Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 62 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
62
Dung lượng
0,96 MB
Nội dung
HOUSING WEALTH EFFECTS IN SINGAORE: PUBLIC
HOUSING VERSUS PRIVATE HOUSING
CHEN SHILU
(MASTER OF SOCIAL SCIENCES), NUS
A THESIS SUBMITTED
FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF ECONOMICS
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE
2010
Acknowledgement
It is my pleasure to express the deepest appreciation to those who has helped me with
this thesis.
I owe sincere gratitude to my most respected supervisors, A/P Anthony Chin Theng
Heng, and A/P Sau Kim Lum, for their patience, encouragement and illuminating
guidance. Through the period of the writing of this thesis, they have spent much time
on each of my drafts and offered me many valuable suggestions. I want to thank them
for generously sharing me with their knowledge and time. Without their help, this
thesis could not have been completed.
i
TABLE OF CONTENTS
SUMMARY ................................................................................................. III
LIST OF TABLES ...................................................................................... IV
LIST OF FIGURES ......................................................................................V
1. INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1
2. LITERTATURE REVIEW...................................................................... 7
3. MAIN CONTRIBUTIONS .................................................................... 16
4. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK ........................................................ 18
4.1 STANDARD LIFETIME BUDGET CONSTRAINTS ....................................... 19
4.2 PRIVATE HOUSING WEALTH EFFECTS ................................................... 22
4.3 PUBLIC HOUSING WEALTH EFFECTS .................................................... 23
4.4 CPF WEALTH EFFECTS ......................................................................... 26
5. EMPIRICAL STUDIES ......................................................................... 28
5.1 DATA...................................................................................................... 28
5.2 METHODOLOGY .................................................................................... 32
5.3 EMPIRICAL RESULTS ............................................................................. 34
5.3.1 Private Housing Wealth Impact On Consumption ......................... 34
5.3.2 Private Housing Wealth Impact On Consumption In Different
Sub-Periods ............................................................................................... 37
5.3.3 Impulse Response Analysis Of Private Housing Wealth Impact
On Consumption ........................................................................................ 39
5.3.4 Public Housing Wealth Impact On Consumption ........................... 44
5.3.5 Public Housing Wealth Impact On Consumption In Different
Sub-Periods ............................................................................................... 45
5.3.6 Impulse Response Analysis Of Public Housing Wealth Impact On
Consumption .............................................................................................. 48
5.3.7 Asymmetric Wealth Effects Of Private Housing On Consumption. 49
6. CONCLUSION ....................................................................................... 51
BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................................................... 53
ii
Summary
This study aims to explore whether appreciation in housing prices affects
consumption in Singapore, and whether private housing and public housing exhibit
different wealth effects. Using aggregate data, the empirical results show no
significant private housing wealth effects or public housing wealth effects in the
Q1:1975-Q4:2009 period and Q1:1990-Q4:2009 period respectively. Nevertheless,
there is evidence of asymmetric effects in private housing market, with consumption
responding significantly towards price increases while remaining stable during price
downturn. It is also observed that there was a structural change in public housing and
public housing wealth effects started to be significant in 2003, when a series of
policies were introduced to boost the public housing market. The role of the Central
Provident Fund (CPF) is extensively examined in this study. The results show that the
CPF wealth effects are not statistically significant. However, the shocks in the
balances of the CPF accounts tend to have a more persistent impact on consumption
compared to housing wealth shocks. Additionally, the CPF is found to have a positive
and significant impact on public housing prices though its influence on private
housing prices is limited.
iii
LIST OF TABLES
TABLE 1: ..................................................................................................... 31
TABLE 2: ..................................................................................................... 35
TABLE 3: ..................................................................................................... 35
TABLE 4: ..................................................................................................... 36
TABLE 5: ..................................................................................................... 38
TABLE 6: ..................................................................................................... 38
TABLE 7:. .................................................................................................... 43
TABLE 8: ..................................................................................................... 44
TABLE 9: ..................................................................................................... 45
TABLE 10: ................................................................................................... 46
TABLE 11: ................................................................................................... 46
TABLE 12: ................................................................................................... 48
TABLE 13: ................................................................................................... 50
iv
LIST OF FIGURES
FIGURE 1 ...................................................................................................... 4
FIGURE 2 ...................................................................................................... 6
FIGURE 3 ...................................................................................................... 6
FIGURE 4 .................................................................................................... 30
FIGURE 5 .................................................................................................... 31
FIGURE 6 .................................................................................................... 31
FIGURE 7 .................................................................................................... 40
FIGURE 8 .................................................................................................... 40
FIGURE 9 .................................................................................................... 41
FIGURE 10 .................................................................................................. 49
v
1. Introduction
It has been widely observed that changes in property prices are associated with changes in
national consumption in many countries. According to the Permanent Income Hypothesis
(PIH) by Friedman (1957), consumption is equal to the annuity value of total wealth,
including human wealth and nonhuman wealth. The lifecycle model by Modigliani and
Brumberg (1955) also suggests that households accumulate and deplete their wealth to
keep their consumption roughly stable. Therefore, it is expected that households will
revise their consumption plan when they experience an unexpected change in their
housing wealth. Various empirical studies examine the housing wealth effects and
provide evidence of consumption responses to housing price changes. Bhatia (1987) and
Case (1992) found significant housing wealth effects with macro data in the United States.
Campbell and Cocco (2007), Case et al. (2005) and Engelhardt (1996) examined
household expenditures using micro data in different countries and concluded that
housing wealth effects were significant.
Unlike the United States, the United Kingdom and other developed countries, the
Singapore housing market consists of a dominant state-controlled public housing sector
and a small private housing market that is relatively less regulated. Public housing is a
unique feature of Singapore in that state-allocated units can be freely traded after a
stipulated period. However, its wealth effects have not been widely examined.
Nevertheless, public housing wealth effects cannot be ignored in the context of Singapore,
given that more than 88% of Singapore citizens live in the subsidised public housing
sector while private housing plays a limited role of supplying expensive residential units
to the higher income groups.
1
New public housing is directly provided by the state on a 99-year lease through its public
housing program managed by the Housing and Development Board (HDB), a sole agency
in charge of the construction and sale of public housing. As the only supplier in the new
public housing market, HDB offers different types of flats, including studio apartments,
units with 2 rooms to 5 rooms, and Design, Build & Sell Scheme (DBSS) flats. DBSS
flats were introduced in 2005 to involve the private sector in the development of public
housing so as to bring about greater innovation in building and design.
Demand for new public housing is also controlled as prospective buyers need to meet
certain eligibility conditions such as citizenship, income, family nucleus and age.
Specifically, eligible buyers must be Singapore Citizens and the family nucleus must
comprise at least another Singapore Citizen or Singapore Permanent Resident. Income
eligibility is adjusted by the government in accordance with the economic outlook and
affordability of its citizenry. The current household income ceiling for HDB flats is
$8,000. Households that are not eligible to buy new HDB flats may need to turn to the
private units or resale HDB flats sold in the open market. They could also buy Executive
Condominium, a hybrid form of private-public housing in Singapore if their income is
below $10,000.
The direct-purchase (new HDB) flats can be re-sold at market rates in the open market,
known as the resale market for public housing, only after a minimum holding period
(MOP) determined by HDB. Therefore, though HDB will not directly control the supply
of resale HDB flats, the MOP has some impact over the number of flats that are eligible
for resale. Currently, the MOP for direct-purchase HDB flats and resale flats is five years
from the effective date of purchase. In terms of demand, prospective buyers of HDB
2
resale flats still need to meet certain eligibility conditions albeit less stringent than those
for direct-purchase HDB flats.
Private housing experienced rapid price increases in the 1980s and 1990s due to
economic growth and an increase in demand for housing. Between 1986 and 1996, the
Singapore Private Residential Property Price Index (RPPI) increased by 440% in nominal
terms. However, prices fell by 45% between 1996 and 1998 due to government controls
and the Asian financial crisis. The private housing market recovered slightly between
1998 and 2000, and prices started rising in 2005 given the policies implemented to boost
the housing market.
The relaxation of foreign ownership rules on apartments, the
increase of the maximum loan-to-value ratio from 80% to 90%, the reduction of cash
down payments from 10% to 5% for home purchase, and permission for non-related
singles to use their CPF to jointly purchase private residential properties contributed to a
23.6% (20.9% in real terms) increase in the RPPI in 2007. In spite of the downturn
incurred during financial crisis in 2008, the improved economic conditions in 2009 and
low interest rates enabled the housing market to recover quickly.
Price movements in the public resale housing sector generally mirror those in the private
housing market, as shown in Figure 1. In 1993, the housing finance policy for resale HDB
flats was liberalised and flats were allowed to be financed based on market prices,
resulting in a boom of the resale market. Strong economic growth in the 1990s also led to
upward pressure on resale public housing prices. Resale public housing is sometimes
regarded as an inferior substitute of private housing. Singapore Permanent Residents
(SPR) buyers who could not afford private housing turn to resale public flats, and some
Singaporean households may prefer resale public flats to new units due to their
3
convenient location or the shorter waiting time to get the unit. A high immigration rate
and the impatience for new units have continued to support the demand for resale public
units and to push up the resale prices even during the crisis years.
Figure 1 plots both the private housing prices and resale public housing prices against
aggregate non-housing private consumption. There is a general simultaneity between
housing prices and consumption, though the simultaneity becomes weak during the
recessions in 1997 and 2008. This suggests that appreciation in housing prices is likely to
exert a positive influence on consumption.
200
25000
180
160
20000
140
120
15000
100
80
10000
60
40
5000
0
199001
199004
199103
199202
199301
199304
199403
199502
199601
199604
199703
199802
199901
199904
200003
200102
200201
200204
200303
200402
200501
200504
200603
200702
200801
200804
200903
20
Public Resale Index
Private Residential Index
0
Non housing consumption
Figure 1. Public housing, Private housing and Non housing consumption
Given the distinct institutional character of the residential sector, this paper distinguishes
between the public and private housing markets and attempts to explore the significance
of respective housing wealth effects in Singapore. It also tries to examine how the
Central Provident Fund (CPF) affects consumption. Singapore adopted a mandatory fullyfunded defined contribution system to cover a wide range of retirement, healthcare, home
ownership, family protection and asset enhancement needs. Working Singaporeans are
4
required to contribute a certain portion of their incomes, on a monthly basis, to their
individual CPF accounts that are managed by the CPF Board. The CPF members‟
contributions are channeled to three accounts: the Ordinary Account from which funds
can be used to buy a home, pay for CPF insurance, investment and education; the Special
Account for old age, contingency purposes and investment in retirement-related financial
products; and the Medisave Account for hospitalization expenses and approved medical
insurance. The Special Account is seldom touched by households due to its purpose to
serve retirement needs. Savings in this account, together with the leftover in the Ordinary
Account after home purchase and other expenditures, will be transferred to the CPF
Minimum Sum Scheme which ensures a minimal sum of money for Singaporeans during
their retirement years. The CPF members are not allowed to use the monies under the
CPF Minimum Sum Scheme for any form of investment. However, at age 55, members
can use the Minimum Sum to purchase an annuity, or to leave the savings in a bank or in
the CPF board. At the age of 62, the money would be released monthly to create a stable
annuity flow.
