1. Trang chủ
  2. » Thể loại khác

Chapter 12_Simultaneous Equations Models

18 74 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 18
Dung lượng 214,49 KB

Nội dung

Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models Chapter 12 SIMULTANEOUS EQUATIONS MODELS I MODEL: Many economic problems involve the interaction of multiple endogenous variables within a system of equations Estimating the parameters of such as system is typically not as simple as doing OLS equation-by-equation Issues such as identification (wether the parameters are even estimable) and endogeneity bias are then primary topic in this chapter Example: Demand and supply for peanuts at t α pt + ε1t  q= d ,t   qs ,t = β pt + γ Rt + ε t qt = quantity, pt = price, Rt = input price Equilibrium: qd,t = qs,t = qt ⇔ α pt + ε1t = β pt + γ Rt + ε t ⇔ (α − β ) pt = γ Rt + ε t − ε1t ⇔ = pt γ (α − β ) Rt + ε t − ε1t (α − β ) The model is the joint determination of price and quantity qt and pt are endogenous variables, Rt is assume determined outside the model, it is exogenous variable All three equations are needed to determine the equilibrium price and quantity Note: The completeness of the system requires that the number of the equations equals the number of endogenous variables General model: The simultaneous system can be written as: Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models Y Γ + X t Β + εt = t (1× M ) ( M × M ) (1× K ) ( K × M ) (1× M ) Where: Yt = [Y1 Y2  YM ]t X t = [ X1 X  X M ]t ε t = [ε1 ε  ε M ]t  γ 11 γ 12 γ γ 22  21 Γ = ( M ×M )     γ M γ M  γ 1M   γ 2M        γ MM   β11 β  21 Β = ( M ×M )    βM1  β1M   β2M        β KM  β12 β 22  βM  qt = α1 + β11 pt + β12 I t + β13 pt* + ε1t  α + β 21 pt + ε t  qt = It: Income; pt* : price of an alternative; qt, pt: Endogenous (determined within the model) It, Rt, pt* : Exogenous (determined outside the model) Matrix form:  +α1 +α  −1   −1 *  + 1 I t pt  + β12  + [ε1t ε t ] = qt pt ]  [ [0 0]       + β11 + β 21    εt Yt    + β13 Xt   Γ   Β Reduced form: Each endogenous variable is expressed in terms of all exogenous variables: Yt= X t Π + Vt Where: Π =− Β Γ −1 ( K ×M ) ( K ×M ) Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics = Vt (1× M ) Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models ε t Γ −1 (1× M ) ( M × M ) If the system is completeness squared matrix is non-singular and π 11 π 12  = qt pt ] +1 I t p  π 21 π 22  [      Yt Xt π 31 π 32  * t [V1t exists V2 t ] • Reduced form can always be estimated, so reduced form equations are identified • If are given we can find structural parameters: π 11 π 12   +α1 +α  −1   −1    ΠΓ = −Β ⇔ π 21 π 22  = − + β12    + β11 + β 21       π 31 π 32    + β13 Γ    Β For equation (1): demand −α1  −π 11 + π 12 β11 =  − β12  −π 21 + π 22 β11 =  −π + π β = − β13 32 11  31 This is “Indirect least squares” estimation (ILS) Over-identification ILS cannot be applied? ⇒ equations, unknown: β11 , α1 , β12 , β13 So parameters of 1st structure equation (demand) are not identified This equation cannot be estimated For equation (2): supply −α  −π 11 + π 12 β 21 =   −π 21 + π 22 β 21 =  −π + π β = 32 21  31 ⇒ β 21 = π 21 / π 22 α π 11 − π 12 (π 21 / π 