Ebook Managerial economics (7th edition): Part 2

452 49 0
Ebook Managerial economics (7th edition): Part 2

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

(BQ) Part 2 book Managerial economics has contents: Oligopoly, game theory and competitive strategy; regulation, public goods, and benefit cost analysis; decision making under uncertainty; the value of information; asymmetric information and organizational design; bargaining and negotiation,...and other contents.

C H A P T E R Oligopoly It is in rare moments that I see my business clearly: my customers, my organization, my markets and my costs Then why I still lie awake at night? I’m trying to figure the damn strategies of my competitors! A MANAGER’S LAMENT In the early 1990s, the infant-formula industry accounted for annual sales of some $2 billion Abbott Laboratories, Bristol-Myers Squibb, and American Home Products Corp dominated the market with 50 percent, 37 percent, and percent market shares, respectively The growth of the overall market had been uneven Until the early 1970s, breast feeding of babies was on the decline, sinking to a low of 20 percent of mothers Formula makers prospered by offering mothers the convenience of bottled milk Twenty-five years of research, however, convinced pediatricians that mother’s milk is the optimum baby food In the 1990s, about 50 percent of American mothers breast fed their babies The three dominant companies employed strikingly similar business practices The formulas they sold were nearly identical (and must have the same nutrients by federal law) The companies charged virtually the same wholesale prices They increased prices by an average of percent annually over the decade (while milk prices increased by percent annually) They produced a 13-ounce can at a marginal cost of about $.60 and sold it for an average wholesale price of $2.10 With average total cost estimated to be about $1.70 per can, the companies enjoyed nearly a 25 percent profit margin The companies engaged in almost no advertising; instead, they promoted and marketed their formulas via give-away programs to Collusion in the Infant Formula Industry 349 350 Chapter Oligopoly hospitals and doctors Such programs were very effective Research has shown that 90 percent of mothers stick to the formula brand the hospital gives them The cozy oligopoly enjoyed by the three companies attracted would-be entrants and government scrutiny In the late 1980s, Carnation and Gerber entered the formula market by advertising directly to consumers However, the American Academy of Pediatrics opposed this strategy, arguing that direct advertising would influence mothers not to breast feed Consequently, the two companies’ sales constituted less than percent of the market In addition, the federal government took an interest in formula pricing Under its Women, Infants, and Children (WIC) Program, the government subsidized formula for disadvantaged families Administered by the states, the WIC program accounted for about one-third of all formula sales In most states, families received WIC vouchers that could be exchanged for any brand of formula, with the companies giving the government a discount (about $.50 per can) off the regular wholesale price However, a number of states instituted competitive bidding—awarding all WIC sales in the state to the firm making the lowest price bid The history of the baby-formula industry raises a number of questions Does viable competition exist in the industry? Are barriers to entry significant? Are prices excessive? What effect might competitive bidding have on market structure, pricing, and profitability in the infant-formula industry? In the previous two chapters, we focused on perfect competition and pure monopoly, the polar cases of market structure However, many markets occupy positions between these extremes; that is, they are dominated by neither a single firm nor a plethora of firms Oligopoly is the general category describing markets or industries that consist of a small number of firms Because of oligopoly’s importance and because no single model captures the many implications of firm behavior within oligopoly, we devote the entire chapter to this topic A firm within an oligopoly faces the following basic question: How can it determine a profit-maximizing course of action when it competes against an identifiable number of competitors similar to itself? This chapter and the succeeding chapter on game theory answer this question by introducing and analyzing competitive strategies Thus, we depart from the approach taken previously where the main focus was on a “single” firm facing rivals whose actions are predictable and unchanging In crafting a competitive strategy, a firm’s management must anticipate a range of competitor actions and be prepared to respond accordingly Competitive strategy finds its most important applications within oligopoly settings By contrast, in a pure monopoly, there are no immediate competitors to worry about In pure competition, an individual firm’s competitive options are strictly limited Industry price and output are set by supply and demand, and the firm is destined to earn a zero profit in the long run Oligopoly The strategic approach extends the single-firm point of view by recognizing that a firm’s profit depends not only on the firm’s own actions but also on the actions of competitors Thus, to determine its own optimal action, the firm must correctly anticipate the actions and reactions of its rivals Roughly speaking, a manager must look at the competitive situation not only from his or her own point of view but also from rivals’ perspectives The manager should put himself or herself in the competitor’s place to analyze what that person’s optimal decision might be This approach is central to game theory and is often called interactive or strategic thinking The outline of this chapter is as follows In the first section, we describe how to analyze different types of oligopolies, beginning with Michael Porter’s Five-Forces