1∼∂N(d1)

∂s1

(t, S1, S2)dS1+∂N(d1)

∂s2

(t, S1, S2)dS2, and 2∼ −∂N(d2)

∂s1 (t, S1, S2)dS1−∂N(d2)

∂s2 (t, S1, S2)dS2.

(10)

Here ∂N(d1)

∂s1

= (2π)12ed21/2∂d1

∂s1

= (2π)12ed21/2 1 s1Σ(t, T).

Likewise ∂N(d1)

∂s2 =(2π)12ed21/2 1 s2Σ(t, T).

258 4.c Option to exchange assets.

Similarly

∂N(d2)

∂s1 = (2π)12ed22/2 1

s1Σ(t, T), ∂N(d2)

∂s2 =(2π)12ed22/2 1 s2Σ(t, T). Thus, from (10),

(2π)12Σ(t, T)S11∼ed21/2dS1−ed21/2S1

S2

dS2, and (2π)12Σ(t, T)S22∼ −ed22/2S2

S1

dS1+ed22/2dS2, which, upon addition, yields

(2π)12Σ(t, T)

S11+S22

ed21/2−ed21/2S2

S1

dS1+

ed22/2−ed22/2S1

S2

dS2

ed21/2

1−e12(d21d22)S2 S1

dS1+ed22/2

1−e12(d22d21)S1 S2

dS2.

(11)

Noting now that 1

2(d21−d22) = (d1−d2)d1+d2

2 = Σ(t, T)d1+d2

2 =log S1/S2

,

we see that the coefficients ofdS1,dS2on the right of (11) vanish and consequently Bãdθ=S11+S220, as desired. Thus θis self-financing. The self-financing propertyof θ is no accident. See 4.e.0 below. Byits verydefinition this strategy replicates the arbitrage price ofhon the entire interval [0, T). The reader will have noticed that the weights θ1, θ2 are not defined at time t =T. Thus Vt(θ) is not defined fort=T. Howeverξ(t)Vt(θ) =EP

ξ(T)h| Ft

is a continuous martingale and the martingale convergence theorem I.7.c.0 shows that ξ(t)Vt(θ)→ξ(T)hand henceVt(θ)→halmost surely, ast↑T. Thus defining the weightsθ1(T),θ2(T) in anyfashion such that VT(θ) =hwill extend the self-financing propertyof θ from the interval [0, T) to all of [0, T].

In the case of a European call onS1(S2(t) =B(t, T)) the replicating strategy invests inS1and the zero coupon bondB(t, T) expiring at timeT. Indeed, if interest rates are stochastic the call cannotbe replicated investing inS1 and the risk-free bond except under rather restrictive assumptions and even then the corresponding portfolio weights have to be chosen differently(see 4.f.3 below).

4.d Valuation of non-path-dependent European options in Gaussian models.

Consider a European option h of the form h = f(S1(T), S2(T), . . . , Sk(T)) exer- cisable at timeT, whereS1(t), S2(t), . . . , Sk(t) are anyassets (possiblyzero coupon bonds). Weassumethat the claimhisattainableand that we are in the setting of the general Black Scholes market of section 3.g. Let Fj(t) =Sj(t)/B(t, T) denote the forward price of the assetSj deliverable at timeT and recall that PT denotes the forward martingale measure at time T. The price process πt(h) ofh can then be computed as

πt(h) =B(t, T)EPT[h|Ft], t∈[0, T]. (0) SinceSj(T) =Fj(T) the optionhcan also be written as

h=f

F1(T), F2(T), . . . , Fk(T)

. (1)

The forward pricesFj(t) arePT-local martingales and hence (in the context of 3.g) follow a driftless dynamics

dFj(t)

Fj(t) =γj(t)ãdWtT, equivalently d(logFj(t)) =1

2γj(t)2dt+γj(t)ãdWtT

(2)

under the forward martingale measurePT, that is, for some Brownian motionWtT on (Ω,F,(Ft)t[0,T], PT). Integration yields

Fj(t) =Fj(0)exp t

0

γj(s)ãdWsT 1 2

t 0

γj(s)2ds

, t∈[0, T]. (3) The use of forward prices and the forward martingale measure eliminates interest rates from explicit consideration. All the necessaryinformation about interest rates is contained in the numeraire asset A(t) = B(t, T). To make (3) useful for the computation of the conditional expectation (0) we make the following

(G)Gaussian assumption: The volatilityprocesses γj are nonstochastic.