22 ) = II RANK AND ORDER CONDITIONS FOR IDENTIFICATION: Classification of variables: + Current endogenous (unlagged) = jointly dependent + Predetermined: a Exogenous (unlagged & lagged) Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models b Lagged endogenous Ex: variables qt −1 or pt −1 on RHS equation Notation: for a given equation M* = number of endogenous variables in this equation M** = number of endogenous variables in system (excluded) K* = number of included predetermined variables in this equation KK* = number of excluded M=M + M ;K=K + K Order conditions: Yt Γ + X t Β + ε t = Yt = − X t ΒΓ −1 − ε t Γ −1 = Y + X t Π + Vt t (1× M ) (1× K ) ( K × M ) (1× M ) Π =− Β Γ −1 ( k ×M ) ( K ×M ) can be known by OLS because reduced form always identified Question: Can β ij 's and γ ij 's ( and ) be fund in terms of Π ij 's ( ) We have: Π = −ΒΓ −1 ⇒ ΠΓ = −Β ⇒ ΠΓ + Β = ⇒    ( KΠ×M ) ( KI×KM )    K ×( M + K ) Γ  Β = ( K ×M )  A ( M +K )M Consider the first equation: Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics ⇒ Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models  γ  Π IK ]    = [    β1  ( K ×1) K ×( M + K )  A ( M + K )1 We have K equations, K+M unknown variables It is impossible to be identification without additional information ∗ Theorem: A necessary condition for a given equation to be identified is that the number of predetermined variables excluded (K**) from this equation be greater than or equal to the number of jointly dependent variables included in this equation mins K ** ≥ M * − K ** + M ** ≥ M * + M ** − K ** + M ** ≥ M − Excluded variables # Dependent variables in system -1 Ex Demand: K ** = M *= 2 − 1= ⇒ not identified pt ,qt Supply: K ** = 2 M *= I t , Pt* 2 − 1= ⇒ order condition is satisfied, not identified yet pt ,qt If over identified: K ** > M * − If exactly identified: ** K= M * −1 Rank conditions:  γ  Π IK ]    = [    β1  ( K ×1) K ×( M + K )  ( M + K )×1  a K equations, (M + K) unknown parameters  Added information in the form of general linear restrictions on a : R1a1 =  ( r1 ×1) r1 ×( M + K ) R1  a1 [ r1 ×( M + K )] [( M + K )×1] r1: number of restrictions on exogenous & endogenous variables Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models 0 0 0 1 1  = R1   3rd coefficient = 0, sum of coefficients on variables → = M K  Π R I K      K r1  γ   = β1  ( r1 + K )×1  ( r1 + K )×( M + K ) ( M + K )×1  a ∗ Theorem:  A necessary and sufficient condition for a solution a to this system of homogenous  Π  IK  equations is that the rank of K     be equals to (M + K – 1) this solution is nontrivial  R1  and unique up to a factor of proportionality ∗ An equivalent condition is that the rank of: (R1A) = M -  Π IK  Rank  Because Rank ( R1 A) + K =   R1  • Rank condition: necessary and sufficient condition for identification: Rank ( R1 A= ) M −1 • Order condition: necessary: r1 ≥ M − Number of rows of R1 is a number of endogenous variables and exogenous variables outside the equation (1) K** + M** Y1t= γ 11Y2 t + γ 12Y3t + β11 + β12 X t order condition now: r1 ≥ M − : ε1t Y2 t = + γ 22Y3t + β 21 + β 22 X t + β 23 X 3t + ε t = Y3t γ 31Y2 t + β 31 + β 32 X t + β 33 X 3t + ε 3t + ( β 