model Next, we introduce the concept of market concentration, as well as the link between concentration and industry prices In the following section, we consider two kinds of quantity competition: when a market leader faces a number of smaller competitors and when competition is between equally positioned rivals In the third section, we examine price competition, ranging from a model of stable prices based on kinked demand to a description of price wars Finally, in the fourth section, we explore two other important dimensions of competition within oligopolies: the effects of advertising and of strategic precommitments OLIGOPOLY An oligopoly is a market dominated by a small number of firms, whose actions directly affect one another’s profits In this sense, the fates of oligopoly firms are interdependent To begin, it is useful to size up an oligopolistic industry along a number of important economic dimensions Five-Forces Framework For 25 years, Michael Porter’s Five-Forces model has provided a powerful synthesis for describing the structures of different industries and guiding competitive strategy.1 Figure 9.1 provides a summary of the Five-Forces framework The core of Porter’s analysis centers on internal industry rivalry: the set of major firms competing in the market and how they compete Naturally, the number of close rivals, their relative size, position, and power, are crucial (The following section looks closely at the notion of industry concentration to measure the number and sizes of firms.) Entry into the market is the second most important factor in sizing up the industry We have already seen that free The Five-Forces model is examined at length in M E Porter, Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1998) 351 352 Chapter Oligopoly FIGURE 9.1 The Five-Forces Framework Entry Supplier Power Internal Rivalry Buyer Power Substitutes and Complements entry predisposes a perfectly competitive market to zero economic profits in the long run Conversely, significant barriers to entry (as listed and described in Chapter 8) are a precondition for monopoly Ease of entry is also crucial for analyzing oligopoly Boeing and Airbus compete vigorously to sell new aircraft, but barriers to entry due to economies of scale protect them from new competitors By contrast, numerous new discount airlines in the United States and Europe have dramatically changed the competitive landscape in the air travel market Similarly, a small independent studio (putting together a good script, directing talent, and up-and-coming actors) can produce a well-reviewed and profitable hit movie despite the formidable clout of the major studios The impacts of substitutes and complements directly affect industry demand, profitability, and competitive strategy In a host of industries, this impact is ongoing, even relentless For instance, trucking and railways are substitutes, competing modes of transport in the long-haul market Soft-drink consumption suffers at the hands of bottled water, sports drinks, and new-age beverages In other cases, the emerging threat of new substitutes is crucial Cable companies have long challenged network television (with satellite TV a third option) and now vigorously compete for local telephone customers Since the millennium, online commerce has steadily increased its sales, often at the expense of “brick-and-mortar” stores The fast growth of hybrid automobiles poses a long-term threat to traditional gasoline-powered vehicles More recently, new attention and analysis has been paid to the industry impact of complementary goods and activities Computer hardware and software are crucial complements Steady growth in one market requires (and is fueled by) steady growth in the other Although Barnes & Noble superstores compete with online seller Amazon, its sales are enhanced by its own online arm, barnesandnoble.com Coined by Adam Brandenberger and Barry Nalebuff, the term coopetition denotes cooperative behavior among industry “competitors.” Thus, firms in the same industry often work together to set Oligopoly common technology standards (for high-definition television or DVDs, for instance) so as to promote overall market growth Firms in the same market also might join in shared research and development programs Coopetition also occurs when a company and its input supplier cooperate to streamline the supply chain, improve product quality, or lower product cost In short, oligopoly analysis embraces both the threat of substitutes and the positive impacts of complementary activities Finally, the potential bargaining power of buyers and suppliers should not be overlooked For instance, the pricing behavior of a final goods manufacturer depends on the nature of the customers to whom it sells At one extreme, its customers—say, a mass market of household consumers—may have little or no bargaining power The manufacturer has full discretion to set its price as it wants (always taking into account, of course, overall product demand and the degree of competition from rival firms) At the other extreme, a large multinational corporate buyer will have considerable bargaining clout Typically, such a buyer will have the power to negotiate the final terms of any contract (including price), and indeed it might hold the balance of power in the negotiation (The producer might need the large buyer much more than the buyer needs the producer.) In the extreme, the buyer might organize a procurement and ask for competitive bids from would-be goods producers In this way, the buyer uses its power to maximize competition among the producers so as to secure the best contract terms and price (Negotiation and competitive bidding are the subjects of Chapters 15 and 16, respectively.) Of course, the same analysis applies to the firm’s relationships with its suppliers We know from Chapter that the firm will receive the best possible input prices if its suppliers compete in a perfectly competitive market On the other hand, if the number of suppliers is limited or if actual