The forward price Fj(t) is then a log-Gaussian process with respect to the for- ward martingale measurePT (III.6.d.4). Likewise assumption (G) implies that the deflated processesξSj are log Gaussian processes with respect to the market prob- abilityP (3.g.eq.(4) and III.6.d.4).

To compute the conditional expectation (0) withh as in (1) it will be conve- nient to write the vector

F1(T), F2(T), . . . , Fk(T)

as a function of some vector measurable with respect toFtand another vector independent ofFt. Using (3) for t=t, T we see that

Fj(T) =Fj(t)exp T

t

γj(s)ãdWsT 1 2

T t

γj(s)2ds

=Fj(t)exp

ζj(t, T)1 2Cjj

, where

(4)

260 4.d Valuation of non-path-dependent European options in Gaussian models.

ζj(t, T) =T

t γj(s)ãdWsT and Cij =T

t γi(s)ãγj(s)ds=log(Fi), log(Fj)Tt. Fixt∈[0, T]. Combining (0), (1) and (4) we obtain

πt(h) =B(t, T)EPT

f

F1(t)eζ1(t,T)12C11, . . . , Fk(t)eζk(t,T)12Ckk

| Ft

. (5) Note now that the vector (F1(t), . . . , Fk(t)) is Ft-measurable, while the vector (ζ1(t, T), . . . , ζk(t, T)) is independent of Ft with distribution N(0, C) (III.6.a.2, III.6.c.2). Thus the conditional expectation (5) is computed byintegrating out the vector (ζ1(t, T), . . . , ζk(t, T)) according to its distribution while leaving the vector (F1(t), . . . , Fk(t)) unaffected (I.2.b.11); in short

πt(h) =B(t, T)

Rk

f

F1(t)ex112C11, . . . , Fk(t)exk12Ckk

N(0, C)(dx). (6) Let us now reduce this integral to an integral with respect to the standard multi- normal distribution N(0, I)(dx) =nk(x)dx= (2π)k2e12x2dx.

To do this we represent the covariance matrixCin the formC=AA, for some k×kmatrixA, that is we write

Cij=T

t γi(s)ãγj(s)ds=θiãθj,

where θj =cj(A) is the jth column of the matrix A. Especiallythen Cii =θi2. Using II.1.a.7 we can now rewrite (6) as

πt(h) =B(t, T)

Rk

f

F1(t)eθ1ãx12θ12, . . . , Fk(t)eθkãx12θk2

nk(x)dx. (7) Replacingxwith−xand noting thateθjãx12θj2=nk(x+θj)/nk(x), (7) can be rewritten as

πt(h) =B(t, T)

Rk

f

F1(t)nk(x+θ1)

nk(x) , . . . , Fk(t)nk(x+θk) nk(x)

nk(x)dx. (8) 4.d.0 Theorem. Assume that the assets S1(t), . . . , Sk(t) follow the dynamics (2) and that the Gaussian assumption (G) holds. Then the price process πt(h) of an attainable European claim h=f(S1(T), . . . , Sk(T))maturing at timeT is given by equation (8), where Fj(t) =Sj(t)/B(t, T) is the forward price of the asset Sj, the vectors θj=θj(t, T)∈Rk are chosen so that

Cij =log(Fi), log(Fj)Tt =T

t γi(s)ãγj(s)ds=θiãθj

andnk(x) = (2π)k2e12x2 is the standard normal density in Rk.

Homogeneous case. In case the function f = f(s1, s2, . . . , sk) is homogeneous of degree one, formula (8) simplifies as follows:

πt(h) =

Rk

f

S1(t)nk(x+θ1), . . . , Sk(t)nk(x+θk)

dx. (9)

The zero coupon bondB(t, T) drops out and anyexplicit dependence on the rate of interest disappears. We have seen this before in the formula for the price of an option to exchange assets. In the Black Scholes call price formula the rate of interest enters onlysince one of the assets is in fact the zero coupon bond with the same maturityas the call option.