32 = β 33 ) Yjt: endogenous variables, Xjt: Exogenous (predetermined) Matrix form: Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics [Y1t + [ε1t • Y2 t Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models 0  −1  Y3t ] γ 11 −1 γ 31  + [1 X 1t   γ 12 γ 21 −1 X 2t ε t ε 3t ] = [0 0]  β11 β X 3t ]  12    β 21 β 31  β 22 β 23   β 32  β 33   For equation (1): write restrictions as: R1a1 = Γ   Where a1 is the first column of   = A Then:  Β 0  0 =  [ 2×( K + M )]   0  R1 r1 = ≥ M − = − = ⇒ Order condition: yes Rank condition: yes 0 β 22 ( R1 A) =  0 β 23 β 32  β 33  Rank ( R1 A)= 2= M − → eq(1) is identified •  For equation (2): write restrictions as: R2a2 = 1 0 0 0 R2 =   0 0 0 r2 = ≥ M − = − = ⇒ Order condition: yes Rank condition: yes  −1 0  ( R2 A) =    β12 0 Rank ( R2 A) =1 ≠ M − → eq(2) is not identified •  For equation (3): ( β 32 = β 33 ) R3a3 = Then: 1 0 0 0  R3 = 0 0 0    0 0 0 −1 Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models r3 = ≥ M − = ⇒ Order condition: yes Rank condition: yes 0  −1    ( R3 A) = 0 β12   (0 − 0) ( β 22 − β 23 ) ( β 32 − β 33 )  Rank ( R3 A)= 2= M − → eq(3) is identified Example 2: I t =α + α1 (Yt − Yt −1 ) + α 2it + ε1t Ct =β + β1Yt + ε t Yt = Ct + I t + ε 3t Matrix form: [ It • Ct  −1  α Yt ]  −1  + [1 it Yt −1 ] α    α1 β1 −1 α β 0 0 0 + [ε1t  0 ε t ε 3t ] = [0 0] For equation (1): r1 = = M − = − = ⇒ Order condition: yes 0 0 0 R1 =   0 0 1 −1   = = ( R1 A)  Rank condition: yes  (α1 + α ) ( β1 + 0) ( −1 + 0)   −1  0 β −1   Rank ( R1 A)= 2= M − → eq(1) is identified •  For equation (2): write restrictions as: R2a2 = r2 =3 ≥ M − ⇒ Order condition: yes  −1  Rank condition: ( R2 A) = α 0 A   α 0 Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models Rank ( R1 A)= 2= M − → eq(1) is identified • For equation (3): r3 = ≥ M − = ⇒ Order condition: yes Rank ( R3 A)= 2= M − → eq(3) is identified III ESTIMATION OF A SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION SYSTEM: Under-identified: Order or rank condition fails Identified: • Exactly identified: r = M – and rank condition is met • Over-identified: r > M – and rank condition is met Problem: How we estimate , consistently? a) If a system is under-identified (there are some equations which are under-identified) there is no way to estimate it consistently b) If a system is exact-identified: One possible way is to use indirect least squares estimation to solve   Π IK  γ   R   =  β  c) If a system is over-identified: ILS does not work because there will be more than one possible estimator and no obvious means of choosing among them OLS → inconsistent estimators because of edogeneity, also call: “Simultaneous equation bias” of least squares We will discuss various methods of consistent and efficient estimation (“All of methods in general use can be placed under the umbrella of instrument variable (I.V) estimator” Greene) Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics ∗ Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models Note: generalised I.V estimator of : −1 βˆIV =  X / M Z X   X / M Z Y  where M Z = Z ( Z / Z ) −1 Z / Z are instrumental variable for X with L > k ( n× L ) ( n× k ) If L = k → Z/X is