inputs are in short supply, bargaining power shifts to the suppliers who are able to command higher prices Industry Concentration As noted earlier, an oligopoly is dominated by a small number of firms This “small number” is not precisely defined, but it may be as small as two (a duopoly) or as many as eight to ten One way to grasp the numbers issue is to appeal to the most widely used measure of market structure: the concentration ratio The four-firm concentration ratio is the percentage of sales accounted for by the top four firms in a market or industry (Eight-firm and twenty-firm ratios are defined analogously.) Concentration ratios can be computed from publicly available market-share information Ratios also are compiled in the U.S Census Bureau, released by the government at five-year intervals Table 9.1 lists concentration ratios for selected goods and services compiled from both sources Notice the progression from highly concentrated to less concentrated industries 353 354 Chapter Oligopoly TABLE 9.1 Concentration Ratios for Selected Goods & Services Concentration Ratio Product or Service Laundry machines Warehouse clubs Refrigerators Web Search Aluminum refining Beer Tobacco Glass containers Rental cars Personal computers Carbon black Cellular phone service Aircraft Breakfast foods Office supply stores Ammunition Tires Running shoes Metal cans Aircraft engines Burial caskets Bottled water Vacuum cleaners Bookstores Lawn equipment Flat glass Stockings Motor vehicles Domestic air flights Motion pictures Drug stores Cable television Photocopying machines Farm machinery Men’s shoes Elevators Snack foods Nuclear power Investment banking Oil refining Soap Firms 98 94 92 91 90 90 90 87 87 87 84 82 81 80 80 79 78 77 77 74 74 72 71 71 71 70 69 68 65 64 63 62 61 59 57 56 53 53 52 48 47 Firms 100 100 98 95 99 92 95 95 96 92 99 94 94 92 81 89 93 96 95 81 83 85 96 78 84 98 85 86 83 96 66 79 83 65 82 70 61 76 77 73 60 20 Firms Oligopoly TABLE 9.1 (continued ) Concentration Ratio Product or Service Paper mills Coffee Television broadcasting Rubber Ski facilities Software Toys Boat building Internet service Book publishing Basic chemicals Supermarkets Internet shopping Pharmaceuticals Newspapers Women’s dresses Life insurance Office furniture Advertising agencies Concrete Hotels Motor vehicle parts Elder care homes Funeral homes Electric power Furniture stores Management consulting Used car dealers Furniture Trucking Bolts, nuts, screws Restaurants Liquor Stores Musical groups and artists Veterinary services Legal offices Florists Auto repair Dry cleaners Firms 46 43 43 43 42 39 36 35 34 33 33 32 31 30 29 28 27 26 24 23 23 19 19 16 15 14 14 13 11 9 7 2.6 2.1 1.7 1.4 Source: U.S Bureau of the Census, 2007, and industry reports Firms 67 58 56 65 53 47 51 43 49 48 44 46 37 47 45 39 44 34 29 28 28 28 23 17 27 19 19 14 19 15 12 12 13 11 4.6 2.9 2.6 2.2 20 Firms 68 60 59 85 69 63 69 75 42 33 40 35 42 30 18 54 27 26 16 30 21 19 17 19 20 9.0 4.5 4.3 3.9 355 356 Chapter Oligopoly Market concentration has a ready interpretation The higher the concentration ratio, the greater is the degree of market dominance by a small number of firms Indeed, a common practice is to distinguish among different market structures by degree of concentration For example, an effective monopoly is said to exist when the single-firm concentration ratio is above 90 percent, CR1 Ͼ 90 A market may be viewed as effectively competitive when CR4 is below 40 percent If CR4 Ͻ 40 percent, the top firms have individual market shares averaging less than 10 percent, and they are joined by many firms with still smaller market shares Finally, one often speaks of a loose oligopoly when 40 percent Ͻ CR4 Ͻ 60 percent and a tight oligopoly when CR4 Ͼ 60 percent Monopolistic competition, discussed in the previous chapter, typically falls in the loose-oligopoly range About three-quarters of the total dollar value of goods and services (gross domestic product or GDP) produced by the U.S economy originate in competitive markets, that is, markets for which CR4 Ͻ 40 Competitive markets included the lion’s share (85 percent or more) of agriculture, forestry, fisheries, mining, and wholesale and retail trade Competition is less prevalent in manufacturing, general services, and construction (making up between 60 and 80 percent of these sectors) In contrast, pure monopoly accounts for a small portion of GDP (between and percent) Tight oligopolies account for about 10 percent of GDP, whereas loose oligopolies comprise about 12 percent.2 In short, as Table 9.1 shows, while concentrated markets are relatively rare in the U.S economy, specific industries and manufactured products are highly concentrated Because the notion of concentration ratio is used so widely, it is important to understand its limitations The most serious limitation lies in the identification of the relevant market A market is a collection of buyers and sellers exchanging goods or services that are very close substitutes for one another (Recall that the cross-elasticity of demand is a direct measure of substitution The larger the impact on a good’s sales from changes in a competitor’s price, the stronger the market competition.) Concentration ratios purport to summarize the size distribution of firms for relevant markets However, it should be evident that market definitions vary, depending on how broadly or narrowly one draws product and geographic boundaries First, in many cases the market definitions used in government statistics are too broad An industry grouping such as pharmaceutical products embraces many distinct, individual product markets Numerous firms make up the overall consumer-drug market (concentration is low), but individual markets (drugs for ulcers and blood pressure) are highly concentrated Similarly, government statistics encompass national markets and therefore cannot capture local monopolies As one might expect, categorization of market structures by concentration is not hard and fast The preceding data are based on W