1. Trang chủ
  2. » Ngoại Ngữ

Barriers - Simple European Options

12 240 0
Tài liệu đã được kiểm tra trùng lặp

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 12
Dung lượng 243,3 KB

Nội dung

15 Barriers: Simple European Options Barrier options are like simple options but with an extra feature which is triggered by the stock price passing through a barrier The feature may be that the option ceases to exist (knock-out) or starts to exist (knock-in) or is changed into a different option These are the archetypal exotics and constitute the majority of exotic options sold in the market (Reiner and Rubinstein, 1991a) The general topic is a large one and we have chosen to spread it across two chapters (plus a fair chunk of the Appendix), rather than concentrating everything into one indigestible monolith If the reader is approaching the subject for the first time, he may feel daunted by the sizes of the formulas and by the number of large integrals; but he should make a point of stepping back to understand the underlying principles rather than drowning in the minutiae There are in fact only a couple of integrals which are just applied over and over again This chapter lays out the basic principles and is a direct continuation of the analysis of the Black Scholes model, given in Chapter The following chapter applies these principles to a number of more complex situations; it finishes with an explanation of how to apply trees to pricing barrier options numerically 15.1 SINGLE BARRIER CALLS AND PUTS (i) The reader should refer to Appendix A.8 which lays out the framework for this chapter The key result in this context is given by equation (A8.4) Imagine a Brownian particle starting at x0 = 0; the probability distribution function of just those particles that have crossed a barrier at b is Fcrossers (x T , T ) = Freturn (x T , T ) for x T on the same side of the barrier as x0 F0 (x T , T ) for x T on the other side of the barrier F0 (x T , T ) is the normal distribution function for a particle starting at x0 = and with unrestrained movement, i.e F0 (x T , T ) dx T = 1 x T − mT exp − √ √ σ 2π T σ T 1 dx T = √ e− z T dz T = n(z T ) dz T 2π Freturn (x T , T )is the distribution function at time T , for those particles starting at x0 = 0, crossing the barrier at b and then returning back across the barrier before time T It is shown in Appendix A.8(iii) that this can be written Freturn (x T , T ) = AF0 (x T − 2b, T ), where the term F0 (x T − 2b, T ) is the normal distribution for a particle starting at x0 = 2b and A = exp(2mb/σ ); m is the drift rate of x T We can then write 2mb 1 x T − 2b − mT exp − √ √ σ σ 2π T σ T 2mb = exp √ e− z T dz T = An(z T ) dz T σ2 2π Freturn (x T , T ) dx T = exp dx T 15 Barriers: Simple European Options (ii) We will now apply these results to stock price movements Consider a stock with a starting price ST in the presence of a barrier K Closely following the Black Scholes analysis of Section 5.2, we write x T = ln(ST /S0 ) and note that x T is normally distributed with mean mT and variance σ T , where m = r − q − σ We use the notation b = ln(K /S0 ), so that 2 A = exp(2mb/σ ) = (K /S0 )2m/σ In the remainder of this section, various knock-in options will be evaluated These will involve a transformation from the variable ST to either of the variables z T or z T , which were defined in the last subsection by ST = S0 emT +σ √ T zT = S0 emT +2b+σ √ T zT When setting up the integral for evaluating a call option, we integrate with respect to ST from X to ∞ On transforming to the variables z T or z T , the integrals will run from Z X to ∞ or from Z X to ∞, where ZX = ln(X/S0 ) − mT ; √ σ T ZX = ln(X/S0 ) − mT − 2b √ σ T Analogous limits of integration z K and z K are defined by ZK = ln(K /S0 ) − mT ; √ σ T ZK = ln(K /S0 ) − mT − 2b √ σ T (iii) Explicit Calculations: In this section we calculate two specific examples in order to illustrate how the formulas for prices are obtained It would be repetitive and boring to this for every possible knock-in option However, generalized results for all options are given later in the chapter Freturn F00 f0 X K S0 Example (a): Down-and-in Call; X < K The option Figure 15.1 