a squared matrix and: −1 βˆIV  X / M Z X   X / M Z Y  = = (Z X ) / −1 Z /Y where M Z = Z ( Z / Z ) −1 Z / (simple IV) −1 And βˆIV =  X / M Z X   X / M Z Y  is also the 2SLS (two-stage least square) estimator: • First stage: get Xˆ = Z Π with Π =( Z / Z ) −1 ZX → Xˆ = Z ( Z / Z ) −1 ZX • Second stage: −1 −1 βˆ2 SLS =  Xˆ / Xˆ   Xˆ /Y  =  X / M Z X   X / M Z Y  = βˆIV when use Xˆ as an IV We can prove that βˆIV generalized is a consistent estimator of −1 βˆIV =  X / M Z X   X / M Z Y  −1  /  /  −1  /    /  /  −1  /  ˆ β IV= β +  X Z  Z Z   Z X    X Z  Z Z   Z ε   n  n    n  n  n   n ( ) −1 −1 −1 So p lim βˆIV = + β β QXZ QZZ QZX  QXZ QZZ = General IV estimator is also 2SLS estimator ∗ Requirement: number of instrumental variables has to be larger than number of endogenous variables in the regression ( ) for 2SLS can be applied General structural model: (1) Yt Γ + Xt Β += εt (1× M ) ( M × M ) (1’) Y (1× K ) ( K × M ) Γ + X (T × M ) ( M × M ) (1× M ) 0= t 1, 2 , T (1× M ) Β + E =0 (T × K ) ( K × M ) (T × M ) (T × M ) (2) E ( ε t ) = (1× M ) (1× M ) Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 10 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics ( ) ( ) (3) E ε t/ ε t = ( M ×M ) Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models Σ ( M ×M ) (4) E ε t/ ε s = ( M ×M ) t≠s (no auto) ( M ×M )   (5) E  X t/ ε s  =  ( k ×1) (1×M )  ( K ×M ) ( Xt predetermined ) (6) E X t/ X t = Σ XX finite, non-singular Well-behave data: X (7) p lim sample statistics converge to corresponding population X t/ X t ∑ T t = Σ XX ( k ×k ) ( k ×k ) (8) p lim X t/ ε t = ∑ ( k ×M ) T t ( k ×1) (1×M ) (9) p lim ∑ ε t/ ε t = T t ( M ×1) (1×M ) Σ ( M ×M ) (10) Γ is non-singular We can use the set X as instrumental variables for Y • First equation (1st column) Y γ 1* + X β1* + ε1 = (T × M ) ( M ×1) (T × K ) ( K ×1) (T ×1)  −1     ( M * − 1) +X ↔ Y  γ1  **   (M )     (T ×1)  β1     K*  ** + ε1 =  M    * ** M  M + M =  * ** K  K + K = y1 ↔ = (T ×1) Y γ 1 [T ×( M * −1)] [( M * −1)×1] Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia + X β1 + ε1 (T × K * ) ( K * ×1) (T ×1) 11 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models γ1  β   1  = ↔ y1 +[Y1 X ]  (T ×1) Z1 [T ×( K * + M * −1)] ε (T ×1) δ1 ( K * + M * −1) y1 Z1δ1 + ε1 ↔ = (T ×1) (T ×1) a OLS estimation: δˆ1= ( Z1/ Z1 ) −1 Z=1/ y1 +δ1 ( Z1/ Z1 ) −1 Z1/ ε1 OLS 1 ) δ1 + p lim( Z1/ Z1 ) −1 p lim( Z1/ ε1 ) P lim( δˆ1 = T T OLS δ1 + Σ −ZZ1 / −1    p lim( T Y1 ε1 )  →≠ ≠ δ1    p lim( X / ε )  →= 1   T b Two-stage least squares: Stage (step1): Reduced form equation for Y1:  =  y2 [T ×( M * −1)]  (T ×1) Y1 y= (T ×1) y3 (T ×1)   yM *  (T ×1)  ˆ + Vˆ X Π    (T ×1) (T × K ) ( K ×1) yˆ ( T ×1) y= (T ×1) ˆ + Vˆ X Π    (T ×1) (T × K ) ( K ×1) yˆ3 ( T ×1) … ˆ + Vˆ yM * = X Π M* M* ˆ Y1 =  X Π ˆ  XΠ ˆ  + Vˆ Vˆ  Vˆ  XΠ M*  M*   ˆ ˆ  Π ˆ  + Vˆ Vˆ  Vˆ  Y1 = X Π Π M* M*     ˆ Π Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia Vˆ1 12 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models ˆ + Vˆ = Yˆ + Vˆ Y1 = X Π 1 (All M* – reduced form equations for Y ) ˆ 0, Yˆ /V= ˆ All estimated by OLS → X /V= 1 Put expression for Y1 into 1st structural equation: y1 = Y1γ + X 1β1 + ε1 = [Yˆ1 + Vˆ1 ]γ + X 1β1 + ε1 y1 = Yˆ1γ + X 1β1 + Vˆ1γ + ε1 γ  y1 Yˆ1 X    + (Vˆ1γ + ε1 ) =    β1  Zˆ1 δ1 y1 = Zˆ1δ1 + (Vˆ1γ + ε1 ) Step (Stage 2): Estimate by OLS: δˆ1 = ( Zˆ1/ Zˆ1 ) −1 (( Zˆ1/ y1 ) = δ1 + ( Zˆ1/ Zˆ1 ) −1 Zˆ1/ (Vˆ1γ + ε1 )  SLS →0 Zˆ1 are instrument instrumental variables of [Y X ] δˆ1 is consistent Zˆ1 = W1 → we get the same δˆ1 SLS SLS Instrumental variables estimators: Let W1 be a T × ( M * + K * − 1) matrix such that: (1) p lim W1/ Z1 T = ΣWZ finite, non-singular (1) p lim W1/ ε1 T = finite, non-singular δˆ1 = (W1/ Z1 ) −1 ((W1/ y1 ) IV 1  p lim δˆ1 = δ1 p lim  W1/ Z1  IV T  Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia −1 1  p lim  W1/ ε1  = δ1 T  13 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models → δˆ1 is consistent IV Note: we can use W1 = Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 X  as an instrumental variables set get 2-SLS (2-SLS as IV with W = Z ) Indirect least squares: ** Requires: exactly identified → K= M * − or K ** + M ** =M − δˆ1 = ( X 1/ Z1 ) −1 ( X 1/ y1 ) ILS Note: Z [T ×( K * + M * −1)] X =W 1 [T ×( K * + M * −1)] → same as estimator of found by algebraically solving for 2-SLS as IV with W1 = Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 Note: δˆ1 and from X  = ( Zˆ1/ Z1 ) −1 (( Zˆ1/ y1 ) = ( Zˆ1/ Zˆ1 ) −1 (( Zˆ1/ y1 ) because of orthogonolity condition: IV _ SLS Zˆ1/ Z1 = Zˆ1/ Zˆ1 Note: 2-SLS computational formula Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 X  ˆ = X ( X / X ) −1 X /Y Yˆ1 = X Π 1 → Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 Because: X  =  X ( X / X ) −1 X /Y1 ( X1 X  = X ( X / X ) −1 X / [Y1 X1 ]  X ) = X ( X / X ) −1 X / ( X  X )   I = X ( X / X ) −1 X / X  X ( X / X ) −1 X / X So: Zˆ1 X ( X / X ) −1 X / [Y1 = = X1 ] X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 Then: δˆ1 = ( Zˆ1/ Zˆ1 ) −1 (( Zˆ1/ y1 ) SLS Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 14 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models = ( Z1/ X ( X / X ) −1 X / X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 ) −1 ( X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 ) −1 y1 = ( Z1/ X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 ) −1 ( Z1/ X ( X / X ) −1 X / y1 ) δˆ = ( Z1/ M X Z1 ) −1 ( Z1/ M X y1 ) SLS Three-stage Least Squares Estimation: = y1 Z1δ1 + ε1 Z1 = [Y1 = y2 Z 2δ + ε X1 ] … = yM Z M δ M + ε M Z M = [YM XM ] Using SUR framework: Z1   y1  [T ×( K * + M * −1)] y   Z2  2 =          0  yM             Z M   δ1   ε  δ  ε   +            δ M  ε M  = y Zδ + ε y= Z δ + ε (TM ×1) (TM ×1)   ε1     (T ×1)     ε     =     ε1 ε  ε N   (1×T )        (1×T )  ε N     (T ×1)    σ 11 I σ 12 I  σ 1M I  σ I σ I  σ I  22 2M  =  21 = Σ ⊗I       ( M ×M ) T   σ M I σ M I  σ MM I  E (εε ′) ( MT × MT ) Σ ={σ ij } MM Define: Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 15 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models  0 X   = IM ⊗ X (T × K )      X X 0 X=    0 Pre-multiply system by = X / y X / Zδ + X /ε ( X/ (TM × KM ) (*) ) E X / εε / X = X / (Σ ⊗ I ) X = [ I ⊗ X / ](Σ ⊗ I )[ I ⊗ X ] = (Σ ⊗ X / X ) Apply GLS to (*): ( Z / X (Σ ⊗ X / X ) −1 XZ  δˆ= −1 SLS = ( Z / X (Σ ⊗ X / X ) −1 X / y  Σ is