We will apply4.d.0 to several options depending on two assets S1,S2 (k=2).

Recall that N(d) =d

−∞n1(t)dt denotes the (one dimensional) cumulative normal distribution function and that the two dimensional standard normal density n2 satisfiesn2(x) =n2(x1, x2) =n1(x1)n1(x2). The following Lemma will be useful:

4.d.1 Lemma. Letrbe a real number,θ, w∈R2 andG={x∈R2|xãw≤r} ⊆R2.

Then

G

n2(x+θ)dx=N

r+θãw w

.

Proof: Let e1 = (1,0) R2 and A be the (linear) rotation ofR2 which satisfies Aw=we1. ThenAis a unitarymap, that is,A=A1. Consider the substitution x=A1u. Using the rotational invariance of Lebesgue measure, the fact thatAis an isometryand that the standard normal densityn2(x) depends onxonlythrough the normx, it follows that

G

n2(x+θ)dx=

AG

n2(A1u+θ)du=

AG

n2(A1(u+))du

=

AG

n2(u+)du.

Here u∈AG⇐⇒ Au∈G⇐⇒ (Au)ãw≤r⇐⇒ (Aw)≤r⇐⇒ u1w ≤r.

Thus AG={u∈R2 |u1 ≤r/w }. Set u= (u1, u2), Aθ= (α1, α2)∈R2. Then n2(u+) =n1(u1+α1)n1(u2+α2) and the special nature of the domainAGnow implies that

G

n2(x+θ)dx=

AG

n2(u+)du

=

u1r/wn1(u1+α1)du1

R

n1(u2+α2)du2

.

Since the second integral in this product is equal to one it follows that

G

n2(x+θ)dx=

tr/w+α1

n1(t)dt=N r

w+α1

. (10)

Finally α1= ()ãe1=θã(Ae1) =θã(A1e1) =θã w w and so 4.d.1 follows from (10).

262 4.d Valuation of non-path-dependent European options in Gaussian models.

Consider now an option h = f(S1, S2) which depends on two assets. Here the dimensionk= 2 and the vectorsθ1, θ2∈R2 satisfy

θ12= T

t

γ1(s)2ds=log(F1)Tt, θ22= T

t

γ2(s)2ds=log(F2)Tt,

and θ1ãθ2=

T t

γ1(s)ãγ2(s)ds=log(F1), log(F2)Tt, from which it follows that Σ2(t, T) := θ1−θ22 = T

t γ1(s)−γ2(s)2ds. Set Y(t) =S1(t)/S2(t) =F1(t)/F2(t) andZ(t) =log(Y(t)). From (2)

dZ(t) =1 2

γ1(t)2− γ2(t)2 +

γ1(t)−γ2(t)

ãdWtT,

and sodZt=γ1(t)−γ2(t)2dt. Thus Σ2(t, T) =T

t γ1(s)−γ2(s)2ds=ZTt

as in Margrabe’s formula 4.c.0.

4.d.2 Example. Option to exchange assets. The option to receive, at timeT, one unit of asset S1 in exchange forKunits of asset S2has payoff

h=f(S1(T), S2(T)) = (S1(T)−KS2(T))+= (S1(T)−KS2(T))1[S1(T)KS2(T)]

which is homogeneous of degree one inS1,S2. Let us see if we can derive Margrabe’s formula 4.c.0 from (9) above. Enteringf(s1, s2) = (s1−Ks2)1[s1Ks2]into (9) yields

πt(h) =

G

S1(t)n2(x+θ1)−KS2(t)n2(x+θ2) dx

=S1(t)

G

n2(x+θ1)dx−KS2(t)

G

n2(x+θ2)dx, where G =

x∈R2 |S1(t)n2(x+θ1) ≥KS2(t)n2(x+θ2)

. Thus x∈G if and onlyif

n2(x+θ1) n2(x+θ2)=exp

1 2

x+θ12− x+θ22

KS2(t) S1(t) , equivalently 1

2

x+θ12− x+θ22

≤log

S1(t) KS2(t)

,

that is (θ1−θ2)≤log

S1(t) KS2(t)

1 2

θ12− θ22 . ThusG={x∈R2|xãw≤r}, wherew=θ1−θ2 and

r=log

S1(t) KS2(t)

1 2

θ12− θ22 .