The CPF Public Housing Scheme (PHS) and the Residential Properties Scheme (RPS),
which were introduced in 1968 and 1981 respectively, allow CPF members to use their
CPF savings to pay for downpayment, stamp duty and mortgage payments incurred for
the housing purchase. The number of members who have utilised the two schemes to
finance their homes has been increasing steadily. The number of members under the PHS
grew from 2,900 in 1968 to 1.29 million at the end of 2007, while the number of those
under the RPS rose from 1,000 in 1981 to 226,000 in 2007. Presently, over 70% of flat
owners service housing loans solely with CPF savings. The withdrawal of the CPF
savings for housing moves closely the housing prices as shown in Figure 2 and Figure 3.
5
CPF schemes ease the financing burden of housing purchases and this paper attempts to
examine how the CPF may affect public and private housing wealth effects.
1800
200
1600
180
160
1400
140
120
1200
1000
100
80
800
600
60
40
400
0
198103
198203
198303
198403
198503
198603
198703
198803
198903
199003
199103
199203
199303
199403
199503
199603
199703
199803
199903
200003
200103
200203
200303
200403
200503
200603
200703
200803
200903
200
CPF withdrawal for private housing
20
0
Private Residential Price Index
Figure 2. CPF and Private housing price index
3000
160
140
2500
120
2000
100
1500
80
60
1000
40
500
CPF withdrawal for Public housing
200901
200801
200701
200601
200501
200401
200301
200201
200101
200001
199901
199801
199701
199601
199501
199401
199301
199201
199101
199001
0
20
0
Resale Price Index
Figure 3. CPF and Public housing price index
Moreover, CPF Members may invest their Ordinary Account balances under the CPF
Investment Scheme - Ordinary Account (CPFIS-OA) and their Special Account balances
6
under the CPF Investment Scheme - Special Account (CPFIS-SA), if they are confident
of earning a higher return than the CPF interest rates. Under the CPFIS, the CPF savings
can be invested in shares and loan stocks, unit trusts, government bonds, statutory board
bonds, bank deposits, fund management accounts, endowment insurance policies,
investment-linked insurance policies (ILPs), exchange traded funds (ETFs) and gold. It is
expected that the CPFIS may encourage households‟ investment in shares and enhance
the stock wealth effects.
Apart from the possible effects on housing and stock wealth, balances in CPF accounts
may directly affect consumption as a form of forced saving. According to the lifecycle
model, people smoothes consumption to prevent income uncertainty in the future, known
as precautionary saving. Therefore, CPF contributions reduce current consumption on the
one hand; but on the other hand, they enable households to be more prudent about their
future and retirement due to the accumulations in their CPF accounts. Asher (1999)
examined the economic impacts of the CPF, with a focus on the CPF adequacy for
retirement financing by reviewing the CPF investment schemes. This paper tries to apply
econometric methods to explore how the CPF affects Singapore housing prices and
consumption.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews relevant literature
followed by Section 3 which summarises key contributions of the paper. The theoretical
framework is provided in Section 4. Section 5 describes the data and statistics summary,
and documents the empirical results. Finally, Section 6 concludes.
2. Literature Review
7
Given the correlation between Singapore house prices and consumption shown in Section
1, it is tempting to attribute it to the housing wealth effect. However, it is crucial to
understand how consumption is determined, and whether wealth is causal to consumption.
Keynes (1936) marks the start of modern consumption theory by exploring the
relationship between consumption and income in his General Theory. He views
consumption as a function of current income, and claims that the marginal propensity to
consume (MPC), as well as the average propensity to consume (APC), falls with income.
Inspired by his work, other researchers extended his study on consumption theory.
Friedman (1957) views consumption as a function of wealth or permanent income, known
as the Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH). The PIH maintains that households consume
a fixed fraction of their permanent income, the annuity value of lifetime income and
wealth, thereby introducing income expectations to consumption theory. The PIH implies
that the MPC is constant and equal to the APC, which is consistent with Kuznets‟ (1946)
findings that long run time series consumption data for the U.S. economy is characterized
by a constant aggregate APC.
Bilson (1980) provides empirical evidence for the PIH with tests on quarterly time-series
data from the U.S., U.K., and Germany. Flavin (1981) applies the test to aggregate
quarterly U.S. data and rejects the PIH. Weissenberger (1986) fits ARMA models to
adjust for the serial correlation of changes in consumption and rejects the PIH using
updated data for Germany and the U.K. Kim (1996) presents two alternatives and
examines whether PIH consumption is a good approximation of postwar U.S. data. He
finds that postwar U.S. consumption deviates from the PIH by less than 4 percent, which
8
indicates a reasonably good fit when viewed in a representative agent framework with so
many restrictive assumptions. More recently, using the Penn World Table annual data,
Dawson et al. (2001) report that the PIH holds in industrial countries but not developing
countries. However, the different results observed in industrial and developing countries
may be a result of systematic differences in data quality.
West (1988a) and Campbell and Deaton (1989) test the relation between the variance of
the revisions in consumption and the variance of the revisions in permanent income and
claim that changes in consumption are much less volatile than changes in observed
income. They reject the joint hypothesis implied in the PIH that per capita aggregate
consumption is generated by the permanent income model and that shocks to labor
income are permanent.
To differentiate the consumption response arising from different asset classes, Friedman
(1957) conjectures a lower MPC out of human wealth than out of financial wealth. Zeldes
(1989) later proposes to “put a weight of less than one on human wealth before adding it
to financial wealth, or to discount expected future income at a higher discount rate.”
Hayashi (1982) tests a generalized permanent income model, using a higher discount rate
for human wealth without using the theory of optimality. Wang (2006) further uses a
„risk-adjusted‟ measure for human wealth by calculating expected future income at a
higher discount rate based on the agent‟s optimality, and delivers a lower MPC out of
human wealth than out of financial wealth.
The introduction of the lifecycle theory by Modigliani and Brumberg (1955) is another
milestone in consumption theory as it introduces utility maximisation to the theoretical
9
framework. Individuals choose a lifetime pattern of consumption in order to maximise
their lifetime utility given their lifetime budget constraint which includes lifetime income
expectations. Lifecycle theory recognises that interest rates and time preference may
affect consumption, and that consumption may vary at different stages of life. The credit
market, specifically borrowing and lending, is also introduced to the theoretical
framework. Modigliani and Brumberg (1955) incorporate microeconomic choice theory
into macroeconomic consumption theory, and draw microeconomic implications with
cross-section data.
Modigliani and Brumberg (1980) further look at the time-series and macroeconomic
implications and conclude that households tend to average income over the life span, with
increases in life-time resources leading to proportionate increases in consumption in all
periods of life.
Subsequent literature has developed methods for dealing with uncertainty which is not
addressed in the Modigliani and Brumberg lifecycle model. Hall (1978) claims that
consumption is a random walk using time-series analysis and the theory of rational
expectations. Flavin (1981), Hall and Mishkin (1982), Hayashi (1982), Muellbauer (1983)
and Bernanke (1985) build their research on the random walk consumption. Flavin (1981)
argues that detrended per capita consumption exhibits excess sensitivity to predictable
changes in detrended per capita income. Mankiw and Shapiro (1985) further claim that
income can be well approximated by a random walk with drift, and the excess sensitivity
may be the spurious result of the presence of unit roots in the detrended per capita
consumption and income data. Hall and Mishkin (1981) and Bernanke (1985) intend to
analyse the correlations between the change in consumption and the econometric
10
estimates of contemporaneous or led innovations in other variables, but their work is
constrained by the fact that the true innovations are unobservable to agents.
Various work attempts to explain the motives of savings and consumption smoothing.
Carroll (1997) believes that people will never borrow even with uncertain future earnings
and the possibility of not being able to repay their debts, if they are sufficiently prudent.
Deaton (1991) also claims that people can save to smooth out their consumption, but they
cannot have consumption greater than their income, except when they already have some
assets in the bank. Consumption may also be smoothed over a few years when liquidity is
constrained, rather than over the whole life-cycle.
Clarida (1991) maintains that the MPC out of any permanent increment (in expectation)
to labor income during the working years will be less than one, as workers tend to save
more to finance higher consumption during retirement. Furthermore, the MPC out of
permanent shifts (in expectation) in labor income declines monotonically with age. Banks,
Blundell and Tanner (1998) observe that saving for retirement seems to start only in
middle-age, and is therefore insufficient to prevent a sharp fall in consumption at
retirement. The elderly do not dispose of their assets and indeed that many of the elderly
appear to save part of their incomes. Duesenberry (1948) documents „relative‟ income
hypothesis, which maintains that an individual‟s desire to consume increases with the
ratio of his expenditure to some weighted average of the expenditures of his contacts.
Merton (1971) shows that consumers maximise their expected utility and set consumption
to be proportional to their total assets when risk is confined to financial assets.
Gourinchas and Parker (2002) show the relative roles of precautionary and retirement
11
motives for accumulating liquid assets, and construct a measure of precautionary saving
and wealth. They indicate that wealth is accumulated early in life for precautionary
reasons. Households would instead borrow against future labor income if they are
sufficiently prudent.
Following Merton (1971), later studies examine the wealth effect of different asset classes.
Housing, as part of total assets, is also extensively examined. According to the PIH and
the lifecycle theory, an increase in housing value is likely to lead to an increase in
consumption. This housing wealth effects can be realised through several channels. First,
an appreciation in housing value increases the households‟ wealth and thus increases
consumption, which is regarded as direct wealth effects. Second, households that face
binding credit restrictions can borrow more against housing which can be used as
collateral in a loan. An increase in housing price relaxes credit constraints and allows
homeowners to borrow more to smooth consumption over the life cycle. This is regarded
as collateral effects or indirect wealth effects.
Various papers have provided empirical evidence for significant housing wealth effects in
different countries. Muellbauer and Murphy (1990) argue that the consumption boom in
the United Kingdom in the late 1980s could be attributed to the increase in housing prices
as well as financial liberalisation. Case (1992) finds substantial consumption increase
during the real estate price boom in the late 1980s using aggregate data for New England.
Skinner (1989) examines the link between housing wealth and consumer expenditure
using data on individual households from the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)
and found statistically significant housing wealth effects. However, the effects become
insignificant after correcting for heterogeneity among homeowners. Engelhardt (1996)
12
tries to examine the homeowners‟ marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of real
capital gains, and obtained a MPC of 0.03 for Canadian households. Benjamin, Chinloy,
and Jud (2010) estimate the United States‟ consumption function using the value of the
real estate and financial wealth for the period Q1:1952-Q4: 2001 and find the real estate
would impose larger wealth effects on consumption compared to financial assets.
Campbell and Cocco (2007) use United Kingdom micro data to show that housing wealth
effects tend to be large for older homeowners and small for young homeowners. Case et
al. (2005) have done a comparison of housing wealth effects and stock wealth effects.
New measures of wealth are constructed for the cross-sectional analysis. Large housing
wealth effects are observed both across states in the US using quarterly data for the period
1982-1999, and a panel of 14 countries using annual data during the period 1975-1996.
Some researchers claim that high housing prices increase consumption through a lower
incentive to save. Yoshikawa and Ohtake (1989) apply micro data in Japan and find that
the net effect of higher housing prices is to increase consumption via a lower incidence to
purchase houses by households. Engelhardt (1994) claims that high housing prices lead to
a fall in the Canadian households‟ incentive to save for a down payment and an increase
in consumption.
Despite the evidence of housing wealth effects shown in numerous empirical studies,
there are some theoretical works posing doubt on such effects. Elliott (1980) argues that
housing would not exert as significant wealth effects as financial wealth. Sheiner (1995)
claims that households may actually increase savings due to higher down payment
requirements to purchase houses when housing prices increase, in contrast to the
conclusion by Engelhardt (1994). There are also quite a lot of empirical works that show
13
no evidence of housing wealth effects. Hoynes and McFadden (1997) find that
households would hardly change their savings in non-housing assets in response to
expectations about capital gains in owner-occupied housing. Levin (1998) claims that
homeowners do not consume their housing wealth which therefore would not affect their
consumption. Some skeptics of housing wealth effects believe that housing price
fluctuations would not affect the economy at an aggregate level as housing is a
consumption durable which is necessary for everyone. Sinai and Souleles (2005) provide
evidence that fluctuations in house prices would not have real wealth effects, because the
gain from higher housing prices is simply compensation for a higher implicit cost of
living in the house. The consumption choices may be affected if there are substitution
effects, and it may lead to the change in the distribution of consumption, but not the
change in the aggregate amount. Recently, Buiter (2008) finds that housing wealth gain
would be offset by higher housing costs during boom periods at the aggregate level, and
thus might not necessarily increase consumption. Psychological factors are also
considered as the cause of insignificance of housing wealth effects. Shefrin and Thaler
(1988) provide an explanation from the psychological perspective and claim that people
tend to take certain assets as more appropriate for current expenditures while take others,
such as housing wealth, as for long-term savings. Thaler (1990) further argues that
housing wealth would be classified into the mental account which is not for current
consumption, and thus would not lead to significant wealth effects.
A related branch of the literature suggests that house prices and consumption are
correlated as both are affected by a same third factor, rather than through housing wealth
effects. Calomiris et al. (2009) find no significant housing wealth effects after adjusting
for common macroeconomic factors.
14
The asymmetric effects of housing price increases and decreases on consumption have
also been explored. There is no consensus so far. Case et al. (2005) show evidence of
positive wealth effects when housing prices increase, but no significant effects when
prices decrease. This is in contrast to the conclusion by Skinner (1993) and Engelhardt
(1996) who find significantly negative effects on consumption when housing prices
decrease but no effects when prices increase.
Given contradicting findings in different literature, the significance of housing wealth
effects on consumption is likely to be an empirical issue, subject to econometric methods
and data analysis. Regarding the Singapore housing market, the empirical studies on
housing wealth effects have been all based on macro data due to the lack of micro data.
There is no consensus on whether the housing wealth effects are significant among the
limited research. Ng (2002) argues that private housing effects are significantly negative.
Phang (2004), using the same set of data, shows no significant direct wealth effects or
collateral effects based on the empirical results of both regressions when the CPF is
included or excluded in the measure of disposable income. Phang (2004) also finds an
asymmetric consumption response to increases and decreases of private housing prices.
Abeysinghe and Choy (2004) claim that housing wealth effects are insignificant in
Singapore. Co-integration of income and consumption did not exist, probably because the
sample period was not long enough for the two to exhibit long-run equilibrium. Edelstein
and Lum (2004) conclude that changes in public house prices would significantly and
persistently affect aggregate consumption, while there are no significant private housing
wealth effects in Singapore. These studies, however, have been constrained by the
limitations of data as public resale market was first introduced only in 1990. The high
15
multicollinearity of private housing and public housing also makes it difficult to
disaggregate the wealth effects.
In terms of econometric methods, Durlauf and Hall (1988, 1989a, 1989b) are the first to
develop a general framework for computing estimates of specification error or deviation,
which is treated as an unobserved component in a signal extraction problem in the model.
Campbell (1987) finds that saving, a linear combination of income and consumption is
stationary in its level under the PIH, though neither income nor consumption is stationary.
Therefore, he sets up a vector autoregression (VAR) and uses the theory of cointegration
in time series to test the model. Edelstein and Lum (2004) apply the vector-autoregressive
model with exogenous variables (VARX), followed by testing the impulse response of
consumption to different variables, to estimate wealth effects of both private and public
housing in Singapore.
3. Main Contributions
The contributions of this paper are as follows.
First of all, the role of the CPF is extensively examined in this study. To my knowledge,
this is the first paper which examines the wealth effects of balances in CPF accounts. It
considers the direct effects of the CPF on consumption as a standalone financial asset, as
well as the indirect effects through its influences on the housing and stock wealth. The
results show that CPF imposes a more persistent impact on consumption than housing
wealth. My interpretation is that the positive shocks to the CPF will lead to higher future
income, especially after retirement, and expected life-long resources are enhanced. This
shows that CPF is considered as nonhuman wealth or permanent income by households,
16
and the empirical study gives that the MPC of CPF is highest among all forms of
nonhuman wealth.
Second, it compares the wealth effects of private housing and public housing. Most of the
previous literature examined only the private housing market without taking the public
resale market into account. Although Edelstein and Lum (2004) examine the differences
between public housing wealth and private housing wealth, take both public and private
housing indices as measures of housing wealth and include them in one regression.
Additionally, the relatively short sample period may fail to result in a robust conclusion.
Different from Edelstein and Lum (2004), I regress aggregate consumption on private and
public housing wealth separately instead of putting them in one regression. This strategy
has several merits. It allows a much longer sample period when investigating the private
housing wealth effect. The RPPI is available since 1975 but the RPI is only available
since 1990. The separation of these two variables can enable a longer sample period for
the private housing regression. Moreover, it helps to overcome the multicollinearity
problem given that the correlation between the public and private housing is 0.9037 from
1990 to 2009. In the unreported robustness tests, I also follow Edelstein and Lum
(2004)‟s strategies and find that the results remain the same.
Third, this paper extends Phang (2004) and explores the asymmetric wealth effects in
private housing. More specifically, this paper includes the stock wealth and balances in
the CPF accounts in the model and further explores the asymmetric wealth effect in
housing. Phang (2004) applies the OLS method to study the contemporary effect of
housing wealth. However, Phang (2004) assumes no leads or lag effects and fails to
capture the dynamic features of housing wealth effect. In my study, a VAR method is
17
applied and the impulse response analysis helps to capture the dynamic features and
identify the cause-effect relationship. Moreover, in contrast to Phang (2004), the results
show that house price increases have a positive effect on aggregate consumption. One of
the explanations is that when private housing prices increase, homeowners tend to view
their private units as investment assets and are eager to reap the return from housing price
appreciation. The direct wealth effects are significant and consumption is increased.
However, during housing price depreciation, homeowners may tend to treat the private
housing for self-occupation rather than for investment, and stay in the current units so that
they will not lose in the depreciation. This result is consistent with Case et al. (2005)‟s
findings in the US housing market.
Last but not least, this study takes stock wealth as a control variable while previous
literature on Singapore housing wealth effects tend to ignore it in the regressions.1 While
our study provides an important implication of housing price, it should be admitted that
we do not have access to individual consumption data. As a result, this paper is unable to
evaluate the heterogeneity of housing wealth effect across income groups. However, it
can be concluded that housing wealth effect seems to be weak in general at least during
1975 to 2009 periods. More comprehensive studies will require micro-level data on
household consumption and we expect that the further researches might help to fill in this
important gap.
4. Theoretical framework
1
However, various studies have explored how the volatility in the stock market affects consumption in different
markets other than Singapore. For example, Elliott (1980) examined risky financial assets and concluded that stocks
influenced consumer expenditure in US. Starr-McCluer (1998) found differentiated stock wealth effects given different
responses from groups with different holdings. A survey exhibiting some time-series evidence of stock market wealth
effects was also shown by Poterba (2000). However, Case et al. (2005) found weak evidence of a stock market wealth
effect using both a panel of annual observations for 14 developed countries from 1975 to 1996, and another panel of
quarterly data for each of the US states for the period from 1982 to 1999.
18
4.1 Standard lifetime budget constraints
According to the Permanent Income Hypothesis and Lifecycle Model, identical
consumers choose
in each period t in order to maximize the utility conditional on the
information set in time t2:
(4.1) 3
subject to
(4.2)
(4.3)
(4.4)
where
and
is financial wealth in period t, r is interest rate,
is labor income in period t,
is the consumption in period t, T is the end of lifetime. This paper assumes that
the utility function is concave. The following is the solution for this maximization
problem:
(4.5)4
Therefore, (4.5) can be written as (4.6), assuming that the best prediction for
is the
2
is the conditional expectation on time t.
As indicated by Zeldes (1989), I assume that the discount rate equals to interest rate.
4
The model setup mainly follows Zeldes (1989). In this stylized model, the interest rate is assumed to be constant while
the prediction remains similar even given a stochastic interest rate. Edelstein and Lum (2004) take into account the
variance in interest rate and obtain similar results. Thus, the stochastic feature of interest will not influence our findings
3
19
linear projection of
.
(4.6)5
The Permanent Income Hypothesis and Lifecycle Model suggest that consumption is a
function of different asset classes. More specifically, following Case et al. (2005),
consumption is a function of human wealth which takes real income as a proxy, and nonhuman wealth including financial asset, fixed asset (housing wealth), and other assets.
(4.7)
As housing is a necessity, homeowners are forced to buy higher-priced flats when they
sell their current units. Owners of public housing may realise the gain in housing wealth
during price appreciation, by selling off the appreciated unit in the resale market at the
market rate and buying a new HDB flat at the subsidised rate from HDB, or by selling off
a higher-value unit and trading down to a lower-value unit in the HDB resale market.
Owners of private housing may also realise gain in housing wealth, by selling their
private properties during price hike if they have more than one residential unit, or by
selling off higher-value unit and trading down to a lower-value unit in the private housing
resale market.
Nevertheless, on an aggregate basis, public and private housing wealth effects are unclear
since the homeowners may make a gain by selling the flats in the open market while the
buyers may suffer from the high housing prices. Therefore, private and public housing
5
H (.) is a linear function of Y and F (.) is a linear function of W and Y.
20
wealth effects at an aggregate level are worth examining as an important empirical
question.
Additionally, Thaler (1990) argues that different wealth would be segregated into separate
mental accounts, and certain assets are more appropriate to use for current expenditures
while others are earmarked for long-term savings. The price appreciation of the assets for
long-term savings may not result in significant consumption responses. Following this
mental account theory, housing price appreciation may not significantly affect
consumption as households generally tend to regard housing as suitable for long-term
investment.
Apart from the direct housing wealth effects, we also attempt to examine indirect wealth
effects, for example, the collateral or balance sheet effects which enable homeowners to
pledge their flats as collateral and unlock housing equity for consumption. NTUC Income
introduced the first RM scheme for private housing in 1998, and to public housing in
March 2006. The other provider, OCBC Bank offered RM for private properties only
with two different loan options – term-based and annuity linked. The types of mortgages
on offer to unlock housing equity have been quite limited and have frustrated much of the
demand to release net housing equity. Currently, both NTUC-Income and OCBC have
ceased issuing RM loans. According to Chia and Tsui (2009), the Reverse Mortgages
(RM) Market in Singapore remains thin until the Lease Buyback Scheme (LBS), a
monetisation option for low-income elderly Singaporean households living in HDB flats,
was implemented in March 2009. Under the LBS, the HDB purchases the tail-end of the
flat lease, while the elderly are able to unlock their housing equity and receive a lifelong
income stream to supplement their retirement income, and age-in-place in their own flats.
21
Another explanation for higher consumption during house price appreciation is the
increase in perceived wealth of homeowners due to an upward trend in housing prices. A
rational consumer will smooth his consumption throughout the time horizon according to
his current and future income and assets, therefore an increase in housing price is likely to
result in a long run increase in total perceived assets and therefore impose positive effects
on consumption.
As discussed in Section 1, housing wealth consists of public housing wealth and private
housing wealth in the context of Singapore. Given the different institutional features, we
expect that public housing and private housing mat have different wealth effects.
4.2 Private housing wealth effects
Hypothesis 1: Private housing wealth effects are significant (insignificant)
Private housing may impose significant wealth effects on consumption. As the buying
and selling of private housing is subject to less rigorous restrictions, households are able
to reap the asset return easily. For example, there is no MOP requirement before reselling private units in the open market. Recently, there is a trend that more private
housing owners tend to purchase resale HDB units. According to data in The Strait Times
(Feb 15, 2010), the proportion of resale HDB flat buyers with private home addresses
ranged between 8% and 19% of transactions. If these private housing owners trade down
to reside in the public units, they will be able to channel the return from private housing
appreciation to consumption. The direct wealth effects of private housing are likely to be
large as it is likely to be classified into the mental account for current consumption.
22
In addition, the financing of private housing has been less difficult since the CPF
liberalisation in 1981. Prior to February 2010, the downpayment was 10% of the total
housing value with only a 5% cash outlay and 5% from the CPF Accounts. Even though
the down payment requirement was recently lifted to 20%, the cash outlay remains at 5%
of total value and the rest can be drawn from the CPF accounts. This enables the
households to invest in private housing and reap the return for current consumption.
However, at an aggregate level, private housing wealth effect can also be insignificant.
Although homeowners may make a gain by selling the flats in the open market, the
families pursuing a flat may suffer from the high housing price as mentioned previously.
Moreover, if the jump in housing price is transitory, we should not expect any significant
impact on current consumption as rational consumer will smooth the consumption
through the time horizon.
4.3 Public housing wealth effects
Hypothesis 2: Public housing wealth effects are insignificant (significant)
Public housing shares some commons with private housing in that homeowner can gain
by selling the flats in the open market and lose by pursuing a high priced flat.
Nevertheless, public housing market is highly regulated, resulting in a relatively stable
price and fewer speculation opportunities compared to private housing market. For
example, homeowners can only sell their flats in the open market to eligible buyers after a
MOP of up to five years. Besides, prior to 2003, homeowners were not allowed to sublet
23
their flats unless they left Singapore for work or study. Therefore, public housing is more
likely to be viewed as a safe asset for long-term saving according to Thaler (1990).
Second, homeowners of public units may tend to view their public housing as a hedge
against risk for their whole life, as their expected future income is generally lower than
those living in private properties. Singaporeans have been considered as „asset-rich and
cash-poor‟ according to Chia and Tsui (2009), and the majority of the households residing
in public units are constrained by limited budgets. As housing is a necessity, households
need to purchase another unit for self-residence when they sell the current one, unless
they own a second flat. According to HDB policy, a household is entitled to purchase
subsidized new HDB flats twice in a lifetime given that the purpose of public housing is
not for investment but to provide a permanent home for Singaporeans. An existing owner
or ex-owner of a new HDB flat can apply for a second flat only after five years excluding
any period of subletting of the whole current flat, and the second-time purchaser is
required to pay a resale levy which can be as high as 25% for a 5-room or Executive flat.
Therefore, the homeowners tend to reside in their heavily-subsided public units for longterm occupancy. Consequently, the appreciation in public housing prices may not
significantly alter consumption.
In addition, public housing is built for long-term owner occupation and the HDB has been
trying to emphasise this purpose by continuously upgrading HDB flats. Recently,
aggressive plans, which are tailored to meet the changing needs of the communities, have
been drawn up to further improve the physical environment of HDB estates. Maintenance
and upgrading have been taking place for middle-aged HDB flats so that the residents can
enjoy new facilities and amenities similar to those of new flats or even private housing.
24
This deters homeowners‟ incentive to move away from the existing units and enhances
the perspectives that public housing should be retained for long-term occupation.
However, it is noticed that regulations on public housing have been loosened since 2003.
For example, the HDB has progressively relaxed the subletting rule. Subletting allows
eligible homeowners to rent out a room or the entire flat to generate rental income. In
2003, homeowners could rent out their flats after 15 years for lessees with an outstanding
HDB loan, and 10 years if the loan has been paid-up. In 2005, this was cut to 10 and 5
years respectively. Since 2007, all HDB flats can be rented out after meeting the MOP.
When the price of resale flat goes up in the open market, the rental income from
subletting will generally increase. This proportion of income is likely to be viewed to be
current, and thus will be channeled to consumption rather than long-term savings.
The Lease Buyback Scheme (LBS), implemented in March 2009, enabled the elderly to
unlock their housing equity and age-in-place in their own flats as mentioned previously.
In addition, sellers also receive $10,000 as cash transfer of which they can keep $5,000 as
an up-front lump sum subsidy. The value unlocked depends on both the property value
and the length of remaining lease of the HDB flat. The collateral effects, or the indirect
wealth effects, are enhanced during public housing price appreciation. Such a change in
public housing market may also impose structure shocks to wealth effects.
In sum, the unique institutional features in public housing market may result in distinction
between public and private housing wealth effects. Therefore, it is essential to examine
public and private housing wealth effects separately.
25
4.4 CPF wealth effects
As a mandatory social pension scheme, the CPF requires working Singaporeans below 55
years old to make a monthly contribution to their interest bearing CPF accounts. This
contribution is a fraction of the monthly income for the working residents and differs by
income levels. The monies can be used for retirement financing, housing purchase,
medical treatment or services whenever they are in need. Furthermore, employers are also
required to contribute to the CPF accounts of their employees, which mean that the future
budgets (wealth) of households are improved by the employers‟ portion.
These balances in the CPF can be taken as financial assets with certain rates of return. If
kept with the CPF Board, the Ordinary Account now pays 2.5% and Special Account
pays 4%. Compared to bank deposit rates, the returns of monies in the CPF accounts are
much higher. The CPF members also have a choice to transfer money from the Ordinary
Account to the Special Account to enjoy a higher interest rate. The planning horizon for
the accumulation in the Special Account is relatively long. Therefore, it is reasonable to
view CPF as an important asset class and impose effects on consumption. The equation
(4.7) can be rewritten as
(4.8)
And we have a following hypothesis: -
Hypothesis 3: Central Provident Fund (CPF) net wealth effects are significant
26
Except for the direct effect on consumption, the CPF may indirectly affect consumption
by its impact on housing prices. Though the CPF savings are essentially for old age,
Singaporeans have increasingly used their CPF savings to purchase homes especially
during the boom of housing market. As shown in Figure 2 previously, the liberalisation of
the CPF policies in 1981, which allowed households to use the CPF savings to finance
residential properties under Residential Properties Scheme (RPS), was likely to have
supported the rise in the RPPI since then. Lum (2002) found that the CPF liberalisation in
1981 affected private housing prices significantly. Similarly, Figure 3 shows the RPI and
the CPF withdrawal for the Public Housing Scheme. The rise in resale prices since 1994
may have been supported by the 172% increase in the net CPF withdrawals for housing
from 1994 to 1999. However, we do observe that resale prices continued to go up high
despite the sharp decrease in the CPF withdrawals after 2003.
Another CPF indirect wealth effects on consumption may be realised via CPF Investment
Scheme (CPFIS), which has helped to increase stock ownership among the CPF members.
Since the inception of the CPFIS, the CPF members have progressively turned to
professional fund managers to help manage their money, particularly in unit trusts.
Households indirectly participate in the stock market through the unit trusts, which are
investment vehicles which pool money from numerous investors to invest in a portfolio of
securities such as shares, bonds, and deposits. Out of the 349 Collective Investment
Schemes managed by unit trusts in Singapore, 162 were 'CPF-included' under the CPFIS.
According to Singapore Asset Management Industry Survey in 2007, CPF-included funds
represented 67% (or $26 billion) of the unit trust industry's assets under management,
from 16 percent in 1997. The booming asset management industry, propelled by the
CPFIS, adds to the turnover of the stock market with frequent trading.
27
Additionally, there were some circumstances where the CPF members were allowed to
purchase discounted shares with their accounts. For example, Singtel offered Group A
shares and ST-2 shares at preferential fixed prices of S$1.90 and S$2.50 per share in
October 1993 and August 1996 respectively. The CPF members who bought the
discounted Singtel Share can sell them at the market price, and the sale proceeds will be
refunded to their CPF Ordinary Accounts. Such special schemes initiated by the CPF
Board also help to increase stock ownership.
5. Empirical Studies
5.1 Data
The data comprise quarterly observations from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009 for aggregate nonhousing consumption expenditure, disposable income, housing wealth in the private
residential market, financial wealth in the stock market and the aggregate CPF
outstanding balances in Singapore. As the public resale market was introduced in 1990,
the data for public housing wealth indicators are from Q1:1990 to Q4:2009.