G Shepherd, The Economics of Industrial Organization, Chapter (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 2003) Oligopoly Newspapers are a dramatic case in point Based on CR4, the newspaper industry would seem to be effectively competitive for the United States as a whole But for most major cities, one or two firms account for nearly 100 percent of circulation.3 Second, the census data exclude imports—a serious omission considering that the importance of imports in the U.S economy has risen steadily (to some 13 percent of GDP today) In many industries (automobiles, televisions, electronics), the degree of concentration for U.S sales (including imports) is much less than the concentration for U.S production Thus, many industries are far more competitive than domestic concentration ratios would indicate Finally, using a concentration ratio is not the only way to measure market dominance by a small number of firms An alternative and widely used measure is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), defined as the sum of the squared market shares of all firms: HHI ϭ s12 ϩ s22 ϩ ϩ sn2 where s1 denotes the market share of firm and n denotes the number of firms For instance, if a market is supplied by five firms with market shares of 40, 30, 16, 10, and percent, respectively, HHI ϭ 402 ϩ 302 ϩ 162 ϩ 102 ϩ 42 ϭ 2,872 The HHI index ranges between 10,000 for a pure monopolist (with 100 percent of the market) to zero for an infinite number of small firms If a market is shared equally by n firms, HHI is the n-fold sum of (100/n)2, or (n)(100/n)2 ϭ 10,000/n If the market has identical firms, HHI ϭ 2,000; if it has 10 identical firms, HHI ϭ 1,000 The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index has a number of noteworthy properties: The index counts the market shares of all firms, not merely the top four or eight The more unequal the market shares of a collection of firms, the greater is the index because shares are squared Other things being equal, the more numerous the firms, the lower is the index Because of these properties, the HHI has advantages over concentration ratios; indeed, the HHI is used as one factor in the Department of Justice’s Merger Guidelines (Under antitrust laws, the government can block a proposed merger if it will substantially reduce competition or tend to create a monopoly.) Concentration ratios and the HHI are highly correlated Because they are available more readily (and easier to compute), concentration ratios are quoted more widely The Bureau of the Census presents concentration ratios starting for broad industry categories and progressing to narrower and narrower groups (so-called six-digit categories) The categories in Table 9.1 are at the five- and six-digit levels As we would expect, concentration tends to increase as markets are defined more narrowly Many researchers believe that five-digit categories best approximate actual market boundaries 357 358 Chapter Oligopoly Concentration and Prices Concentration is an important factor affecting pricing and profitability within markets Other things being equal, increases in concentration can be expected to be associated with increased prices and profits One way to make this point is to appeal to the extreme cases of pure competition and pure monopoly Under pure competition, market price equals average cost, leaving all firms zero economic profits (i.e., normal rates of return) Low concentration leads to minimum prices and zero profits Under a pure monopoly, in contrast, a single dominant firm earns maximum excess profit by optimally raising the market price Given these polar results, it is natural to hypothesize a positive relationship between an industry’s degree of monopoly (as measured by concentration) and industry prices For instance, the smaller the number of firms that dominate a market (the tighter the oligopoly), the greater is the likelihood that firms will avoid cutthroat competition and succeed in maintaining high prices High prices may be a result of tacit collusion among a small number of equally matched firms But even without any form of collusion, fewer competitors can lead to higher prices The models of price leadership and quantity competition (analyzed in the next section) make exactly this point There is considerable evidence that increases in concentration promote higher prices The customary approach in this research is to focus on particular markets and collect data on price (the dependent variable) and costs, demand conditions, and concentration (the explanatory variables) Price is viewed in the functional form P ϭ f(C, D, SC), where C denotes a measure of cost, D a measure of demand, and SC seller concentration Based on these data, regression techniques are used to estimate this price relationship in the form of an equation Of particular interest is the separate influence of concentration on price, other things (costs and demand) being equal The positive association between concentration and price has been confirmed for a wide variety of products, services, and markets—from retail grocery chains to air travel on intercity routes; from cement production to television advertising; from auctions of oil leases and timber rights to interest rates offered by commercial banks More generally, a large-scale study of manufacturing (using five-digit product categories) for the 1960s and 1970s shows that concentration has an important effect on ... 44 46 37 47 45 39 44 34 29 28 28 28 23 17 27 19 19 14 19 15 12 12 13 11 4.6 2. 9 2. 6 2. 2 20 Firms 68 60 59 85 69 63 69 75 42 33 40 35 42 30 18 54 27 26 16 30 21 19 17 19 20 9.0 4.5 4.3 3.9 355... Dry cleaners Firms 46 43 43 43 42 39 36 35 34 33 33 32 31 30 29 28 27 26 24 23 23 19 19 16 15 14 14 13 11 9 7 2. 6 2. 1 1.7 1.4 Source: U.S Bureau of the Census, 20 07, and industry reports Firms... Firms 98 94 92 91 90 90 90 87 87 87 84 82 81 80 80 79 78 77 77 74 74 72 71 71 71 70 69 68 65 64 63 62 61 59 57 56 53 53 52 48 47 Firms 100 100 98 95 99 92 95 95 96 92 99 94 94 92 81 89 93 96