Down-and-in call; X < K is explained schematically in Figure 15.1 The probability density function Fcrossers is different on each side of the barrier as shown The price of the option is written +∞ Cd−i (X < K ) = e−r T (ST − X )+ Fcrossers dST = e−r T (ST − X )Fcrossers dST X K = e−r T +∞ (ST − X )F0 dST + e−r T X ∞ (ST − X )Freturn dST K The first integral on the right-hand side can be split into two manageable parts as follows: K e−r T X (ST − X )F0 dST = e−r T ∞ (ST − X )F0 dST − e−r T X ∞ (ST − X )F0 dST K = [BSC ] − [GC ] The first integral here is just the Black Scholes formula for a call with strike X The second integral is the formula for a gap option which was described in Section 11.4 178 15.1 SINGLE BARRIER CALLS AND PUTS To evaluate the second integral in the expression for Cd−i (X < K ), we make the transformation to the standard normal variate z T described in subsection (ii) and use the integral result of equations (A1.7): ∞ [JC ] = e−r T (ST − X )Freturn dST = e−r T K ∞ (S0 emT +2b+σ √ T zT zK = A e−r T S0 e2b+(m+ σ )T − X )An(z T ) dz T √ N[σ T − Z K ] − X N[−Z K ] The value of this option can then be written Cd−i (X < K ) = [BSC ] − [GC ] + [JC ] Example (b): Up-and-in Put; K < X The reasoning in this example is precisely analogous to that of the last example (see Figure 15.2) The reader is asked to pay particular attention to the signs of the various terms: +∞ Pu−i (K < X ) = e−r T (X − ST )+ Fcrossers dST Freturn F0 K S0 X K = e−r T Figure 15.2 Up-and-in put; K < X (X − ST )Freturn dST X + e−r T (X − ST )F0 dST K The second integral on the right may be written X e−r T X (X − ST )F0 dST = e−r T K K (X − ST )F0 dST − e−r T (X − ST )F0 dST = [BS P ] − [G P ] As in the previous example, the first term is the Black Scholes formula (for a put option this time) while the second term is again a gap option The first integral is solved by making the same transformation as in the last example and using the integral result of equations (A1.7): K [J P ] = e−r T (X − ST )Freturn dST = e−r T = A e−r T X N[Z K ] − S0 e2b+(m+ σ )T ZK (X − S0 emT +2b+σ −∞ √ N[Z K − σ T ] √ T zT )An(z T ) dz T The value of the option is written Pu−i (K < X ) = [BS P ] − [G P ] + [J P ] (iv) Generalizing the Results: If the reader compares the results of the last two examples he will be struck by how similar they are The essential differences are: r The first example is for a call while the second is for a put Each of the terms reflects this difference, which can be accommodated by the use of the parameter φ(= +1 for a call 179 15 r Barriers: Simple European Options and −1 for a put); this was explained in Section 5.2(iv) where we wrote a general Black Scholes formula which could be used for either a put or a call If we make use of the parameter φ, we can almost write a general expression which could be applied to either of the last two examples There is, however, still a difference in the term [J]: the signs of the arguments of the cumulative normal functions are reversed This is essentially due to the fact that the limits of integration were Z K to +∞ in the first example and −∞ to Z K in the second; the difference comes because the stock price had to fall to reach the barrier in the first example but rise in the second Therefore a factor ψ(= +1 for rise-to-barrier and −1 for fall-to-barrier) multiplying the arguments of the cumulative normal function of [J] would allow us to write a general expression which prices either Cd−i (X < K ) or Pu−i (K < X ) 15.2 GENERAL EXPRESSIONS FOR SINGLE BARRIER OPTIONS The reader should now be in a position to derive a formula for any knock-in option If he really enjoys integration, he can work out the integral results for all the puts and calls with barriers in different positions Without showing all the detailed workings, we give the results in the next subsection First, however, we take note of a simple but powerful relationship: Knock-in Option + Knock-out Option = European Option This result is obvious if we consider a portfolio consisting of two options which are the same except that one knocks in and the other knocks out Whether or not the barrier is crossed, the payoff is that of a European option This relationship allows us to calculate all the knock-out formulas from the knock-in results The following definitions are used: √ N[φ(σ T − Z X )] − X N[−φ Z X ] √ [G] = e−r T φ S0 e(m+ σ )T N[φ(σ T − Z K )] − X N[−φ Z K ] √ [H] = A e−r T φ S0 e2b+(m+ σ )T N[ψ(Z X − σ T )] − X N[ψ Z X ] √ [J] = A e−r T φ S0 e2b+(m+ σ )T N[ψ(Z K − σ T )] − X N[ψ Z K ] [BS] = e−r T φ S0 e(m+ σ ψ= ZK )T +1 up to barrier −1 down to barrier m = r − q − σ 2; ln(X/S0 ) − mT ; √ σ T ln(K /S0 ) − mT ; = √ σ T ZX = b = ln(K /S0 ); φ= +1 −1 call put A = exp(2mb/σ ) = (K /S0 )2m/σ ln(X/S0 ) − mT − 2b √ σ T ln(K /S0 ) − mT − 2b ZK = √ σ T ZX = The formulas for all the single barrier options are given in Tables 15.1 and 15.2 180 15.3 SOLUTIONS OF THE BLACK SCHOLES EQUATION Table 15.1 Single barrier knock-in options Calls Cd−i (X Cd−i (K Cu−i (X Cu−i (K Puts < K) < X) < K) < X) Pu−i (K Pu−i (X Pd−i (K Pd−i (X Formula < X) < K) < X) < K) [BS] − [G] + [J] [H] [G] + [J] − [H] [BS] Table 15.2 Single barrier knock-out options Calls Cd−o (X Cd−o (K Cu−o (X Cu−o (K Puts < K) < X) < K) < X) Pu−o (K Pu−o (X Pd−o (K Pd−o (X Formula < X) < K) < X) < K) [G] − [J] [BS] − [H] [BS] − [G] − [J] + [H] 15.3 SOLUTIONS OF THE BLACK SCHOLES EQUATION (i) The general approach to pricing barrier options has been to use the Fokker Planck equation to derive an analytic expression for the probability distribution function of particles crossing a barrier This explicit probability density function is then used to calculate an expression for the value of a knock-in option; the knock-out option prices are obtained from the symmetry relationship which states that the sum of the values of a knock-out and a knock-in option equals the value of the corresponding European option In Appendix A.4 we discuss the close relationship between the Kolmogorov equations and the Black Scholes equation A reader might well ask why we bothered to go to the trouble of a two-step solution (first, find the probability distribution function; second, calculate the riskneutral expected payoff), rather than solving the Black Scholes equation directly The reason is partly historical: at the time when people first needed to calculate a formula for a barrier option, the expression for the transition probability density function for a Brownian particle in the presence of an absorbing barrier had already been worked out; it was just a question of looking it up in the right book But there are other good reasons for the approach adopted: it allows a unified approach to all knock-in options with an emphasis on the underlying processes in terms of probabilities The pure solution of differential equations can be rather sterile, without much reference to underlying processes Furthermore, in some cases, the boundary conditions for the Black Scholes model are rather hard to apply We will therefore content ourselves here by sketching out the approach to a relatively easy example: the down-and-out call (X < K ) which is the “out” equivalent of the down-and-in call illustrated in Figure 15.1 The approach is identical to that of Section 5.3 where we solved the Black Scholes equation for a European call option The fundamental equation is unchanged We seek a solution in the range K < S0 < ∞ subject to the following initial and boundary conditions: r C(S0 , 0) = max[0, S0 − X ]; X < K; r limS →K C(S0 , T ) → r limS →∞ C(S0 , T ) → S0 e−qT − X e−r t K < S0 < ∞ 0 181 15 Barriers: Simple European Options Using the notation and transformations of Section 5.3, the Black Scholes equation becomes ∂v/∂ T = ∂ v/∂ x with initial and boundary conditions r v(x, 0) = max[0, e(k+1)x − X ekx ]; ln X < b; r limx→b v(x,T ) → r limx→∞ v(x,T ) → e(k+1)x+(k+1) T − X ekx+k T b < x0 < ∞; b = ln K The solutions of this type of equation are given by equations (A6.8) or (A7.10) in the Appendix: +∞ v(x, T ) = b ekx max[0, ex − X ] √ πT exp − (y − x)2 (y + x + 2b)2 −exp − 4T 4T dy We can replace [0, ex − X ] by ex − X since this is always positive in the range of integration It then just remains to follow the computational procedures set out in Section 5.3 to work out this integral; unsurprisingly, the answer is the same as that given in Table 15.1 15.4 TRANSITION