The
definitions of variables for the empirical study mainly follow those in Edelstein and Lum
(2004). More specifically, the definitions and the sources of the main variables are as
follows:
Real aggregate non-housing consumption (C): it is defined as logarithm of nominal
aggregate private consumption expenditure, subtracting expenditure on housing and
utilities and deflated by the Consumer Price Index (CPI). The series are provided by
the Singapore Department of Statistics and it starts from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009.
28
Real disposable income (Y): it is defined as logarithm of nominal Gross Domestic
Product (GDP), subtracting taxes from and deflated using the CPI. The CPF
Contributions are not excluded from the disposable income. The series are provided
by the Singapore Department of Statistics and it starts from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009.
Real private housing wealth (pri): it is defined as logarithm of Private Residential
Property Price Index (RPPI), deflated using the CPI. It is used as a measure of real
private housing wealth, following Case et al. (2005) that take housing index as an
indicator of housing wealth. The RPPI is a capital value-weighted, transaction based
index compiled by the Urban Redevelopment Authority (URA) and it can be downed
load from DataStream and it starts from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009..
Real public housing wealth (pub): it is defined as logarithm of Resale Price Index
(RPI), deflated using the CPI. It is taken in this paper to measure public housing
wealth. The price of public resale units are determined by the open market, and
therefore, can better reflect the value of public housing compared to the price of new
public units. The RPI series are provided by the Housing and Development Board
and it can be downloaded from HDB website (www.hdb.gov.sg). This data starts
from Q1:1990 to Q4:2009.
Real stock wealth (sto): it is defined as logarithm of Singapore MSCI, deflated using
the CPI and is taken as the measure of stock wealth in Singapore. The series are
source from DataStream and starts from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009.
Real Central Provident Fund wealth or balances (CPF): it is defined as logarithm of
aggregated CPF Amount due to members, deflated by CPI. It is taken as the measure
of wealth accumulated in the CPF. The series are provided by Singapore Central
Provident Fund Board. I obtain the data from Singapore Department of Statistics and
starts from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009. In the model, CPF is viewed as an asset class which
29
might affect the consumption growth.
The logarithmic forms of above variables are plotted in Figure 4. As indicated by Phang
(2004), consumption and income exhibit unit roots in levels. Table 1 shows the results of
standard Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root test for stationarity6 for log of real
consumption, income, stock price, public housing price and private housing price, as well
as the first difference of the log of real consumption, income, stock price, public housing
price and private housing price. Consistent with Phang (2004) and Edelstein and Lum
(2004), the results show that the consumption and income exhibit unit roots in levels but
first difference of these variables are stationary. I further plot the first difference of the
log of real consumption, income, stock price, public house price and private house price
2
4
6
8
10
12
in Figure 5 and Figure 6.
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
newdate
Log consumption
Log stock wealth
Log private wealth
2000q1
2005q1
2010q1
Log income
Log public wealth
Log CPF
Figure 4. Variables in logarithm
6
The number of lags is set to be 0. The results remain the same even if it is set to be 3.
30
.4
.2
0
-.2
-.4
-.6
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
newdate
△ consumption
△ stock
2000q1
2005q1
2010q1
△ income
-.2
-.1
0
.1
.2
.3
Figure 5. Consumption growth, income growth and stock growth
1975q1
1980q1
1985q1
1990q1
1995q1
newdate
△ cpf
△ public
2000q1
2005q1
2010q1
△ private
Figure 6. CPF growth, Private housing price growth and Public housing price growth
Table 1: ADF Test and summary statistics
Dickey Fuller
Start date
End date
Q2:1975
Q4:2009
139
Std.
Mean
Test(p-value)
△C
Reject unit
Obs
0.0000
root(95%)
YES
Min
Max
-0.066
0.080
Dev.
0.014
0.033
31
C
Q1:1975
Q4:2009
140
0.7931
NO
9.128
0.593
8.092
10.035
△Y
Q2:1975
Q4:2009
139
0.0000
YES
0.016
0.018
-0.041
0.057
Y
Q1:1975
Q4:2009
140
0.3579
NO
9.898
0.694
8.662
10.969
△Sto
Q2:1975
Q4:2009
139
0.0000
YES
0.014
0.140
-0.539
0.370
Sto
Q1:1975
Q4:2009
140
0.4154
NO
6.566
0.600
5.166
7.660
△Pub
Q2:1990
Q4:2009
79
0.0019
YES
0.019
0.050
-0.074
0.271
pub
Q1:1990
Q4:2009
80
0.1898
NO
4.476
0.436
3.515
5.016
△Pri
Q2:1975
Q4:2009
139
0.0000
YES
0.019
0.058
-0.152
0.240
Pri
Q1:1975
Q4:2009
140
0.2335
NO
4.177
0.821
2.518
5.201
△CPF
Q2:1975
Q4:2009
139
0.0001
YES
0.030
0.021
-0.061
0.074
CPF
Q1:1975
Q4:2009
140
0.0000
YES
10.513
1.128
7.880
12.025
5.2 Methodology
Different econometric strategies have been applied in various papers on wealth effects.
For example, Phang (2004) uses OLS and finds no significant impact of housing prices on
aggregate consumption. Using a co-integration specification, Ng (2002) finds positive
32
short run and negative long run housing price effects on aggregate consumption.
However, this paper follows Edelstein and Lum (2004) and uses the vector-autoregressive
model for several reasons. First, Vector autoregression models (VARs) can statistically
estimate the dynamic interactions between a set of variables without imposing strong
theoretical assumptions. Therefore, VARs have the advantage of capturing average past
experience in a less restricted way. Second, the Error Correction Model cannot be applied
as the data show no evidence of long run cointegration between income and consumption.
This is consistent with the finding by Abeysinghe and Choy (2004) and may be the result
of the insufficient sample size for the series of data to exhibit equilibrium. Third, there is
no precise time series specification or structural form for the relationship between and
among many of our variables, though the Permanent Income Hypothesis provides some
insights on the relationship between consumption and wealth.
I estimate the unrestricted parameters of the VAR by ordinary least squares (OLS).
Taking the first differences of C,Y, pri, pub, sto, cpf, a lag order of 1 is selected according
to the Akaike Information Criterion. However, as the private housing index and the public
resale price index are highly correlated, with a correlation of 0.9037, VAR using △C, △
Y, △ pri, △sto, △cpf, and △C, △Y, △pub, △sto, △cpf, are applied separately. Then,
I use the estimated VAR in Eq. (4.8) to examine the response of the aggregate
consumption to random shocks in the different wealth variables. These impulse response
functions (IRFs) map out the dynamic response path of a variable due to a one-period
standard deviation shock to another variable.
Two-step Least Square (2SLS) Regressions are also run as Robustness Tests for the
33
above results. Following Calomiris et al. (2009), lags of consumption are taken as
instruments. The three Robustness Tests take Ct 2 , Ct 2 and Ct 3 , and Ct 2 ,
Ct 3
and
Ct 4 as instruments respectively.
5.3 Empirical results
5.3.1 Private housing wealth impact on consumption
Table 2 gives the results when using C, Y, pri, sto, cpf as variables in the regression.
Stock wealth effects are positively significant, and a one dollar gain from stock will lead
to an increase of 4 cents in consumption. However, there is no evidence of private
housing wealth effects, suggesting that long-run investment story is more suitable for
Singapore market.
The net wealth effect of the CPF is not significant. Moreover, it has little impact on
private housing price. This result can be explained by the fact that private housing owners
do not rely on CPF when they making investment decisions. In public housing wealth
effect part, I will further discuss why CPF have insignificant effect on private housing
price but significant effect on public housing. The results in Table 2 also show that stock
market has significant effect on aggregate consumption. This result is consistent with
Benjamin et al. (2004). However, most of the existing studies on Singapore consumption
fail to take into account the stock wealth effects.
The results show that in the regression with CPFt , R square is as high as 0.85. One
concern of such a high R square is that first difference of the log of CPF may be a unit
34
root process, which is however rejected by the results of ADF Test shown in Table 1.
Although it may not fully rule out the possibility that first difference of the log of CPF is
non-stationary, it should at least alleviate our concerns about spurious regression.
Therefore, the high R square could be due to the high correlation between leads and lags,
demonstrated by the fact that the coefficient of CPFt 1 is as high as 0.873 in the
regression of CPFt .
Table 2: VAR estimation results for Q1:1975 to Q4:2009, using C,Y, pri, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
prit
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.3313***
0.0874*
-0.2347**
0.2075**
0.1271***
(-4.15)
(1.95)
(-0.17)
(2.16)
(3.59)
Yt 1
0.7897***
0.2371***
0.1409
0.1288
-0.02453
(5.08)
(2.72)
(0.02)
(0.69)
(0.36)
stot 1
0.04106**
0.0354***
0.05245
0.1281***
-0.008042
(2.06)
(3.16)
(0.58)
(5.34)
(-0.91)
prit 1
-0.01517
0.01033
0.0588
0.5586***
-0.00736
(0.03)
(0.37)
(0.26)
(9.38)
(-0.34)
CPFt 1
0.03978
0.2551***
0.5339
0.1283
0.873***
(0.45)
(5.15)
(1.34)
(1.21)
(22.29)
0.2965
0.4926
0.0313
0.6448
0.8590
R sq
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Table 3: Comparison of private housing effects on consumption when the CPF is included
or excluded
Ct
Ct 1
Yt 1
(1)
Ct
(2)
-0.3313***
-0.3321***
(-4.15)
(-4.16)
0.7897***
0.8244***
35
(5.08)
(6.11)
stot 1
0.04106**
0.03990**
(2.06)
(2.06)
prit 1
-0.01517
0.01299
(0.03)
(0.26)
CPFt 1
0.03978
(0.45)
R sq
0.2965
0.2955
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Table 3 further compares the private housing effects on consumption when the CPF is
included or excluded from the regression, and there are no significant wealth effects in
both cases. Table 4 shows the result of 2SLS Regressions using different lags of
consumption as instruments. The private housing wealth effects remain insignificant. The
CPF does not have significant wealth effects either.
Table 4: 2SLS Regression results using IV and C,Y, pri, sto, cpf
Ct
Regression(1)
Regression(2) Regression(3)
Yt
1.0055**
1.0584**
0.8609**
stot
0.03838
0.02007
0.01915
prit
0.02082
-0.0145
-0.00354
CPFt
-0.118
-0.1148
-0.05556
Ct 2 as IV
Yes
Ct 2 , Ct 3
Ct 2
,
as IV
Ct 3
and
Yes
Yes
36
Ct 4 as IV
5.3.2 Private housing wealth impact on consumption in different sub-periods
One concern of the previous test is that there might be structural change in the
relationship between wealth and consumption. To address this potential problem,
following Edelstein and Lum (2004), this paper divides the whole sample into two subsample periods using the Asian financial crisis in 1997 as break point. It is reasonable to
pick the Asian financial crisis as break point. First of all, the Asian financial crisis
resulted in a sharp decrease of GDP growth. Such negative impact might change people‟s
expectation of future income and thus affect their consumption choice. Moreover, regime
shifts also occurred in the private housing sector. The government had been undertaking
cooling measures to curb speculation prior to financial crisis, but started to introduce
expansionary private housing policies in November 1997. For example, quantum for
private residential units was to be increased by 1000 to 7000 units in early 1997. However,
this was subsequently reduced to 5000 units in November 1997. Project completion
period for projects where units had not been launched for sale was extended to 8 years
subject to the payment of a premium of 5% of the land price per year of extension.