From 4.d.1

Gn2(x+θ1)dx=N(d1) and

Gn2(x+θ2)dx=N(d2) and so πt(h) =S1(t)N(d1)−KS2(t)N(d2),

where d1= (r+θ1ãw)

w andd2 = (r+θ2ãw)

w. Recalling from (10) that w=θ1−θ2= Σ(t, T) and observing that

r+θ1ãw=log

S1(t) KS2(t)

+1

2w2 and r+θ2ãw=log

S1(t) KS2(t)

1 2w2, it follows that

d1=log

S1(t)/KS2(t)

+12Σ2(t, T)

Σ(t, T) and d2=d1Σ(t, T), as in formula 4.c.0 above. Note that we can also write these quantities as

d1,2= log(F1(t)/F2(t))−log(K)±12

log(F1/F2)T

t

log(F1/F2)T t

.

4.d.3 Example. Digital option. Consider the option h= 1[S1(T)KS2(T)]. Since the function f(s1, s2) = 1[s1Ks2] satisfiesf(αs1, αs2) = f(s1, s2), 4.d.0 simplifies to

πt(h) =B(t, T)

R2

f

S1(t)n2(x+θ1), S2(t)n2(x+θ2)

n2(x)dx

=B(t, T)

G

n2(x)dx=B(t, T)N r

w

, where G,r andware as in 4.d.2. Setρ=r/w. Asw=

log(F1/F2)Tt and r=log

S1(t) KS2(t)

1 2

θ12− θ22

=log

F1(t)/F2(t)

−log(K) +1 2

log(F2)Tt − log(F1)Tt

,

we obtainπt(h) =B(t, T)N(ρ), where ρ=log

F1(t)/F2(t)

−log(K) +12

log(F2)Tt − log(F1)Tt

log(F1/F2)Tt

. (11) Comparing this with the formulaπt(h) =B(t, T)EPT(h|Ft) shows thatN(ρ) is the (conditional) exercise probabilityN(ρ) = EPT(h|Ft) =PT

S1(T)≥KS2(T)| Ft

under the forward martingale measurePT. In caseS2(t) =B(t, T) the option payoff becomes h= 1[S1(T)K],F2(t) = 1 and consequently(11) simplifies to

ρ= log F1(t)

−log(K)12log(F1)Tt

log(F1)Tt

.

264 4.d Valuation of non-path-dependent European options in Gaussian models.

4.d.4 Example. Power option. Let nowh=S1(T)λS2(T)à1[S1(T)KS2(T)], where λ, à∈R. LetG,randw be as in 4.d.2. As the functionf(s1, s2) =sλ1sà21[s1Ks2] satisfiesf(αs1, αs2) =αλ+àf(s1, s2), 4.d.0 simplifies to

πt(h) =B(t, T)1(λ+à)

R2

f

S1(t)n2(x+θ1), S2(t)n2(x+θ2)

n2(x)1(λ+à)dx

=B(t, T)1(λ+à)S1(t)λS2(t)à

G

n2(x+θ1)λn2(x+θ2)àn2(x)1(λ+à)dx

=B(t, T)F1(t)λF2(t)à

G

n2(x+θ1)λn2(x+θ2)àn2(x)1(λ+à)dx.

SetU =exp

12

λ(1−λ)θ21+à(1−à)θ222λà θ1ãθ2

. Bystraightforward computation nk(x+θ1)λnk(x+θ2)ànk(x)1(λ+à) = U nk(x+λθ1+àθ2) and so, using 4.d.1,

πt(h) =U B(t, T)F1(t)λF2(t)à

G

nk(x+λθ1+àθ2)dx

=U B(t, T)F1(t)λF2(t)àN w1

r+ (λθ1+àθ2)ãw .