PROBABILITIES AND REBATES (i) First Passage or Absorption Probabilities: The pseudo-probability of a barrier above being crossed is straightforward to calculate It is simply the sum of the probabilities of a particle crossing and returning, and a particle crossing and staying across In terms of equity prices, this is written Pcros sin g = = ∞ −∞ ZK −∞ Fcrossers dST = An(z T ) dz T + K ∞ Freturn dST + −∞ +∞ ZK F0 dST K n(z T ) dz T = A N[Z K ] + N[−Z K ] There is an analogous expression for the pseudo-probability of crossing a barrier below, and the general expression can be written Pcros sin g = A N[ψ Z K ] + N[−ψ Z K ] = exp (b + mT ) (b − mT ) 2mb N −ψ + N −ψ √ √ σ2 σ T σ T (15.1) It should be remembered that this is a pseudo-probability in a risk-neutral world It is not the probability in the real world that an option will be knocked in or out (ii) Knock-in Rebate: Occasionally, barrier options are structured so that the purchaser receives a lump sum payment if his investment strategy does not work For example, if he buys a knock-in option and the stock price does not reach the barrier before maturity, he receives a fixed amount R at maturity The upfront value of this rebate is simply the present value of R multiplied by the pseudoprobability of the barrier not being reached: Rmaturity = e−r T R(1 − Pcros sin g ) where Pcros sin g is given in the last subsection 182 15.5 BINARY (DIGITAL) OPTIONS WITH BARRIERS (iii) Knock-out Rebate: More common than for knock-in options, rebates are often given as consolation prizes with knock-out options However, the calculation of this type of rebate is more complex since the lump sum is paid as soon as the knock-out occurs; we cannot then calculate the present value just by discounting back over the period T In Appendix A.8(vii) it is seen that the first passage time τ (time to first crossing) is a random variable with a well-defined probability distribution function gabs (τ ) = ψb exp − (b − mτ )2 √ 2σ τ σ 2π τ By definition, we can write Pcros sin g = exp 2mb (b + mT ) (b − mT ) N −ψ + N −ψ √ √ σ σ T σ T (15.2) The value of a knock-out rebate of $1 is given by the following integral: T Rfirst passage = e−r τ gabs (τ ) dτ On the face of it, this looks like a very difficult integral to solve: but a little trick helps; completing the square in the exponential gives e−r τ gabs (τ ) = exp − = exp − b(γ − m) σ2 ψb exp − (b + γ τ )2 √ 2σ τ σ 2π τ b(γ − m) h abs (τ ) σ2 √ where γ = m + 2r σ and h abs (τ ) is the same as gabs (τ ), but with the replacement m → γ Using the result of equation (15.2), we can write T Rfirst passage = e−r τ gabs (τ ) dτ = exp − = exp − b(γ − m) σ2 exp b(γ − m) σ2 T h abs (τ ) dτ 2γ b (b − γ T ) (b + γ T ) N −ψ + N −ψ √ √ σ2 σ T σ T (15.3) 15.5 BINARY (DIGITAL) OPTIONS WITH BARRIERS (i) Recap of Straight Binaries: Referring back to Section 11.4(iv), a gap option can be written as (Reiner and Rubinstein, 1991b) f gap = φ{S0 [BS]1 − R[BS]2 } = f asset − f cash where [BS]1 and [BS]2 are the first and second terms in the Black Scholes formula R is a cash sum which may or may not be equal to the strike price X ; if it is, we just have the formula for a put or a call option φ(= ±1) differentiates between puts and calls f asset and f cash are the prices of asset-or-nothing and cash-or-nothing options with strike X 183 15 Barriers: Simple European Options (ii) Barrier options may be decomposed into digital options in just the same way This is best illustrated by way of an example Returning to the example of Section 15.1(iii), the formula for the down-and-in call can be decomposed as described in the last subsection: Cd−i (X < K ) = {S0 [BSC ]1 − X [BSC ]2 } − {S0 [GC ]1 − X [GC ]2 } + {S0 [JC ]1 − X [JC ]2 } Freturn $1 F0 X K S0 Figure 15.3 Digital knock in: downand-in; cash or nothing Collect together the terms in −X ; its coefficient [BSC ]2 − [GC ]2 + [JC ]2 is the price of an option with the following payoff at time T (Figure 15.3): • $1, if the barrier has been crossed and X < ST ; • otherwise Similarly, the terms in S0 give the price of an option with the following payoff at time T (Figure 15.4): r ST , if the barrier has been crossed and X < ST ; r otherwise These last two