Ngày đăng: 04/02/2020, 19:32

Từ khóa liên quan

Mục lục

  • Copyright

  • Preface

  • About the Authors

  • Brief Contents

  • Contents

  • CHAPTER 1: Introduction to Economic Decision Making

    • SEVEN EXAMPLES OF MANAGERIAL DECISIONS

    • SIX STEPS TO DECISION MAKING

      • Step 1: Define the Problem

      • Step 2: Determine the Objective

      • Step 3: Explore the Alternatives

      • Step 4: Predict the Consequences

      • Step 5: Make a Choice

      • Step 6: Perform Sensitivity Analysis

      • PRIVATE AND PUBLIC DECISIONS: AN ECONOMIC VIEW

        • Public Decisions

        • THINGS TO COME

          • The Aim of This Book

          • SECTION I: Decisions within Firms

            • CHAPTER 2: Optimal Decisions Using Marginal Analysis

              • SITING A SHOPPING MALL

              • A SIMPLE MODEL OF THE FIRM

                • A Microchip Manufacturer

                • MARGINAL ANALYSIS

                  • Marginal Analysis and Calculus

                  • MARGINAL REVENUE AND MARGINAL COST

                    • Marginal Revenue

                    • Marginal Cost

                    • Profit Maximization Revisited

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan