1. Trang chủ
  2. » Giáo Dục - Đào Tạo

Economics and environmental implications of carbon taxation in malaysia, a computable general equilibrium approach

14 6 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 14
Dung lượng 275,56 KB

Nội dung

Economics and Environmental Implications of Carbon Taxation in Malaysia: A Computable General Equilibrium Approach Pui Kiew Ling University of Malaya, Malaysia Abstract Due to high use of energy input in industrialization process, Malaysia has experienced a continuous rise in emission coinciding with the period of rapid economic development Against the backdrop, the paper has taken initiatives to examine the economy-wide impacts of carbon taxation in Malaysian economy The inevitable use of energy inputs in production chains and consumption necessitates an assessment covering economy-wide framework The paper, has therefore applied, computable general equilibrium model for the empirical analysis The model adopts Malaysia Input-Output Tables 2010 as the main database in the simulation The investigation assumes three hypothetical carbon taxation ranged from RM50/tonne to RM300/tonne (~USD12-70/tonne) CO2 These tax rates are imposed on crude oil, natural gas, and coal which are the main energy inputs to produce petroleum products and electricity The simulation result shows that the carbon taxation is effective to control the rise in CO2 emissions in a positive economic performance, if the tax revenue is recycled back to the economy as compensation scheme Compared to the standalone carbon taxation policy, the tax recycling reform does appear more economically acceptable considering inflation impact and employment rate At sectoral level, the energy intensive industries become more efficient in managing their energy use, as intended As the policy implications, the paper recommends that the country may consider implementing carbon taxation by phased-in gradually to promote energy saving and emission control while keeping economic competitiveness In conclusion, Malaysia may introduce a policy package with a carefully designed carbon taxation system, in combination with revenue recycling measures, for a more balanced economic efficiency and environment conservation in transitioning towards a more sustainable economic growth Keyword: emission control; energy conservation; environmental fiscal reform; double dividend effect Introduction Following a rise in economic development and standard of living, the world CO emissions have been increasing throughout the period (IEA, 2016) The close economic-energy relation may has resulted an irreversible impact on the global economy in the future, if there is no mitigation action is taken against the rising use of energy commodities in production activities The concern for a continuous economic benefit reflects the urgency of tackling the energy-environmental impact, at both local as well as global levels Implementation of the Paris Agreement in 2015 contributes to the achievement of Sustainable Development Goals which helps to reduce emissions and builds climate resilience internationally A more practical key issue is to trace appropriate instruments for making progress on the emission mitigation pledge at country level, both developed and emerging economies 551 In Malaysia, the country has incurred a continuous economic growth since phrasing towards industrialization in 1980s Coinciding with economic development and a growing population, the country has been experiencing a continuous energy use over time (Department of Statistics Malaysia, 2018; EC, 2016; IEA, 2016) Compared to 2000, National Energy Balance 2015 states that final energy consumption has risen nearly 80% in 2015 The International Energy Agency reports further that CO emission in Malaysia has reached 220 million tonnes in 2015, which is almost double compared to 2000 One major contributing factor for the rising emission in the country is the failure of markets to take into account the environmental implications into prices, either directly on energy commodity itself, or on goods and services Theoretically, the emission cost, or simply called externalities, should be internalized by incorporating it into market prices For this purpose, past literature commonly agrees that carbon taxation is one effective economic instrument for achieving energy saving and environment conservation with the condition that it would continue to generate economic growth (Wang and Chen 2015) The carbon taxation plays a role in signaling an efficient use of energy input and output, which then influences the long term direction of economic development (Ekins and Speck, 1999) and environmental quality (Wolfson & Koopmans 1996) Theoretically, the tax rate is determined in proportion with quantity of emission produced, for instance per tonne of carbon6 (Speck 2013) The carbon tax could be imposed directly onto prices of energy input itself, or indirectly on goods and services By putting back the energy price to its market level, the carbon taxation would automatically adjust output production back to efficient level, which may then cut down emission to some extent (Wolfson & Koopmans 1996) At the same time, the carbon tax provides one mean to generate tax revenue for handling fiscal deficits The government could allocate the tax revenue to improve economic performance and environmental quality The economic and environmental benefits, or the so called double dividend effect, makes the carbon taxation one attractive instrument for emission controlling while keeping economic competitiveness Refer to Table 11, transportation sector alone has accounted nearly one third of CO emission over the years 2001-2015 (Table 11) Petroleum product is the most crucial energy type used in the transportation sector In terms of energy mix, crude oil represents the most important energy input for petroleum products’ production in Malaysia (EC, 2016) Meanwhile, natural gas and coal accounts more than 80% of total energy inputs used in power stations (EC, 2016) This calls for an examination to impose carbon taxation on crude oil, natural gas, and coal to encourage an efficient use of petroleum products and electricity Table 11 Sectoral CO2 emissions in Malaysia (IEA, 2018) Year 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Total CO2 emissions from fuel combustion 108.8 115.7 122.8 136.2 138.0 154.0 177.4 180.9 164.2 185.0 194.0 195.9 Electricity including cogeneration 31.9 37.2 38.6 44.1 48.6 60.0 62.7 63.9 68.2 91.1 89.5 90.2 Other energy industry own use 11.5 9.8 14.1 14.5 10.5 11.3 22.9 25.8 16.3 10.5 21.0 17.3 Manufacturing industries and construction 27.7 29.8 29.6 34.1 35.2 39.3 46.4 43.7 32.9 32.2 32.8 38.0 Transport 33.6 34.4 36.6 39.3 39.2 38.7 40.0 42.1 41.3 42.4 43.0 42.9 A carbon tax could be translated into CO2 tax as a tonne of carbon corresponds to 3.67 tonnes of CO2 552 Land Transport 33.5 34.3 36.5 39.2 39.0 38.4 39.5 41.5 40.5 42.2 42.5 42.7 Other sectors 4.2 4.5 4.0 4.2 4.6 4.7 5.4 5.3 5.5 8.7 7.7 7.5 2013 2014 2015 207.2 220.5 220.4 95.9 98.2 103.1 17.9 21.0 20.4 29.1 28.6 28.8 56.7 65.5 61.4 56.5 63.4 59.0 7.7 7.2 6.7 The objective of the present paper is to analyze the economic and environmental implications of the carbon taxation With this regard, the present study has extended the relevant local literature by incorporating two contributions in the paper Firstly, Malaysia currently has not implemented carbon tax on energy inputs or goods and services In general, the carbon tax is not common in developing countries, considering the subsequent economic cost on inflation and export competitiveness Given the rising emission level in the country, a detailed study on economic impacts of carbon tax is therefore necessary, before actual implementation The study first conducts the investigation by retaining all the tax revenues in government’s coffers The reasons are, firstly, to trace the sole impacts of carbon taxation on the economy; and secondly, due to the increasing pressure to reduce the large government deficit A complementary measure may become necessary to reduce the economic cost of carbon taxation, if any Nevertheless, the significance of the carbon taxation in emerging economies especially is justified by its capacity to raise tax revenue From literature, political economic constraint posits that recycling carbon taxation revenue back to economy, or the so-called environmental fiscal reform, is always efficient than standalone carbon taxation in compensating economic loss The study therefore intends to re-examine the economic impacts of carbon taxation after allocating back all the tax revenues as cash transfer to households The purpose is to confirm whether tax revenue reallocation through environmental fiscal reform (EFR) is always better than the standalone carbon taxation in yielding double dividend effect The study adopts computable general equilibrium (CGE) model as method for the assessment The simulation results present a difference between the zero-tax scenario and the tax scenario The study conducts the simulation using the latest Malaysia IO Tables, 2010, as the main database The flow of investigation is guided with two hypotheses as stated below Answers for these two hypotheses give hints for the policymakers to evaluate whether the carbon taxation is one effective solution for slowing down the rising CO2 emissions in the country H1: The carbon taxation helps to reduce CO2 emissions, however at some economic costs H2: The tax revenue reallocation is more effective to generate double dividend effect The findings of this paper allow policymakers to take better and more informed decisions, by providing an economy-wide impact and cross-sectoral analysis of reducing emissions by implementing a national carbon tax Efficient energy consumption and stabilizing greenhouse emissions could come together with continuous economic growth with policy enforcements are undertaken appropriately The emissions control should be reduced by minimizing the unnecessary energy use, not at the cost of a lower output production The emissions decoupling should occur at a lower energy use and emissions control while keeping economic competitiveness The rest of this paper is structured as follows In Section 2, the study presents some relevant literature review to stress out the need of conducting this research Section provides some backgrounds of the CGE model and simulations employed to run the carbon taxation policy The next section provides empirical analysis of the simulations The analysis revolves economics and environmental impacts of the different carbon tax simulations at both macro and industrial level The paper proceeds with some corresponding policy recommendations and suggestions The final section provides some concluding remarks 553 Literature Review The carbon taxation itself plays a significance role in energy saving and environment conservation through a more efficient use of energy and a substitution towards less carbon intensive energy The carbon tax may influence carbon emission through a change in energy price Looking from economic perspective, the carbon tax may increase energy prices, as it is imposed directly on energy inputs or energy intensive products Due to cost consideration, some producers may pass on the cost increases to customers by charging higher output prices on energy input itself or final goods and services The price increase may lead to a drop-in demand for it, forcing its production levels down, and subsequently the emission level At economy-wide perspective, the subsequent impact on inflation and industrial competitiveness loss may result in some economic cost The extent of implications may vary with energy share in production, energy structure, industrial structure, as well as socioeconomic level (Zhang et al., 2016) The impacts may then spread to the whole economy through energy efficiency, energy substitution, production cost, industry competition, and labor market adjustment (Bruvoll and Larsen, 2004) The empirical studies have therefore long advocates the CGE model as one appropriate method for examining the economy-wide carbon taxation policy Currently, there are a handful of literature on economic and environmental impacts of carbon taxation At the earlier periods, the relevant literature is dominated by developed countries The developing countries have shown an increasing concern in making use of carbon taxation for emission mitigation in recent years In general, the literature agrees that carbon tax is one policy effective for handling the rising emission A recent literature by Guo and Liu (2016) found out that the carbon tax was effective to cut down energy use in especially the energy intensive sectors such as manufacturing and transportation industries Orlov et al (2013) wrote that the increase in energy prices caused a fall in demand for electricity and natural gas in Russia with coal as the most pronounced Bruvoll and Larsen (2004) found that carbon tax was effective to lead to a fall in emission intensity in Norwegian economy through a change in energy mix Similar evidence was obtained by Siriwardana et al (2011) from Australian economy that energy consumption and emissions were lower compared to without the carbon tax Nordhaus (2007) demonstrated that the long run effect on emission reduction should be greater than its short run effect One reason is that the carbon tax policy becomes more likely to induce energy saving or greener technology innovations as time passes These findings confirm the effectiveness of carbon tax on energy savings, as well as bringing down emissions level Further empirical studies show that the carbon tax, however, may cause at a slower economic growth as its opportunity cost Whether in developed countries or developing countries, the literature reveals that levying a carbon tax may generate a negative impact on economic growth As stated by Nurdianto and Resosudarmo (2016), the carbon taxation was effective for environmental gain in some Asia countries, yet it could come at a cost in terms of GDP contraction and decline in households welfare Cabalu et al (2015) also stated that the carbon taxation may result in a gain for the environment which is intended, with a cost in terms of GDP contraction as well as household income reduction in the Philippine economy The study by Siriwardana et al (2011) found out further that the introduction of the carbon tax in the Australian economy led to a contraction of the size of the economy overall, particularly it lowered real household consumption The similar results were also found in China where both Sun and Kuang (2015) and Zhang et al (2016) wrote that the carbon tax was helpful to reduce carbon emission, yet it was accompanied with a slowdown in the economic performance Meanwhile, in the Indonesian economy, Yusuf (2008) also found a slight fall in the GDP and private consumption after the carbon tax implementation McDougall (1993) estimated the short run sectoral and economy-wide effects of a carbon tax at a rate of $25 per tonne in Australian economy in the earlier period, 1991-92 Coinciding with studies at later periods, the results revealed that the CO2 emission did fall as expected, but real GDP performed lesser compared to without 554 the carbon tax Other macroeconomic indicators such as employment and export also responded negatively to the carbon tax The results basically yielded a consensus that the carbon tax reduced energy consumption and emissions, with a slight fall in economic growth However, if governments are persistent, the carbon tax policy may generate a positive impact on economy and environment one day Subsequent the carbon tax, the increase in production cost may induce sectors to adopt more energy efficient technologies or to shift towards a cleaner input mix among industries and households (Orlov et al., 2013), which accelerates the CO2 emission to fall In recent years, the concern on industries’ competitiveness loss has been frequently quoted as one reason for rejecting the carbon tax (Harnay and Rème, 2012) Among sectors with the potential for disproportionate impact include heavy manufacturing and energy intensive industries, which deserves a deeper consideration in policymaking Zhang et al (2016) revealed a significant contraction in energy intensive sectors’ output Liang et al (2016) demonstrated that without any complementary measures, a carbon tax may negatively affect export competitiveness of almost all tradable sectors Anderson and Ekins (2009) showed further that the introduction of carbon taxation may impair the competitiveness of some affected companies Meng (2012) mentioned that the introduction of carbon tax in Australia from July 2012 had triggered a tremendous fear in resources sectors Therefore, some countries offer tax exemption on a certain sector or an energy input type, in order to retain the industries’ competitiveness, as before the carbon tax introduction In empirical studies, Abrell (2012) found out that the exemption of transport sector generated a lesser welfare loss in European countries compared to without the tax exemption The past literature commonly agrees that, carbon tax is an effective step to reduce emission, but its rate should be imposed at appropriate rate for it to take effect Guo et al (2014) revealed that a moderate carbon tax was sufficient to reduce carbon emission and energy consumption, despite it may still came at a slight fall in economic growth Wang and Liang (2014) argued that the carbon tax policy could be introduced with a low rate at the initial stage as it may not strongly exacerbate inquietly in primary income distribution A higher carbon tax was not suggested at the initial implementation due to its possible impact to jeopardize economic impact and social welfare Sun and Kuang (2015) argued that the higher the tax rate, the higher the loss of GDP growth Chiu et al (2015) examined four possible carbon tax regimes ranging from US$20 to US$50 per ton of CO2 in the Taiwan gasoline market The paper found out that a higher level of carbon tax was more effective to induce a reduction in gasoline consumption, through a reflection in higher gasoline price Despite the effectiveness, Siriwardana et al.(2011) noted that sectoral outputs tend to contract at an increasing rate with the level of carbon tax One reason to explain the economic loss, as found out in the prior literature, is because the tax revenue is being retained in the economy as government’s extra income The priorities on economic development, poverty reduction, and improvement of living standards often lead to an opposition when the carbon taxation policy comes to actual implementation (Liang and Wei, 2012) The feasibility of carbon taxation in the real economy has become a source of controversy between economists and politicians which are often the policymakers Both parties agree on one consensus if the carbon taxation could stimulate a continuous economic development In the case, the carbon taxation policy may continue accessible if there is any instrument that could at least eliminate or hinder the subsequent economic costs The literature agrees that carbon taxation is still effective to reduce energy use and emissions, with the condition that the tax revenue is being recycled to accelerate economic growth and increase employment The tax revenue raising capacity (Speck, 2013) is one attractive key feature that convinces the politicians to implement or retain its implementation Abdullah and Morley (2014) found some evidences of short-run causality running from the increased revenue from the environmental tax to economic growth in some European and Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development countries Recycling the tax revenue to economic agents seems necessary to compensate or improve economic performance subsequent the introduction of carbon taxation 555 The economics and environmental implications of revenue recycling, better known as EFR, depends on how the tax revenues are being recycled ERT enables the carbon tax policy to be carried out in a revenueneutral way, that is leaving total tax revenues unchanged The essence of ETR is the shifting of the burden of taxation away from socially desirable economic activities such as on labor and capital to socially less desirable activities which entail negative environmental externalities (Vandyck and Van Regemorter, 2014) Note that ETR is not the introduction of new taxes Orlov et al (2013) conducted a thorough study to access the double dividend