examples are of course, for specific configurations of S0 , X and K Formulas for other configurations can be obtained from Tables 15.1 and 15.2 Freturn F0 (iii) One Touch Options (Immediate Payment): The bi- S0 X K nary options of the last subsection give a positive payoff if two conditions are met: the barrier is Figure 15.4 Digital knock in: down-andcrossed and the option expires in-the-money One in; asset or nothing touch options are closely related but not have the second condition They also pay out as soon as the barrier has been crossed The one-touch cash-immediately option with payout R is clearly just the same as the knockout rebate and is priced by equation (15.3) The one-touch asset-immediately option is priced in just the same way: at time τ when the barrier is crossed, Sτ is equal to K ; but Sτ is the payout, so we price this option as a knock-out rebate in which the lump sum payment is equal to K (iv) One Touch Options (Payout at Expiry): These are simple adaptations of previously obtained formulas: Cash at expiry: use e−r T R Pcros sin g Asset at expiry uses the appropriate digital barrier option, putting the strike price equal to zero 15.6 COMMON APPLICATIONS (i) American Capped Calls (Exploding Calls): These are American call options in which the payout is capped at a certain certain amount (K − X ), irrespective of when the option is exercised A European capped call is the same as a call spread If we buy a call with strike X and sell a call with a higher strike K , the maximum payoff of the combination at maturity is (K − X ) 184 15.6 COMMON APPLICATIONS However, this structure does not carry over to American options because each option holder can choose when to exercise: the person to whom we have sold the call may not wish to exercise when we The American capped call can instead be priced as an up-and-out call, (X < K ) with a rebate of (K − X ) paid at knock out A similar approach is used to price an American capped put (ii) Ladders: When investors buy European call options, it is not uncommon for them to watch the price of S0 K1 K2 K3 the underlying stock soar, and with it the value of the option – only to see both plunge out-of-the-money at maturity Ladder options have payoffs which capture the effects of such movements The simplest form of such a scheme would be a series of one-touch cash-immediately options The payoffs would be r K − S0 received as soon as the stock price reaches K ; r K − K received as soon as the stock price reaches K ; etc (iii) Fixed Strike Ladders: The simple ladder of the last subsection does not really display the features of a call option There are two commonly used structures which are fundamentally call options but which at the same X K1 K2 time capture large up-swings in the stock price (Street, 1992) The fixed strike ladder has the following payoff (we assume for simplicity that the call option is at-the-money, i.e S0 = X ): r If St never reaches K , we just have a plain call option with strike X ; r If St gets as far as K before maturity, the call payoff has a minimum of K − X ; r If St gets as far as K , the minimum payoff is K − X ; etc The combination of options which gives this payoff is summarized below The analysis is easiest to follow by referring to Figure 15.5 knock in K knock in atat 2K2 X knock in at K knockin at K 1 • C(X ) Buy a European call option, strike X K1 K2 If St never rises above K , this gives the payoff knock in at KK1 knock in atat K2 knock in at K knock in needed • Pu−i (K , K ) − Pu−i (X, K ) Buy a knock-in put, strike K and sell a knock-in put, strike X Figure 15.5 Construction of fixed strike If at some point St crosses K (but not K ), ladder there are two possibilities: if the final stock price ST is between K and K , the two knocked-in puts are out-of-the-money so the payoff comes just from the original call option: ST − X For ST anywhere below K , the payoff is (K − X ) • Pu−i (K , K ) − Pu−i (K , K ) As in the last step, we have a long put with strike K and a short put with strike K , both of which knock in at K We use precisely the same reasoning as for the last step: if at some point St crosses K , there are two possibilities: we have a call