estimated by Σˆ =σˆ ij  M ×M where σˆ ij = ei/ e j T for all i, j pairs and e= yi − zi δˆi i (i = 1, 2,…, M) − SLS Different way:  1st stage: Perform 2-SLS for each equation of the system Save ei s (i = 1,2,…, M); (T ×1) e= i (T ×1) yi − zi δˆi (T ×1) − SLS  2nd stage: Estimate Σ by Σˆ =σˆ ij  M ×M where σˆ ij = ei/ e j T for all i, j pairs  3rd stage: (1) → y= Z δ + ε (TM ×1) (TM ×1) Estimate δ by using instrumental variable Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 16 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models  Zˆ1   [T ×( K * + M * −1)]    Zˆ  0 Zˆ =          0  Zˆ M  Where Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 Zˆ M = YˆM X  and using GLS method: δˆ1 SLS Note:  X M  −1 = ( Zˆ / (Σˆ −1 ⊗ I ) Z  ( Zˆ / (Σˆ −1 ⊗ I ) y  Zˆ1 = X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 … Zˆ M = X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z M → / Zˆ= Z / ⊗ X ( X / X ) −1 X / −1 δˆ1 = ( Z / X (Σˆ −1 ⊗ ( X / X ) −1 ) X / Z  (ΣZ / X⊗( ˆ −1 SLS ( X / X ) −1 ) X / y  If we use: OLS −1 δˆIV = =  Zˆ / Z   Zˆ / y  is simply equation-by-equation 2SLS The improvement of 3SLS is using GLS to gain more efficiency, we need to have one more stage Σˆ =σˆ ij  that is calculate M ×M Note: In the 2-SLS procedure: The matrix: Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 X  has (M* + K* - 1) columns, all columns are linear function of the K column of X (Because Zˆ1 = X ( X / X ) −1 X / Z1 ) There exist, at most, K linear independent combination of the columns of X if the equation is not identified then K ** < M * − → K * + K ** < K * + M * − → K < K * + M * −1 Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 17 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics but Zˆ1 = Yˆ1 Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models X  only has maximum K independent columns → Zˆ1 will not have full rank,  Zˆ1/ Zˆ1  −1 does not exist → 2-SLS estimators cannot compute If, however, the order condition but not the rank condition is met, then although the 2SLS estimator can be computed, it is not a consistent estimator Note: For a system of exactly identified equation: K < K * + M * −1 → X Z = squared matrix (K×K) / i ( K ×T ) (T × K ) −1 δˆi = ( Z i/ X ( X / X ) −1 ) X / Z i  ( Z i/ X ( X / X ) −1 ) X / yi  − SLS = ( X / Z i ) −1 ( X / X )( Z i/ X ) −1 ( Z i/ X )( X / X ) −1 X / yi = ( X / Z i ) −1 X / yi → δˆi = δˆ when K = K * + M * − for every equation in the system − SLS ILS Nam T Hoang University of New England - Australia 18 University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam ... Vietnam Advanced Econometrics ⇒ Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models  γ  Π IK ]    = [    β1  ( K ×1) K ×( M + K )  A ( M + K )1 We have K equations, K+M unknown variables... Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models ˆ + Vˆ = Yˆ + Vˆ Y1 = X Π 1 (All M* – reduced form equations for Y ) ˆ 0, Yˆ /V= ˆ All estimated by... England - Australia University of Economics - HCMC - Vietnam Advanced Econometrics Chapter 12: Simultaneous equations models b Lagged endogenous Ex: variables qt −1 or pt −1 on RHS equation Notation:

Ngày đăng: 09/12/2017, 08:39