Sincew=θ1−θ2 andr=log(F1(t)/F2(t))−log(K)12(θ12− θ22 we have r+(λθ1+àθ2)ãw=r+λθ12+ (à−λ)θ1ãθ2−àθ22

=log(F1(t)/F2(t))−log(K) + (λ−12)θ12+ (à−λ)θ1ãθ2+ (12−à)θ22. Recallingθ12=log(F1)Tt,θ22=log(F2)Tt,θ1ãθ2=log(F1), log(F2)Tt and w=log(F1/F2)Tt, the option price assumes the form

πt(h) =U B(t, T)F1(t)λF2(t)àN(q), where U =exp

12

λ(1−λ)log(F1)Tt +à(1−à)log(F2)Tt 2λàlog(F1), log(F2)Tt

and q= log

F1(t)/F2(t)

−log(K) + (λ−12)log(F1)Tt + (12−à)log(F2)Tt

+ (à−λ)log(F1), log(F2)Tt

log(F1/F2)Tt.

Remark. Herelog(Fj)Tt is the aggregate percentage volatilityof the forward price Fj that is left from current time t to the time T of expiryof the option. It is incorrect to use the volatilities of the cash prices Sj instead. The two are the same onlyif the zero coupon bondA(t) =B(t, T) is a bounded variation process.

Note thatlog(Fj)Tt =T

t γj(s)2ds,log(F1), log(F2)Tt =T

t γ1(s)ãγ2(s)dsand log(F1/F2)Tt =log(F1)Tt +log(F2)Tt 2log(F1), log(F2)Tt

=T

t γ1(s)−γ2(s)2ds.

The following notation is frequentlyemployed in the literature: set σj =γj (the numerical volatilityof the forward priceFj(t)) andρij =

γii

ã

γjj . The dynamics of the forward prices Fj(t) then becomes

dFj(t) =Fj(t)σj(t)dVjT(t)

for PT-Brownian motionsVjT(t) defined by dVjT(t) =γj(t)1γj(t)ãdWtT which are one dimensional and correlated by dViT, VjTt=ρij(t)dt(III.6.b.0). Then

log(Fj)Tt = T

t

σ2j(s)ds, log(F1), log(F2)Tt = T

t

(σ1σ2ρ12)(s)ds

and log(F1/F2)Tt = T

t

(σ12+σ222σ1σ2ρ12)(s)ds.

4.e Delta hedging. A replicating strategyθ for a European optionhis also called a hedge for h with the interpretation that a seller of h will trade in the market according toθto hedge the random payoff hat timeT.

Assume now thatAis a numeraire asset such thatξAis a martingale. Then the local martingale measure PA is defined. Assume that the market B contains only finitelymanysecurities and thatAis a securityofBand writeB= (A, B1, . . . , Bn).

For a process X(t) we writeXA(t) =X(t)/A(t) as usual.

Now let h be a European option exercisable at time T and write πt(h) = ξ(t)1EP

ξ(T)h|Ft

,t∈[0, T]. Thenξ(t)πt(h) is aP-martingale and henceπAt(h) a PA-martingale (3.d.0.(b)).

4.e.0 Delta Hedging. Assume that the process πtA(h)can be written in the form πAt(h) =F

t, BA(t)

=F

t, B1A(t), . . . , BnA(t)

, t∈[0, T], (0) for some function F =F(t, b) = F(t, b1, . . . , bn) C1,2

[0, T]×Rn+

. Let θ(t) = K(t), H1(t), . . . , Hn(t)

be the trading strategy investing in B = (A, B1, . . . , Bn) defined by

Hj(t) = ∂F

∂bj

t, BjA(t)

and K(t) =F

t, BA(t)

n

j=1Hj(t)BjA(t).

Thenθ is a replicating strategy forh.

Remark. HereF =F(t, b)∈C1,2([0, T]×Rn+) is to be interpreted as in III.3.a.1, that is,F is continuous on [0, T]×Rn+, the partial derivative∂f /∂texists on (0, T)×R+n

Một phần của tài liệu Continuous Stochastics calculus with Applications to Finance (Trang 268 - 293)

Tải bản đầy đủ (PDF)

(337 trang)