option payoff for K < ST and a payoff (K − X ) for all ST < K , etc 185 15 Barriers: Simple European Options (iv) Floating Strike Ladders: This structure captures large downward swings in the stock price, by changing the strike price to lower values as barriers are crossed The payoff is as follows: K2 K1 X never reaches K , we just have the call option with strike X If St reaches K (but not K ) before maturity, the call option with strike X is replaced by a call with strike K If St reaches K , the call option with strike K is replaced by a call with strike K , etc r If St r r The structure of the barrier options needed to produce this payoff is simpler to follow than in the last subsection (see Figure 15.6) • C(X ) Buy a European call option with strike X knock at K knock inin at K2 knock inin at K knock at K If St never falls as far as K , this gives the payoff we need X • Cd−i (K , K ) − Cd−i (X, K ) Buy a knock-in K K1 knock at K knock inin at K1 call option with strike K and sell a knock-in call knock at K knock inin at K with strike X ; both knock in at K The sold option cancels the original call option of the first step above, and we are left with a new call, Figure 15.6 Construction of floating strike ladder strike K • Cd−i (K , K ) − Cd−i (K , K ) Again, the second of these cancels the call option left from the previous step The net result is that if these two options knock in (St crosses the K barrier), we are left with a call option, strike K , etc 2 15.7 GREEKS By their nature, barrier options display a sudden increase or decrease in value as the stock price crosses a barrier We have already seen in the discussion of digital options in Section 11.4(v) that sudden changes in option value for small changes in the price of the underlying stock can cause 20.00 problems in hedging (i) Figure 15.7 shows the value of an up-and-out call option plot10.00 ted against the stock price Far from the barrier, the value of the option coincides with that of the corresponding European call op90.00 100.00 110.00 120.00 130.00 tion In this region the probability of a knock-out is remote; but Figure 15.7 Up-and-out call option as the barrier is approached, the value of the knock-out option declines sharply This creates a very pointed peak in the value of the option; put another way, the negative gamma of the option becomes very 186 15.8 STATIC HEDGING large In fact, because of the sharpness of the peak, the negative gamma of this type of option is more pronounced than for any other option commonly encountered in the market Trading operations would usually avoid dealing in an option of this type except in small size All barrier options have some sort of discontinuity: but this does not mean that they are all prone to gamma blow-up Figure 15.8 shows a down-and-in call where the barrier is out-of-the-money At high stock prices, the value of the op- 5.00 tion is small since the probability Call of knock-in is small As the price Option K drops, the likelihood of knock- 3.00 in increases, but at the barrier the underlying call option is outof-the-money and consequently Knock in 1.00 Call has small value This type of option therefore presents less of a 95.00 100.00 105.00 problem than the last example; but even in this case, the delta Figure 15.8 Down-and-in call option moves from being negative (for the down-and-in call) to being positive (European call option) when the barrier is crossed 15.8 STATIC HEDGING (i) The difficulty of hedging barrier options has led practitioners to try to find alternatives to the standard delta hedging techniques Dynamic hedging works well for relatively benign options such as standard puts and calls, but can be very risky and expensive for options which have very high gamma over long periods Take the example of the down-and-in call option which is illustrated in Figure 15.8 A glance at the graph shows that while the stock price remains above the barrier, the general form of the option price is similar to that of a put option; but as soon as the barrier is touched, the option becomes a standard call option When these types of option were first introduced in the market, traders soon realized that there is a simple hedging strategy: sell a put option when the option is first taken on; then buy back the put and sell a call if and when the barrier is reached There are a couple of difficulties with this strategy: first, it assumes that we can exactly exchange the short put for a short call at precisely the point when the stock price hits the barrier; this can be a challenge if the market is lively Second, what type and amounts of puts and calls we need? To answer this question we need to make a short diversion (ii) Put-Call Symmetry: Recall (Carr and Bowie, 1994) from the put–call parity relationship of Section 2.2(i) that if the forward rate equals the strike price (F0T = X or S0 e−qT = X e−r T ), then the values of a put and a call option are the same: C0 (S0 , F0T , T ) = P0 (S0 , F0T , T ) The Black Scholes formula for a call option on one share with strike X C , and a put option on 187 15 Barriers: Simple European Options n shares with strike X P , is taken from equations (5.1) and (5.2): C0 (S0 , X C , T ) = e−r T {F0T N[dC1 ] − X N[dC2 ]} n P0 (S0 , X P , T ) = n e−r T {X N[−d P2 ] − F0T N[−d P1 ]} √ 1 F0T di1 = √ + σ 2T ; di2 = di1 − σ T ; ln Xi σ T i = C or P We can easily confirm the put–call parity result previously obtained by using these two pricing formulas and putting n = 1, F0T = X C = X P (i.e ln F0T / X = 0) and N[a] = − N[−a] A further relationship between puts and calls, known as put–call symmetry, may be deduced from the above Black Scholes formulas if we put n = F0T /X P = X C /F0T Substituting for n and for X P from this last relationship into the second Black Scholes formula above gives C0 (S0 , X C , T ) = n P0 S0 , F0T ,T ; XC n= XC F0T This says that at any time before maturity, a call option with strike X C is equal in value to n put options with strike X P (= F0T / X C ) In the special case where there is no drift (i.e r = q or F0T = S0 ), the call option is equal in value to n = X C /S0 put options with strike X P = S0 / X C (iii) Replication of a Down-and-in Call: Using the put–call symmetry of the last subsection, we will now devise a strategy to replicate the down-and-in call option illustrated in Figure 15.9 XP K S0 XC • If the stock price always remains above K , there Figure 15.9 Put–call symmetry; down-and-in call will be no payoff under the knock-in option • Once the stock price has touched the barrier at K, the option becomes a call option with strike X C At the point ( t = τ ) when the stock price touches K we need to buy a call option with strike X C and maturity T • The cost of this call will be C(K , X C , T − τ ); what instrument can we buy today which will have this value in time τ ? • Let us make the simplifying assumption that the stock price has no drift, i.e that Fτ T = Sτ The result given at the end of the last subsection shows that with this assumption, n = X C /K put options with strike X P = K / X would have precisely the same value as the call option which we need to buy • Our strategy is therefore to buy this package of puts for a price n P(S0 , K / X, T ) If the stock price drops to K , these puts would have appreciated to the point where we can afford to buy the call we need Note that the above strategy strictly depends on the no-drift assumption; without this condition, the strike price and the number of put options depends on τ However, for relatively small values of drift the technique remains useful, perhaps augmented by a small amount of delta hedging Unfortunately, this neat static approach can only be applied to half the barrier options 188 ... are the prices of asset-or-nothing and cash-or-nothing options with strike X 183 15 Barriers: Simple European Options (ii) Barrier options may be decomposed into digital options in just the same... plunge out-of-the-money at maturity Ladder options have payoffs which capture the effects of such movements The simplest form of such a scheme would be a series of one-touch cash-immediately options. .. 15.5 BINARY (DIGITAL) OPTIONS WITH BARRIERS (iii) Knock-out Rebate: More common than for knock-in options, rebates are often given as consolation prizes with knock-out options However, the calculation

Ngày đăng: 25/10/2013, 19:20

TỪ KHÓA LIÊN QUAN