hypothesis from the sectoral and macroeconomic impact of carbon taxation on the Russian economy The empirical results showed that substituting the carbon taxation for the labor tax provided a simultaneous economic and environmental benefit, thereby signifying the existence of the double dividend effect Conefrey et al (2013) also found out that the carbon taxation was able to reduce emission and stabilize economic growth in Ireland, if the tax revenue was properly recycled to reduce existing distortionary tax in the economy Specifically, the paper found that the EFR was effective to yield a double dividend effect if the carbon taxation revenue was recycled through reduced income tax, but less likely through a lump-sum transfer to households Murray and Rivers (2015) supported that EFR through tax cuts and lump sum transfer to households generated a weak double dividend effect in British Columbia as the revenue recycling did mitigate some economic losses from the carbon taxation policy Further, Welsch and Ehrenheim (2004) found that EFR yielded a moderate double dividend effect in terms of reduced emissions with stabilized employment and economic growth in Germany The empirical works basically support policy coordination as always dominant over the standalone carbon taxation in the real economy Markandya et al (2013) revealed a similar result was obtained for the case of Spain where the revenue-recycling effect of using the tax revenues to reduce taxes on labor or capital or to make lump sum transfers to households was more likely to yield a double dividend effect compared to a standalone carbon taxation policy Compensation for potential losers seems necessary to increase the acceptance of carbon taxation policy as the tax reallocation always yield better economic impacts The empirical study by Siriwardana et al (2011) identified further that the substitution for the labor tax yielded a double dividend effect in the Australian economy Particularly, the paper demonstrated that cash transfers to households generated less expansionary pressure on the domestic economy compared to a reduction in commodity tax The negative impact on economic growth and factor income loss was reduced with a cut in other taxes, which is further supported by Liang and Wei (2012) Baranzini et al (2000) recognized that carbon taxation was a cost-effective instrument for reducing emissions in some European countries after its main negative impacts may be compensated through the design of the tax and the use of the generated fiscal revenues The revenue recycling could not only improve the environment quality but also it reduces the distortion of existing tax for instance income or labor tax These findings proved further that how to use the generated fiscal revenue is of fundamental importance in determining the final economic impact of carbon taxation In the Malaysia’s literature, despite its limited number, is emerging lately Among the most relevant studies, Nurdianto and Resosudarmo (2016) found that Malaysia could benefit economically from carbon tax as it counteracted price distortions due to the existence of fuel subsidy in the country Solaymani et al (2015) and its extended paper, Solaymani (2017) found that the carbon tax was more effective than the equivalent energy tax to reduce carbon emissions as it involved lesser cost in terms of real GDP and investment Solaymani et al (2015) showed that lump sum household transfer was more effective than labor tax recycling in compensating the economic cost of carbon taxation with the reason that the tax interaction effect was less remarkable compared to the tax recycling effect Private consumption and households’ welfare increased after the tax revenue was reallocated to the economy through lump sum transfer In comparison, the labor tax recycling was not as effective as to raise the double dividend effect where the household’s consumption and welfare seem failed to increase up to the level as before the carbon taxation introduction 556 Method The present study adopts CGE model to simulate the economic and environmental impact of the carbon taxation Due to the close link between energy commodities and the whole economy, the carbon taxation is better analyzed using a general equilibrium framework The model could provide a comprehensive analysis of the economy-wide impacts of the carbon taxation The CGE model is preferred over partial equilibrium model or econometrics because of this capacity of representing the complex interdependencies in the whole economy (Lin and Ouyang, 2014) The investigation employs Malaysia Input-Output Tables 2010 as the main database in the simulation There are originally 124 industries and type of commodities in the IO table To suit the need of simulation, the paper has disaggregated the petroleum refinery commodity into four: gasoline, diesel, biodiesel, and other fuel The parameters of the functions in the model are adapted mainly from literature on other CGE models, and intelligent guessing when literature is not available 3.1 CO2 Emissions While energy inputs influence output production, the combustion of energy releases emissions into the atmosphere The present study has incorporated CO2 emissions matrix to simulate the economic impacts of carbon taxation This study focuses specifically on CO2, since it makes up the largest proportion of pollutants Following the formula used by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (Temurshoev 2006), this study calculates CO2 emissions by multiplying energy consumption 𝑄 with energy’s carbon content 𝐶𝐶, the carbon oxidation factor 𝜛, and the molecular weight ratio of emissions δ (Equation 1): CO2𝑒,𝑖 = 𝑄𝐶𝐶𝜛δ (1) The present paper focuses on CO2 emission produced by industries and households Data on energy consumption 𝑄 is obtained from in the Malaysia Input-Output Tables 2010 The energy matrix in the Malaysia Input-Output Tables 2010 is converted first to physical terms Then, the energy data is multiplied with emission factor to derive CO2 emission matrix Express it in a percentage change form: ∆CO2𝑒,𝑖 = ∆𝐸𝑒,𝑖 (2) 3.2 Simulations The CO2 Emission from Fuel Combustion Highlights 2016 Edition, published by the International Energy Agency, has long recognized transportation, and electricity sectors among the largest CO2 emitters in Malaysia for decades The high CO2 emissions in the transportation sector is attributable to heavy reliance on petroleum products (EC, 2016), for instance petrol and diesel as energy source Given the high share of natural gas and coal in total energy mix, it explains the reason CO2 emissions always increase in power plant The CO emissions from the electricity sector is very likely to rise in the future if service sector continues to excel This indicates a necessity to encourage a further efficient energy use in these sectors for achieving a more sustainable economic development These tax rates are imposed on crude oil, natural gas, and coal, which are the main energy inputs to produce petroleum products and electricity The carbon taxation on these three kind of energy inputs covers nearly 90% of total primary energy supply in Malaysia for the 2015 (EC, 2016) Instead of taxing petroleum product itself, the paper puts an arbitrary tax on crude oil for two reasons; political resistance and possibly unequal distribution impacts on lower-income households The paper does not impose carbon taxation on electricity (Wissema and Dellink, 2007) consumption because its use does not cause emissions directly Despite the electricity consumption does not cause CO2 emissions directly, the electricity generation process involves a lot 557 of primary energy which has caused large CO2 emissions (Ren et al., 2014) The amount of CO2 emissions produced from the power plant depends on electricity generation technologies, energy intensity, and energy mix For this reason, the paper introduces arbitrarily tax on its intermediate energy including natural gas and coal This approach avoids double-taxing where only primary energy is taxed in the electricity and transportation industries; petroleum products and electricity are secondary energy In expectation, the carbon taxation imposed on crude oil should be effective to encourage local economic agents to consume petroleum products more efficiently during driving, which it contributes to an emission reduction This study also believes carbon taxation is effective to stimulate a more efficient energy use in power plant for electricity generation The subsequent price change is expected to encourage a more efficient electricity consumption among local economic agents especially the energy intensive industries and households Instead of the form of ad valorem, the carbon tax is imposed as a specific tax by charging the amount of money needed to pay for producing a certain quantity of CO emissions, that is ringgit per tonne of CO2 Regarding the tax rate, the study has imposed three carbon pricing ranged from RM50 to RM300 per tonne of CO2 emissions Since Malaysia has never implemented carbon taxation before, an initial stage better starts with a low rate first For the reason, the study imposes arbitrarily RM50 (~US$12) per tonne of CO2 emissions in the first scenario In the real world, developing countries prefer a lower tax rate than developed countries (Matsumoto, 2008) This main policy scenario is examined with two comparable tax scenarios, namely RM120 (~US$28) and RM300 (~US$70) per tonne of CO2 emissions The carbon price of RM120 is simulated merely to gauge the extent of variation of the impact if a carbon price usually imposed by developed countries is implemented in Malaysia The relative high carbon price RM300 would be contrasted with the low carbon price as RM50 and the medium carbon price as RM120 The comparison is conducted to recognize whether a high carbon tax could be more appropriate for stimulating a further emission cut Next, the study simulates to return all the tax revenue to the economy as cash transfer to households The present study repeats these four scenarios in both short run and long run economic environment Sensitivity test proceeds with doubling and halving the elasticity of substitution between diesel and biodiesel Time Period Short run Short run Short run Short run Scenario Long run Long run Long run Long run Type of Shock RM50 of carbon tax RM120 of carbon tax RM300 of carbon tax RM50 of carbon tax and tax revenue is handed back as a consumption subsidy RM50 of carbon tax RM120 of carbon tax RM300 of carbon tax RM50 of carbon tax and tax revenue is handed back as a consumption subsidy Results and Analysis 4.1 Macroeconomics Impacts Since the model used is comparative static type, the simulation output is interpreted as a new equilibrium after the economy system has adjusted to the shock The first column in Table 12 shows that an RM50 carbon tax rate resulted in a 0.0026 percent decline in real GDP in the short run The economic performance worsens with the rate of the carbon tax As energy goods are used by almost every sector, the carbon tax might lead to increase in prices of several goods and services As expected, the carbon tax came at the cost of inflationary pressure The shows that the consumer price index rose by 0.0163 percent more in the short run when the 558 carbon tax of RM50 per tonne was imposed That is, households needed to pay 0.0163 percent more for the same quantity of goods and services they purchased before the carbon tax policy The inflation thus weakened their purchasing power by 0.0163 percent If the economy increases the penalty on CO emissions, the economic performance may come at a higher economic cost and inflation At a carbon tax rate of RM120 per tonne, the economy incurred 0.0534 percent inflation in the short run The rise in price level may affect the economy on the demand side by cutting export and import demands in the country Facing a higher cost of energy-intensive input, the increase in production cost may push producers to reduce export for foreign countries It is because normally the local producers are less flexible to pass an increase in production cost to overseas buyers With the RM50 carbon tax rate, the export demand fell by 0.0129 percent in the short run The country may incur more export revenue loss if a higher carbon pricing is charged At the RM120 carbon tax rate, the export demand fell by 0.0282 percentage points more compared to the RM50 carbon tax rate Local economic agents may also reduce demand for imported goods, including intermediate inputs, as an effort to minimize the production cost following the introduction of the carbon tax The import demand fell by 0.0133 percent if the RM50 carbon tax rate was charged on energy commodities, of which producers are one major importer in the country The local economic agents may reduce even further the demand for imported goods if a higher carbon pricing is charged As expected, the import demand fell by 0.0455 percent at the RM120 carbon tax rate The import demand fell even more, by 0.0625 percentage points, if RM300 was charged per tonne of CO2 As shown in the fourth scenario, the outcome may be different when the carbon tax revenue is given back to the economy By recycling the tax revenue as a subsidy on consumer purchases, the economy appeared to recover slightly from the negative impact for a short run As shown in table, the economy performed 0.0068 percent better in real terms after the tax revenue redistribution At this point, the economy grew 0.0068 percent more relative to where the carbon tax was not imposed That is, the GDP performed better after the carbon tax redistribution compared to without it However, as time passes, the economy seems to perform 0.0089 percent lesser, even after the tax recycling An extra compensation package is necessary to achieve a simultaneous positive impact on both the economy and environment, ie the double dividend effect One way is to compensate for the loss of purchasing power among consumers especially, at least to some extent Secondly, the government could subsidize certain goods and services to offset the increase in production cost subsequent to the carbon tax burden It therefore allows goods and services always to be sold at affordable prices despite the carbon tax introduction It could indirectly avoid the rise of price level from beginning before the producers transfer it to consumers These reasons necessitate the carbon tax regime to be implemented along with supplementary fiscal measures Table 12: Macroeconomic effects of a carbon tax in Malaysia (in Percentage Change) Macroeconomic effects Gross domestic product Household consumption Volume of exports Volume of imports Aggregate employment Consumer price index Scenarios -0.0026 -0.0061 -0.0274 0.0068 -0.0173 -0.0444 -0.1221 -0.0089 0 0 0.0131 0.0271 0.0507 -0.0089 -0.0129 -0.0133 -0.0411 -0.0455 -0.1116 -0.108 -0.0026 -0.0129 -0.0686 -0.0686 -0.1596 -0.1581 -0.3705 -0.3606 -0.0292 -0.0435 -0.0071 -0.0131 -0.0373 0.0207 0 0 0.0163 0.0534 0.1434 -0.0623 0.0166 0.0382 0.0873 0.1082 4.2 Industrial Impacts 559 The section assesses the impacts on outputs and employment in energy intensive industries, as their inputs are hit directly by the carbon taxation Because of the high energy intensity, the energy intensive industries are sometimes more vulnerable to the carbon taxation policy A carbon tax generally increases the cost of production more significantly for industries whose its energy intensity is high The subsequent rise in price of energy commodities may then result in an immediate reduction in output supply especially in the energy intensive industries As expected, the 20 top energy intensive industries in the country seems to contract (Table 13), at an increasing rate with the rate of carbon taxation With the RM50 carbon pricing, petroleum refinery and transportation are among the two hardest hit industries (Table 13) At the carbon price RM120, the petroleum refinery industry cut down its output production by 0.06 percent relative to baseline ie without the carbon tax reform Other industries that experience contraction are those closely related to these two industries Among them include heavy manufacturing (cement, lime and plaster), agriculture and fishing, and service (financial institution) Some industries turn to perform better, after the tax revenue is recycled back to the economy The estimated long-run effects appear more severe than the short-run effects, possibly due to industrial structure Due to the multiplier effect of price increases, the economy seems becomes less capable to induce a more beneficial reallocation of resources over the long run Over time, the direction of reallocation still inelastic to switch away from lower cost processes with higher emission levels towards higher cost processes with relative lower emission levels Many opponents argue that the additional tax burden may result in employment losses especially in energy intensive industries Table 14 confirms this view, showing that some energy-related industries experience job losses The paper expects that blue-collar workers in the industries might be severely affected by the carbon taxation Despite employment losses in other energy intensive industries, interestingly, the petroleum refinery industry seems to increase its labor demand The similar employment gain seems to continue exist after the tax recycling Table 13: Sectoral output changes in response to carbon taxation Energy intensive industries Petroleum refinery Wholesale & retail trade and motor vehicle Electricity and gas Air transport Land transport Basic chemicals Other chemicals product Crude oil and natural gas Fishing Forestry and logging Financial institution Civil engineering Oils and fats Water transport Restaurants Scenarios 0.00 -0.06 -0.01 -0.05 -0.15 -0.12 -0.02 -0.01 -0.10 -0.09 -0.23 -0.20 -0.54 -0.48 -0.09 -0.06 0.00 -0.01 -0.17 -0.01 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 -0.61 -0.03 -0.08 -0.04 -0.04 -1.53 -0.09 -0.20 0.00 0.00 -0.24 0.00 -0.02 -0.04 -0.04 -0.18 -0.21 -0.17 -0.09 -0.09 -0.43 -0.49 -0.40 -0.22 -0.21 -1.01 -1.16 -0.94 -0.03 -0.03 -0.16 -0.13 -0.07 0.00 -0.01 -0.03 0.00 -0.06 -0.15 -0.36 -0.06 0.00 -0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.00 -0.02 -0.05 -0.01 0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.01 -0.04 -0.14 -0.02 0.07 -0.05 -0.08 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.06 -0.09 -0.02 -0.02 -0.08 0.00 0.00 -0.14 -0.21 -0.04 -0.05 -0.20 0.01 -0.01 -0.34 -0.52 -0.12 -0.12 -0.45 0.00 -0.01 -0.03 -0.04 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.01 560 Semi-conductor devices, tubes and circuit boards Cement, lime and plaster Iron and steel products Accommodation Public administration -0.01 -0.03 -0.07 0.00 -0.09 -0.20 -0.47 -0.03 0.01 0.02 0.06 0.00 -0.03 -0.07 -0.18 -0.02 -0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.03 0.00 0.00 -0.09 0.00 0.00 -0.01 0.01 0.00 -0.06 0.00 0.01 -0.15 -0.01 0.03 -0.35 -0.03 0.05 -0.03 -0.01 -0.01 Table 14: Sectoral employment changes in response to carbon tax Energy intensive industries Petroleum refinery Wholesale & retail trade and motor vehicle Electricity and gas Air transport Land transport Basic chemicals Other chemicals product Crude oil and natural gas Fishing Forestry and logging Financial institution Civil engineering Oils and fats Water transport Restaurants Semi-conductor devices, tubes and circuit boards Cement, lime and plaster Iron and steel products Accommodation Public administration Scenarios 0.17 0.56 -0.04 -0.14 1.44 -0.37 0.25 -0.02 0.09 -0.08 0.20 -0.18 0.48 -0.42 0.09 -0.05 -0.03 -0.01 0.32 -0.04 -0.06 -0.07 0.01 2.60 -0.11 -0.16 -0.20 0.02 6.86 -0.31 -0.44 0.01 0.05 1.10 0.00 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 1.89 -0.19 -0.16 -0.06 -0.07 4.51 -0.44 -0.38 -0.15 -0.17 11.14 -1.03 -0.88 -0.02 -0.03 1.91 -0.11 -0.07 -0.02 -0.12 -0.34 0.00 -0.05 -0.12 -0.27 -0.05 -0.01 -0.06 -0.01 0.02 -0.02 -0.03 0.00 -0.03 -0.02 -0.19 -0.03 0.04 -0.05 -0.08 -0.01 -0.10 -0.05 -0.51 -0.07 0.11 -0.14 -0.20 -0.04 -0.26 0.02 -0.03 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 -0.09 -0.08 -0.01 0.00 -0.08 0.01 -0.08 0.02 -0.21 -0.19 -0.03 -0.01 -0.18 0.02 -0.18 0.05 -0.48 -0.46 -0.08 -0.02 -0.40 0.05 -0.41 -0.01 -0.05 -0.04 -0.02 0.00 -0.03 -0.01 -0.02 0.04 0.09 0.23 0.04 -0.02 -0.04 -0.10 -0.02 -0.03 0.00 0.00 -0.11 0.00 0.00 -0.30 -0.01 0.00 -0.01 0.02 0.00 -0.04 0.01 0.01 -0.10 0.01 0.03 -0.24 0.02 0.06 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 4.3 Impacts on energy consumption and CO2 emissions Table 15 shows there may be a 0.01 percent lesser energy consumption in the economy, after the RM50 carbon price The 0.01 percent cut in demand for energy goods with the proposed carbon tax RM50 tends to reduce aggregate CO2 emissions level at the similar rate subsequently The projection with higher carbon pricing recognizes that the carbon tax may an effective policy instrument as it may bring more energy saving and the pollution level down further The GDP loss indicates that the country may incur an increasing economic cost in lowering down the CO2 emissions level with the increase in carbon pricing (Figure 5) This finding therefore validate the first hypothesis that the carbon taxation helps to reduce CO emissions, at some economic costs Comparing the first and fourth scenarios, practicing budget neutrality by distributing back the tax revenue to the economy appears effective to improve economic performance at least in the short run, however, weaken the capacity to raise energy saving and emission control In overall, environmental fiscal reform is therefore 561 preferable than carbon taxation standalone policy in yielding economic and environmental benefits This finding confirms the second hypothesis that the tax revenue reallocation is effective to generate double dividend effect The tax revenue seems necessary to compensate the economic loss caused by the carbon taxation policy As the economy may continue to perform lesser than expected in the long run, extra compensation scheme with a proper planning might be needed over time The sensitivity test yields the similar findings, as the main scenarios Table 15: Projections of environmental variables Environmental variables Energy saving CO2 emission cut Scenarios -0.01 -0.10 -0.01 -0.11 -0.24 -0.27 -0.04 -0.04 -0.14 -0.15 -0.33 -0.36 -0.76 -0.82 -0.13 -0.14 Figure 5: CO2 emissions reduction under different carbon price 0.00 CO2 Emission Cut (%) 50 120 300 -0.05 -0.10 -0.15 -0.20 -0.25 -0.30 Carbon Tax (RM per tonne CO2) Discussion of Findings In the face of rapid economic growth and urbanization process, the results can provide valuable insights for the appropriate design of energy or climate policies that allow for the targeted fostering of a more sustainable economic development It would be unfortunate if the successful lobbying of some politicians’ intent on maintaining sectoral economic performance and household welfare are to hinder the economic and environmental benefits from being realized That is, the fall in CO emissions, which is one of the most important objectives of environmental policies, however, should not come at a slower economic growth than its opportunity cost A sustainable economic development stresses the necessity of continuous economic growth with an efficient use of resources and better environmental quality As the policy implications, the country is advisable to introduce carbon taxation by phased-in gradually for a continuous economic welfare Compared to energy tax, carbon tax could internalize externality more directly by suggesting that polluters should be taxed accordingly to offset their underestimated input prices In overall, the simulation results show that the carbon taxation is effective to control the rise in CO2 emissions in a positive economic performance at least in the short run, after the tax revenue is recycled back to the economy as a compensation scheme The existence of double dividend effect found in the present paper confirms the past literature that EFR was still effective to reduce energy consumption and carbon emissions 562 while leaving economic performance and employment level qualitatively unchanged To cushion any negative impacts of carbon tax, a moderate carbon tax rate and carbon tax recycling policy are recommended, according to the simulation results Practically, in Malaysia, the carbon taxation could be implemented as an ex-post policy after the fuel subsidy has been abandoned completely Its tax revenue is effective to finance budget deficits in case the fuel subsidy saving is still insufficient to so Putting all these policies together in one portfolio could continuously encourage economic development and welfare protection, especially among the lower-income households This intuition has been supported empirically by the study of He et al (2015), which proposes that a rational energy policy should maintain coordination of the energy tax and fuel subsidy reform in one portfolio to achieve the double dividend effect Conventionally, comprehensive energy policies are more conducive to induce the double dividend effect with simultaneous economic and environmental benefits, as compared to a stand-alone policy On the regard, the policymaking should draw a special attention on the energy use and emission in energy intensive industries In the short run, the country may offer some exemptions to energy intensive industries, given the possibility of output contraction in response to the carbon taxation Tax recycling may increase employment and at least maintain output production Besides, a long-term policy consideration necessitates a complementarity with technology advancement The carbon tax could become more relevant in the future if its introduction is saddled with energy saving or greener technology innovations Reducing emissions requires lesser use of emission intensive energy sources, using more renewable energy, or switching to less polluting energy consumption Conclusion The primary objective of the present study is to analyze the economics and environmental impacts of carbon taxation in Malaysia The study employs computable general equilibrium modeling as method to account its impact on improving economy performance and energy security First, the study examines the impacts of carbon taxation, retaining tax revenue as government budget Isolating the tax revenue from government’s coffers gives the pure economic impacts of the carbon taxation Overall, the simulation results show that a carbon taxation can lower down CO2 emissions effectively, but it may cause mild economic contraction The commitment on achieving a continuous economic growth requires a compensation scheme The investigation examination has continued with recycling all the tax revenue as cash transfer to the economy The simulation results show that a proper compensation plan seems necessary to tackle the negative effects of the carbon tax on the economy, at least in the short run As a concluding remark, currently, the carbon tax is not yet an environmental policy, but its sizeable environmental conservation effect makes it worth a deep investigation into its validity in the Malaysian economy Acknowledgement This research did not receive any specific funding from agencies in the public, commercial or not-for-profit sectors References Abdullah, S., Morley, B., 2014 Environmental taxes and economic growth: Evidence from panel causality tests Energy Econ 42, 27–33 Abrell, J., 2012 Regulating CO2 emissions of transportation in Europe: A CGE-analysis using market-based instruments Transp Res Part D 15, 235–239 Anderson, M.S., Ekins, P 2009 Carbon Energy Taxation: Lessons from Europe New York: Oxford University Press Baranzini, A., Goldemberg, J., Speck, S., 2000 A future for carbon taxes Ecol Econ 32, 395–412 Bruvoll, A., Larsen, B.M., 2004 Greenhouse gas emissions in Norway: Do carbon taxes work? Energy Policy 32, 493–505 Cabalu, H., Koshy, P., Corong, E., Rodriguez, U.P.E., Endriga, B.A., 2015 Modelling the impact of energy policies on the Philippine economy: Carbon tax, energy efficiency, and changes in the energy mix Econ Anal Policy 48, 222–237 563 Chiu, F.P., Kuo, H.I., Chen, C.C., Hsu, C.S., 2015 The energy price equivalence of carbon taxes and emissions trading-Theory and evidence Appl Energy 160, 164–171 Conefrey, T., Fitz Gerald, J.D., Malaguzzi Valeri, L., Tol, R.S.J., 2013 The impact of a carbon tax on economic growth and carbon dioxide emissions in Ireland J Environ Plan Manag 56, 934–952 Department of Statistics Malaysia, 2018 Malaysia Informative Data Centre (MysIDC) http://mysidc.statistics.gov.my/index.php?lang=en (accessed 27 January 2018) Energy Commission Malaysia, 2017 National Energy Balance 2015 Ekins, P., Speck, S., 1999 Competitiveness and exemptions from environmental taxes in Europe Environ Resour Econ 13, 369–396 Guo, Z., Zhang, X., Zheng, Y., Rao, R., 2014 Exploring the impacts of a carbon tax on the Chinese economy using a CGE model with a detailed disaggregation of energy sectors Energy Econ 45, 455–462 Guo, Z.Q., Liu, H.B., 2016 The impact of carbon tax policy on energy consumption and CO emission in China Energy Sources, Part B Econ Planning, Policy 11, 725–731 Harnay, P.V., Rème, P., 2012 Carbon taxation in France: A failure compared with experience elsewhere in Europe? The case of road freight transport Eur Transp Res Rev 4, 201–215 He, Y.X., Liu, Y.Y., Du, M., Zhang, J.X., Pang, Y.X., 2015 Comprehensive optimisation of China’s energy prices, taxes and subsidy policies based on the dynamic computable general equilibrium model Energy Convers Manag 98, 518–532 Internatiuonal Energy Agency, 2018 CO2 Emissions from Fuel Combustion Highlights (2017 Edition) Liang, Q., Wei, Y., 2012 Distributional impacts of taxing carbon in China: Results from the CEEPA model Appl Energy 92, 545–551 Liang, Q.M., Wang, T., Xue, M.M., 2016 Addressing the competitiveness effects of taxing carbon in China: Domestic tax cuts versus border tax adjustments J Clean Prod 112, 1568–1581 Lin, B., Ouyang, X., 2014 A revisit of fossil-fuel subsidies in China: Challenges and opportunities for energy price reform Energy Convers Manag 82, 124–134 Markandya, A., González-Eguino, M., Escapa, M., 2013 From shadow to green: Linking environmental fiscal reforms and the informal economy Energy Econ 40, S108–S118 Matsumoto, K., 2008 Introduction of the carbon tax based on the imputed price of carbon for the Post Kyoto Protocol scenario Int J Green Energy 5, 241–254 McDougall, R.A., 1993 Short-run effects of a carbon tax Gen Pap No G-100, Cent Policy Stud Meng, X., 2012 Will Australian carbon tax affect the resources boom? Results from a CGE model Nat Resour Res 21, 495–507 Murray, B., Rivers, N., 2015 British Columbia’s revenue-neutral carbon tax: A review of the latest “grand experiment” in environmental policy Energy Policy 86, 674–683 Nordhaus, W.D., 2007 To Tax or Not to Tax: Alternative Approaches to Slowing Global Warming Rev Environ Econ Policy 1, 26–44 Nurdianto, D., Resosudarmo, B., 2016 Economy-wide Impact of a Carbon Tax in ASEAN J Southeast Asian Econ 33, 1–22 Orlov, A., Grethe, H., Mcdonald, S., 2013 Carbon taxation in Russia: Prospects for a double dividend and improved energy efficiency Energy Econ 37, 128–140 Ren, S., Yin, H., Chen, X., 2014 Using LMDI to analyze the decoupling of carbon dioxide emissions by China’ s manufacturing industry Environ Dev 9, 61–75 Siriwardana, M., Meng, S., Mcneill, J., 2011 The impact of a carbon tax on the Australian economy: Results from a CGE model Business, Econ Public Policy Work Pap Number 2011-2, Univ New England’s Sch Bus Econ Public Policy, Armidale, Aust Solaymani, S., 2017 Carbon and energy taxes in a small and open country Glob J Environ Sci Manag 3, 51–62 Solaymani, S., Kardooni, R., Sumiani Yusoff, Fatimah Kari, 2015 The impacts of climate change policies on the transportation sector Energy 81, 719–728 Speck, S., 2013 Carbon taxation: Two decades of experience and future prospects Carbon Manag 4, 171–183 Sun, R., Kuang, D., 2015 CGE model-based analysis of the neutralized hybrid carbon policy and its decomposed effects on economic growth, carbon reduction, and energy utilization costs Chinese J Popul Resour Environ 13, 43-54 Temurshoev, U., 2006 Pollution Haven Hypothesis or Factor Endowment Hypothesis: Theory and Empirical Examination for the US and China Work Pap Ser 292 Cent Econ Res Grad Educ Acad Sci Crezh Repub Econ Inst Vandyck, T., Van Regemorter, D., 2014 Distributional and regional economic impact of energy taxes in Belgium Energy Policy 72, 190– 203 Wang, Q., Chen, X., 2015 Energy policies for managing China’s carbon emission Renew Sustain Energy Rev 50, 470–479 Wang, Q., Liang, Q.M., 2014 Will a carbon tax hinder China’s efforts to improve its primary income distribution status? Mitig Adapt Strateg Glob Chang 20, 1407–1436 Welsch, H., Ehrenheim, V., 2004 Environmental fiscal reform in Germany: A computable general equilibrium analysis Environ Econ Policy Stud 6, 197–219 Wissema, W., Dellink, R., 2007 AGE analysis of the impact of a carbon energy tax on the Irish economy Ecol Econ 61, 671 – 683 Wolfson, D.J., Koopmans, C.C., 1996 Regulatory taxation of fossil fuels: Theory and policy Ecol Econ 19, 55–65 Yusuf, A.A., 2008 INDONESIA-E3 : An Indonesian Applied General Equilibrium Model for Analyzing the Economy, Equity, and the Environment Work Pap Econ Dev Stud No 200804, Cent Econ Dev Stud Dep Econ Padjadjaran Univ Zhang, X., Guo, Z., Zheng, Y., Zhu, J., Yang, J., 2016 A CGE analysis of the impacts of a carbon tax on provincial economy in China Emerg Mark Financ Trade 52, 1372–1384 564 ... subsidy RM50 of carbon tax RM120 of carbon tax RM300 of carbon tax RM50 of carbon tax and tax revenue is handed back as a consumption subsidy Results and Analysis 4.1 Macroeconomics Impacts Since the... coordination as always dominant over the standalone carbon taxation in the real economy Markandya et al (2013) revealed a similar result was obtained for the case of Spain where the revenue-recycling... have shown an increasing concern in making use of carbon taxation for emission mitigation in recent years In general, the literature agrees that carbon tax is one policy effective for handling

Ngày đăng: 18/09/2020, 08:51

w