Moreover, vendor of a private housing unit no longer needs to pay stamp duty surcharge.
Therefore, it is likely to capture the effects of regime shifts using Asian financial crisis as
break point.
I estimate Eq. (4.8) over two sub-periods, from Q1:1975 to Q2:1997 and from Q1:1975 to
Q4:2009, and report the results in Tables 5 and 6 respectively. The results show that
housing market impact on consumption is not statistically important, which are consistent
37
with Edelstein and Lum (2004). However, there is a structural change in stock wealthconsumption relationship. During the first sub-period, shock to stock wealth does not
have significant effects on consumption. However, it is observed that stock wealth effects
become more pronounced in the second sub-period.7
Table 5: VAR estimation results for Q1:1975 to Q2:1997 using C,Y, pri, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
prit
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.373***
0.087**
0.048
0.217*
0.172***
(-3.87)
(2.00)
(0.12)
(1.90)
(3.77)
Yt 1
0.948***
0.319***
-0.471
0.106
0.109
(4.14)
(3.08)
(-0.51)
(0.39)
(1.00)
0.003
0.012
-0.0517
0.085***
-0.009
(0.12)
(0.93)
(-0.47)
(2.61)
(-0.72)
-0.009
0.055*
0.298
0.627***
-0.002
(-0.14)
(1.85)
(1.12)
(8.00)
(-0.05)
0.192***
0.578
0.117
0.831***
(-0.11)
(3.86)
(1.31)
(0.90)
(15.93)
0.2955
0.6122
0.0511
0.6393
stot 1
prit 1
CPFt 1-0.012
R sq
0.8590
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Table 6: VAR estimation results for Q3:1997 to Q4:2009 using C,Y, pri, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
prit
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.219
0.118
-0.384
0.216
-0.0179
(-1.57)
(1.07)
(-0.46)
(1.23)
(-0.41)
Yt 1
0.498***
0.111
0.780
0.150
0.0188
(2.59)
(0.74)
(0.68)
(0.62)
(0.31)
7
These results remain the same even if I exclude the samples for Q3:2008 to Q4: 2009.
38
stot 1
0.097***
0.071***
0.197
0.193***
-0.003
(3.82)
(3.56)
(1.30)
(6.10)
(-0.41)
prit 1
-0.0143
-0.063
-0.270
0.416***
-0.007
(-0.20)
(-1.10)
(-0.62)
(4.58)
(-0.30)
CPFt 1
0.221
0.384**
0.511
-0.114
0.907***
(1.00)
(2.23)
(0.39)
(-0.41)
(13.18)
0.4209
0.4075
0.0637
0.7107
0.8170
R sq
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
5.3.3 Impulse response analysis of private housing wealth impact on consumption
The next step in the VAR models is to introduce shocks to the error terms in Eq. (4.8). In
effect, a shock imposes a change in consumption. By tracking the consequent changes in
aggregate consumption growth, the impulse response analysis help to identify the causal
effect of housing wealth on consumption while holding all other variables constant.
Figures 7, 8 and 9 present the impulse response functions (IRF) for whole sample period,
and the two sub-periods, respectively.
Response to Cholesky one S.D innovation
Income ->Consumption
Stock market->Consumption
39
Private housing ->Consumption
CPF->Consumption
Figure 7. Impulse response analyses for Q1:1975 to Q4:2009
Response to Cholesky one S.D innovation
Income ->Consumption
Stock market->Consumption
Private housing ->Consumption
CPF->Consumption
Figure 8. Impulse response analyses for Q1:1975 to Q2:1997
40
Response to Cholesky one S.D innovation
Income ->Consumption
Stock market->Consumption
Private housing ->Consumption
CPF->Consumption
Figure 9. Impulse response analyses for Q3:1997 to Q4:2009
The results show that consumption significantly responds to unanticipated changes in
income. However, all results show that the impact of private house wealth is negative but
insignificant. The impact of stock market changes on consumption is not significant in
first sub-sample period but becomes positive and significant in second sub-sample period.
Further, I compute the short run response of consumption to the private housing wealth,
stock market and CPF. The results are reported in Table 7.
41
According to Table 7, it takes 5 to 6 quarters for a housing wealth shock to die out (less
than 0.001) and 4 to 6 quarters for a stock market shock to die out. However, it takes 13
to 18 quarters for a CPF shock to die out. If I redefine die out time as the time when the
value of response equals to 0.00001, it takes 46 quarters for a housing wealth shock to die
out in first sub-period and 64 quarters in the second sub-period. In terms of shock on CPF,
it takes 59 quarters to die out in first sub-period and 81 quarters in the second sub-period.
These results indicate that the effects from CPF shocks are much more persistent. One
possible explanation is that ownership of CPF is much more widespread compared to
housing wealth or stock wealth. In the event of housing wealth or stock price shock, only
the owners are likely to be affected. However, the positive shock of CPF will lead to
higher future income, especially after retirement, and expected life-long resources are
enhanced. In an unreported table, I also find that the effects of CPF shocks are more
persistent than those of income shocks. 8 This exactly proves that CPF is considered
nonhuman wealth or permanent income by households, and the empirical study gives that
MPC of CPF is highest among all nonhuman wealth. This result sheds light on policy
making. However, most of the existing studies on Singapore housing market tend to
ignore this important role, while this study helps to fill in this important gap.
The impulse response analysis provides insights on the housing wealth-consumption
relationship in the Singapore and these results appear to be consistent in different sample
periods. These results are also consistent with Phang (2004) and Edelstein and Lum (2004)
who find that private housing wealth does not significantly affect consumption. Moreover,
these results further demonstrate that stock market significantly affect consumption after
8
Figure 7, 8 and 9 also indicate this conclusion.
42
Asian financial crisis. This will shed light on future study stock market-consumption
relationship and how such link change after Asian financial crisis. Last but not least, my
findings show that the unexpected shock on CPF will result in a more persistent impact
on consumption than the housing wealth shock does.
Table 7: Impulse response functions of aggregate consumption to shocks in private house
wealth, stock market and CPF.
Q1:1975-Q2:1997
Private
Time
Q3:1997-Q4:2009
housing
Private
Stock Index
CPF
price
housing
Stock Index
CPF
price
1
-0.00034
0.003351
-0.00019
-0.00076
0.01312
0.00164
2
0.00210
0.002308
0.00264
-0.00233
0.00315
0.00292
3
0.00128
0.001215
0.00217
-0.00172
-0.00056
0.00298
4
0.00136
0.000921
0.00248
-0.00123
-0.00161
0.00283
5
0.00102
0.000746
0.00226
-0.00080
-0.00130
0.00251
6
0.00092
0.000656
0.00220
-0.00059
-0.00087
0.00223
7
0.00077
0.000596
0.00205
-0.00049
-0.00054
0.00198
8
0.00068
0.000549
0.00193
-0.00044
-0.00038
0.00177
9
0.00060
0.000509
0.00180
-0.00040
-0.00031
0.00160
10
0.00055
0.000473
0.00169
-0.00037
-0.00027
0.00144
11
0.00049
0.000441
0.00157
-0.00034
-0.00025
0.00130
12
0.00045
0.00041
0.00146
-0.00031
-0.00023
0.00117
13
0.00041
0.000382
0.00136
-0.00028
-0.00021
0.00106
14
0.00038
0.000356
0.00127
-0.00025
-0.00019
0.00096
15
0.00035
0.000332
0.00118
-0.00023
-0.00018
0.00086
16
0.00033
0.000309
0.00110
-0.00020
-0.00016
0.00078
17
0.00030
0.000288
0.00102
-0.00018
-0.00014
0.00070
18
0.00028
0.000268
0.00095
-0.00017
-0.00013
0.00063
19
0.00026
0.00025
0.00088
-0.00015
-0.00012
0.00057
20
0.00024
0.000233
0.00082
-0.00014
-0.00011
0.00052
43
5.3.4 Public housing wealth impact on consumption
In the previous section, I comprehensively study the effect of private housing wealth on
consumption. Next, we further study the impact of public housing wealth. Table 8 shows
the results when using C, Y, pub, sto, cpf as variables in the regression. Similar to the
previous regression, the stock wealth effects are highly significant. Public housing and the
CPF do not have significant wealth effects. Though the CPF plays a role in pushing up
public resale prices, it does not alter the insignificance of public housing wealth effects
according to Table 9.
CPF has positive and significant impact on public housing, though its impact on private
housing is found to be limited. This result can be explained by the fact that private
housing owners do not rely on the monies in their CPF accounts when they are
purchasing houses. However, public housing owners have comparatively lower incomes,
thus are more likely to rely on CPF.
Table 8: VAR estimation results for Q1:1990 to Q4:2009, using C,Y, pub, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
pubt
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.2051*
0.08708
-0.01963
0.0870
0.0559
(-1.82)
(1.05)
(-0.03)
(0.54)
(0.79)
Yt 1
0.5553***
0.1357
0.0641
-0.0918
0.1318
(3.38)
(1.12)
(0.07)
(-0.39)
(1.28)
stot 1
0.0653***
0.0570***
0.1282
0.0622**
-0.0048
(2.95)
(3.49)
(1.07)
(1.97)
(-0.35)
pubt 1
0.076
0.0427
0.206
0.6138***
-0.0393
(1.29)
(0.98)
(0.65)
(7.28)
(-1.06)
CPFt 1
0.0808
0.3905***
0.626
0.4954**
0.6751***
44
R sq
(0.57)
(3.17)
(0.81)
(2.43)
(7.53)
0.3572
0.4552
0.0454
0.5611
0.5616
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Table 9: Comparison of coefficient of Ct , with or without CPF
Ct
(1)
Ct
(2)
Ct 1
-0.2051*
-0.2054*
(-1.82)
(-1.82)
Yt 1
0.5553***
0.5910***
(3.38)
(3.88)
stot 1
0.06533***
0.0629***
(2.95)
(2.89)
pubt 1
0.0760
0.0833
(1.29)
(1.44)
CPFt 1
0.0808
R sq
(0.57)
0.3572
0.3545
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
5.3.5 Public housing wealth impact on consumption in different sub-periods
Next, I further divide the whole sample into two sub-samples using Asian financial crisis
as breakpoint and estimate Eq. (4.8) over two sub-periods. The results are reported in
Tables 10 and 11 respectively. In Tables 10 and 11, the results show that public housing
impact on consumption is not statistically significant, which are consistent with the
findings of Edelstein and Lum (2004). We also find that there is a structural change in
stock market-consumption relationship, consistent with the results in Table 4 and 5 shown
45
previously.
Table 10: VAR estimation results for Q1:1975 to Q2:1997, using C,Y, pub, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
pubt
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.0755
0.126
1.181
0.370
0.194
(-0.42)
(1.04)
(1.52)
(0.90)
(1.21)
Yt 1
0.757**
0.257
-1.856
-0.178
0.697**
(2.43)
(1.22)
(-1.37)
(-0.25)
(2.50)
stot 1
-0.0482
0.0246
-0.110
0.0786
-0.0154
(-1.11)
(0.84)
(-0.58)
(0.79)
(-0.40)
pubt 1
0.0836
0.0683
0.596*
0.524***
-0.114*
(1.14)
(1.37)
(1.88)
(3.10)
(-1.75)
-0.188
0.264**
0.500
0.771*
0.354**
(-0.98)
(2.03)
(0.60)
(1.75)
(2.07)
0.6175
0.1928
0.5727
0.5850
CPFt 1
R sq
0.3942
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Table 11: VAR estimation results for Q3:1997 to Q4:2009, using C,Y, pub, sto, cpf
Ct
Yt
stot
pubt
CPFt
Ct 1
-0.246
0.098
-0.501
-0.085
-0.0251
(-1.81)
(0.90)
(-0.61)
(-0.85)
(-0.58)
Yt 1
0.485***
0.078
0.627
0.0455
0.0140
(2.61)
(0.52)
(0.56)
(0.33)
(0.24)
stot 1
0.094***
0.067***
0.177
0.061***
-0.00416
(3.83)
(3.40)
(1.19)
(3.38)
(-0.54)
pubt 1
0.131
-0.045
0.005
0.733***
0.0260
(1.14)
(-0.48)
(0.01)
(8.59)
(0.71)
0.226
0.438***
0.734
0.122
0.912***
(1.08)
(2.62)
(0.58)
(0.79)
(13.81)
CPFt 1
46
R sq
0.3572
0.4552
0.0454
0.5611
0.5616
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
Another finding of the empirical study is that public housing wealth effects started to be
significant since 2003 although there are no significant housing wealth effects for the
whole sample period. Taking the sub-sample of Q1:2003-Q4:2009, wealth effects of
public housing become marginally significant, and the coefficient is twice as much as that
of stocks, shown in Table 12. The reason for such a change may be that the restrictions on
public housing were loosened so that households are able to reap the return from the
public resale market easily since 2003. For example, the required cash outlay for HDB
purchases was reduced to 5% of the total housing value. The MOP for resale flat buyers
who take an HDB concessionary loan and a bank loan was shortened to 2.5 years and 1
year respectively. Households may find the public resale units suitable for investment
and the owners of the HDB flats may not aim to hold the units for long-term occupancy.
Therefore, direct wealth effects become significant.
Most importantly, due to the relaxation of subletting rules, homeowners do not need to
sell out houses to gain from housing appreciation, but they can enhance budgets by
renting out rooms. The extra stream of income can be used to increase consumption,
especially when rental rates increase. Recently the rental market has become quite active
as more foreign workers, international students or expatriates move to Singapore. Some
of them turn to the rental market and push up the rentals. The higher rentals further
reduce homeowners‟ incentive to sell their flats. The demand for resale flats, from the
immigrants who intend to buy, remains strong. Given the tightened supply of and
expanded demand for public resale housing, the prices go up tremendously.
47
Table 12: VAR estimation results for Q1:2003 to Q4:2009, using C,Y, pub, sto
Ct
Yt
stot
pubt
Ct 1
-0.5648***
-0.03441
-1.1288
-0.2059*
(--3.40)
(-0.2)
(-1.50)
(-1.68)
Yt 1
0.4333**
0.00694
1.342
0.1922
(2.12)
(0.03)
(1.45)
(1.28)
stot 1
0.14***
0.1279**
0.4415**
0.06133**
(3.39)
(3.03)
(2.36)
(2.01)
pubt 1
0.2869*
0.08088
-1.115
0.8049***
(1.78)
(0.49)
(-1.53)
(6.77)
0.5128
0.3278
0.3713
0.6727
R sq
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
5.3.6 Impulse response analysis of public housing wealth impact on consumption
I further conduct impulse response analysis based on above VAR results. Figure 10
presents the IRFs for whole sample period, the first and second sub-periods. The results
show that consumption positively responds to unanticipated changes in public housing.
Compared with private house wealth, public housing wealth affects consumption
positively and more profoundly, especially during the 2003 and 2009 sample period.
48
Response to Cholesky one S.D innovation
(Public housing wealth->Consumption)
Q1:1975 to Q4:2009
Q3:1997 to Q4:2009
Q1:1975 to Q2:1997
Q1:2003 to Q4:2009
Figure 10. Impulse response analyses for four sub-sample periods
5.3.7 Asymmetric wealth effects of private housing on consumption
As explained in the previous section, the RPPI and RPI are used as proxies of housing
wealth in two regressions separately, due to the fact that the correlation between private
49
housing and public resale housing price changes or levels is as high as 0.9037. The results
in both regressions show that overall housing wealth effects are insignificant. There is no
evidence of private or public housing wealth effects for the whole sample. One possible
explanation is that this econometric study uses aggregate data, and therefore, the effects
of housing price appreciation on buyers and sellers are offset at the aggregate level.
However, there is evidence of asymmetric wealth effects of private housing. The increase
in private housing wealth significantly increase aggregate consumption but a decrease has
insignificant effects on consumption, shown in Table 13. There are several explanations
for the asymmetry. When private housing prices increase, the homeowners tend to view
their private units as investment assets and are eager to reap the return from housing price
appreciation. The direct wealth effects are significant and they will increase the
consumption. However, during housing price depreciation, the homeowners may tend to
treat the private housing as for self-occupation rather than for investment, and stay as in
the current units so that they will not lose in the depreciation. Meanwhile, the buyers will
tend to watch the market rather than become the owner of the housing wealth, as they
expect the prices to further dip in the future. Their consumption would not be sacrificed
for home purchase, and the perceived wealth would not change. 9
Table 13: VAR estimation results for Q1:1975 to Q4:2009, desegregating positive and
negative private housing change
Ct 1
Ct
Yt
stot
prit (+)
prit (-) CPFt
-0.3335***
0.0939*
0.0034
1.115
-0.3733
0.1234***
(-3.80)
(1.82)
(0.01)
(2.16)
(-0.38)
(2.77)
9
I also conduct the same test for public housing. The results show no asymmetric effect of public housing wealth.
These results further demonstrate that the asymmetric effects are due to the different perspectives on housing. Lowerincome people are more likely to treat housing as for self-occupation rather than for investment.
50
Yt 1
0.5657***
0.0529
0.1953
3.626*
-2.854
-0.03661
(3.34)
(0.53)
(0.25)
(1.70)
(-1.49)
(0.43)
stot 1
0.05261**
0.0435***
0.0444
0.5441**
-0.4626*
-0.0004
(2.41)
(3.38)
(0.43)
(1.97)
(-1.88)
(-0.04)
prit 1 (+)
0.0125**
0.0107***
-0.001
0.6975***
0.1719**
0.0039
(2.30)
(3.35)
(-0.04)
(10.19)
(2.18)
(1.41)
prit 1 (-)
0.0068
0.0054*
-0.0279
0.0698
0.829***
0.0056**
(1.27)
(1.72)
(-1.11)
(1.03)
(13.76)
(2.05)
-0.1193
0.1311***
0.726
1.486
0.2929
0.791***
(1.06)
(1.98)
(1.38)
(1.05)
(0.23)
(13.85)
0.4891
0.5839
0.3471
0.9193
0.8296
0.9548
CPFt 1
R sq
Note: t statistics are in ( ). *** denotes 1% significance, ** denotes 5% significance, and
* denotes 10% significance.
6. Conclusion
This paper aims to explore whether wealth effects are significant for private housing and
public housing in Singapore. The net CPF wealth effect is also examined and discussed
extensively in the study.
Using the RPPI from Q1:1975 to Q4:2009 and RPI from Q1:1990 to Q4:2009, there are no
significant public or private housing wealth effects found for the respective whole sample.
Using Asian Financial Crisis in 1997 as a break point, the main results for the two subperiods are the same as those in full sample regression for both public and private housing.
These findings support Thaler (1990)‟s mental account theory, suggesting that most
Singaporeans regard properties as for long term saving. However, it is observed that there
was a structural change in public housing wealth effects in 2003, when a series of policies
51
were introduced to boost the public housing market. One of the possible explanations is that
such policies, such as the reduction in MOP and the ease of financing of the HDB flats,
may alter the households‟ perception of the public housing. They may tend to view the
public units suitable for speculation, and the direct wealth effects start to be significant. The
permission to sublet is considered as another explanation for the significant public housing
wealth effects after 2003. The rental income is likely to be regarded current, and channeled
into consumption.
Additionally, this paper suggests that private housing exhibits asymmetric wealth effects.
Consumption responds positively to price increase in private housing but remains
unchanged during price decrease.
Stock wealth effects, though ignored by previous literature in Singapore, are found to be
significant in Q3:1997 to Q4:2009, which may be attributed to the government‟s
encouragement to invest in shares via CPFIS so that the Singaporean households‟
participation in stock market is deepened. With the recent volatility in stock market,
households are likely to reap return which is then channeled to consumption.
This paper also extensively examines the roles of the balances in CPF accounts. In all
regressions, there are no statistically significant CPF wealth effects. However, in the
impulse response analysis, the results show that the impacts of CPF shocks on consumption
are more persistent than those of private or public housing wealth. Moreover, there is no
strong evidence observed that the CPF directly pushes up private housing price though it
does result in the increase in public resale housing prices.
52
Bibliography
Abeysinghe, T. & Choy, K. M. (2004). The aggregate consumption puzzle in Singapore.
Journal of Asian Economics, 15, 563–578.
Ando, A. & Modigliani, F. (1963). The „Life-Cycle‟ hypothesis of savings: aggregate
implications and tests. American Economic Review, 53, 55-84.
Asher, M. G. (1999), Pension scheme in Singapore: case study and implications.
Economic and Political Weekly, 34, 3687-3694.
Banks, J. , Blundell, R. & Tanner, S. (1998) Is There a Retirement-Savings Puzzle?
American Economic Review 88(4), 769–88.
Bardhan, A. D., Datta, R., Edelstein, R. H., & Lum, S. K. (2003). A tale of two sectors:
upward mobility and the private housing market in Singapore. Journal of Housing
Economics, 12, 83-105.
Bernanke, Ben S. (1985). Adjustment Costs, Durables and Aggregate Consumption.
Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 41-68.
Benjamin, J., Chinloy, P., and Jud, D. (2004). Real Estate versus Financial Wealth in
Consumption. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29, 341–354.
Bhatia, K. B. (1987). Real Estate Assets and Consumer Spending. Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 102, 437-444.
Bilson, John EO. (1980). The Rational Expectations Approach to the Consumption
Function: A Multi-Country Study. European Economic Review 13, 273-299.
Buiter, W. H. (2008). Housing wealth isn't wealth. NBER Working Paper14204.
Calomiris, C. W., Longhofer S. D. & Miles, W. (2009). The (mythical?) housing wealth
effect. NBER Working Paper 15075.
Campbell, J. Y. & Deaton, A. (1989). Why is Consumption So Smooth? Review of
Economic Studies 56, 357-374.
Campbell, J. Y. & Mankiw, N. G. (1989). Permanent income, current income, and
consumption. In Blanchard, O. J. & Fisher, S., eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.
Campbell, J. Y. & Cocco, J. F. (2007). How do house prices affect consumption?
evidence from micro data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(3), 591-621.
Carroll, C. D. (1997). Buffer-stock saving and the life-cycle/permanent income
hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(1), 1–55.
Case, K. E. (1992). The real estate cycle and the economy: consequences of the
massachusetts boom of 1984-1987. Urban Studies, 29, 171-183.
53
Case, K. E., Quigley, J. M., and Shiller, R. J. (2005). Comparing wealth effects: the stock
market versus the housing market. Advances in Macroeconomics, 5(1), 1-34.
Chia, N. C. & Tsui, K. C. (2009). Monetizing housing equity to generate retirement
incomes. SCAPE Policy Research Working Paper Series .
Chua, B. H. (1996). Private ownership of public housing in Singapore. Asia Research
Centre, Murdoch University, Working paper, 63, 1-27.
Clarida, R. (1991). Aggregate Stochastic Implications of the Life-Cycle Hypothesis.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 851-867.
Dawson, J., DeJuan, J., Seater, J. & Stephenson, E. F. (2001). Economic Information
versus Quality Variation in Cross-Country Data. Canadian Journal of Economics 34,
988-1009.
Dynan, K. E. & Maki, D. M. (2001). Does stock market wealth matter for consumption?
Finance and Economics Discussion Series, FEDS Discussion Paper No. 2001-23.
Deaton, A. (1991). Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(5), 1221–1248.
Deaton, A. (1992). Understanding consumption. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Duesenberry, J.S. (1948). Income - Consumption Relations and Their Implications.
Income, Employment and Public Policy, New York: W.W.Norton & Company, Inc.
Edelstein, R. H. & Lum, S. K. (2004). House prices, wealth effects, and the Singapore
macroeconomy. Journal of Housing Economics, 13, 342–367.
Elliott, J. W. (1980). Wealth and wealth proxies in a permanent income model. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 95, 509-535.
Engelhardt, G. V. (1996). House prices and home owner saving behavior. Regional
Science and Urban Economics, 26, 313–336.
Engelhardt, G. V. (1994). House prices and the decision to save for down payments.
Journal of Urban Economics, 36, 209-237.
Flavin, M. (1981). The Adjustment of Consumption to Changing expectations about
Future Income. Journal of Political Economy 89, 974-1009.
Friedman, M. (1957). The Permanent Income Hypothesis: Comment. American Economic
Review, 48, 990-91.
Gourinchas, P.-O. & Parker, J.A. (2002). Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica
70, 47–89.
Hall, R. E. (1978). Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle-Permanent Income
Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence. Joumal of Political Economy 86, 971-987.
54
Hall, R. E. & Mishkin, F. S. (1982). The Sensitivity of Consumption to Transitory
Income: Estimates from Panel Data on Households. Econometrica 50 (2), 461-481.
Hayashi, F. (1982). The Permanent Income Hypothesis: Estimation and Testing by
Instrumental Variables. Journal of Political Economy 90, 895-916.
Hoynes, H. W. & McFadden, D. L. (1997). The impact of demographics on housing and
nonhousing wealth in the United States. In Hurd, M. D. & Yashiro, N, eds., The
Economic Effects of Aging in the United States and Japan, Chicago: University of
Chicago Press for NBER, 153-194.
Keynes, J.M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money London:
Macmillan.
Kim, C. (1996). Measuring Deviations from the Permanent Income Hypothesis.
International Economic Review 37(1), 205-225.
Kuznets, S. (1946). National Income: A Summary of Findings New York: NBER, 1946.
Levin, L. (1998). Are assets fungible? Testing the behavioral theory of life-cycle savings.
Journal of Economic Organization and Behavior, 36, 59-83.
Lum, S. K. (2002). Market fundamentals, public policy and private gain: house price
dynamics in Singapore”, Journal of Property Research, 19(2), 121-143.
Lustig, H. & Nieuwerburg, S. V. (2010). How much does household collateral constrain
regional risk sharing? Review of Economic Dynamics, 13, 265-294.
Mankiw, N. G. & Shapiro, M. D. (1985). Trends, Random Walks, and Tests of the
Permanent Income Hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 65-174.
Merton, R.C. (1971). Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous-time
model. Journal of Economic Theory 3, 373-413.
Modigliani, F. & Brumberg R. H. (1955). Utility analysis and the consumption function:
an interpretation of cross-section data. Post-Keynesian Economics, New Brunswick, NJ.
Rutgers University Press. 388–436.
Modigliani, F. & Brumberg R. H. (1980). Utility analysis and aggregate consumption
functions: an attempt at integration. The Collected Papers of Franco Modigliani: Volume
2, The Life Cycle Hypothesis of Saving. Cambridge, MA. The MIT Press. 128–197.
Muellbauer, J. (1983). Surprises in the consumption function. The Economic Journal 93,
Supplement: Conference Papers, 34-50.
Muellbauer, J. & Murphy, A. (1997). Boom and busts in the UK housing market. The
Economic Journal, 107, 1701-1727.
Muellbauer, J. & Murphy, A. (1990). Is the UK's balance of payments sustainable?
Economic Policy, 348-395.
55
Paiella, M. (2009). The stock market, housing and consumer spending: a survey of the
evidence on wealth effects. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23, 947-973.
Phang, S. Y. (2004). House prices and aggregate consumption: do they move together?
evidence from Singapore. Journal of Housing Economics, 13, 101-119.
Poterba, J. (2000). Stock market wealth and consumption, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 14 (2), 99-118.
Starr-McCluer, M. (1998). Stock market wealth and consumer spending. Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, FEDS Paper No. 98-20.
Sheiner, L. (1995). Housing prices and the savings of renters”, Journal of Urban
Economics, 38, 94-125.
Sinai, T. & Souleles, N. (2005). Owner-occupied housing as a hedge against rent risk.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 763-789.
Skinner, J. (1989). Housing wealth and aggregate saving. Regional Science and Urban
Economics, 19, 305-324.
Skinner, J. (1993). Is housing wealth a sideshow?" NBER Working Papers 4552.
Thaler, R. H. (1990). Saving, fungibility and mental accounts. Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 4, 193-205.
Wang, N. (2006). Generalizing the permanent-income hypothesis: Revisiting Friedman‟s
conjecture on consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 737–752.
Weissenberger, E. (1986). Consumption innovations and income innovations: evidence
from UK and Germany. The Review of Economics and Statistics 68, 1-8.
West, Kenneth D. (1988a). The Insensitivity of Consumption to News About Income.
Journal of Monetary Economics 21, 17-34.
Yoshikawa, H. & Ohtake, F. (1989). An analysis of female labor supply, housing demand,
and the saving rate in Japan,” European Economic Review, 33, 997-1030.
Zeldes. S. P. (1989). Optimal Consumption with Stochastic Income: Deviations from
Certainty Equivalence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 104, 275-298.
56
[...]... Section 1, housing wealth consists of public housing wealth and private housing wealth in the context of Singapore Given the different institutional features, we expect that public housing and private housing mat have different wealth effects 4.2 Private housing wealth effects Hypothesis 1: Private housing wealth effects are significant (insignificant) Private housing may impose significant wealth effects. .. nonhuman wealth Second, it compares the wealth effects of private housing and public housing Most of the previous literature examined only the private housing market without taking the public resale market into account Although Edelstein and Lum (2004) examine the differences between public housing wealth and private housing wealth, take both public and private housing indices as measures of housing wealth. .. in public housing market may also impose structure shocks to wealth effects In sum, the unique institutional features in public housing market may result in distinction between public and private housing wealth effects Therefore, it is essential to examine public and private housing wealth effects separately 25 4.4 CPF wealth effects As a mandatory social pension scheme, the CPF requires working Singaporeans... consumption through the time horizon 4.3 Public housing wealth effects Hypothesis 2: Public housing wealth effects are insignificant (significant) Public housing shares some commons with private housing in that homeowner can gain by selling the flats in the open market and lose by pursuing a high priced flat Nevertheless, public housing market is highly regulated, resulting in a relatively stable price and... unit in the HDB resale market Owners of private housing may also realise gain in housing wealth, by selling their private properties during price hike if they have more than one residential unit, or by selling off higher-value unit and trading down to a lower-value unit in the private housing resale market Nevertheless, on an aggregate basis, public and private housing wealth effects are unclear since... evidence of housing wealth effects Hoynes and McFadden (1997) find that households would hardly change their savings in non -housing assets in response to expectations about capital gains in owner-occupied housing Levin (1998) claims that homeowners do not consume their housing wealth which therefore would not affect their consumption Some skeptics of housing wealth effects believe that housing price... extensively examined According to the PIH and the lifecycle theory, an increase in housing value is likely to lead to an increase in consumption This housing wealth effects can be realised through several channels First, an appreciation in housing value increases the households‟ wealth and thus increases consumption, which is regarded as direct wealth effects Second, households that face binding credit... Edelstein and Lum (2004) conclude that changes in public house prices would significantly and persistently affect aggregate consumption, while there are no significant private housing wealth effects in Singapore These studies, however, have been constrained by the limitations of data as public resale market was first introduced only in 1990 The high 15 multicollinearity of private housing and public housing. .. suitable for long-term investment Apart from the direct housing wealth effects, we also attempt to examine indirect wealth effects, for example, the collateral or balance sheet effects which enable homeowners to pledge their flats as collateral and unlock housing equity for consumption NTUC Income introduced the first RM scheme for private housing in 1998, and to public housing in March 2006 The other... the consumption boom in the United Kingdom in the late 1980s could be attributed to the increase in housing prices as well as financial liberalisation Case (1992) finds substantial consumption increase during the real estate price boom in the late 1980s using aggregate data for New England Skinner (1989) examines the link between housing wealth and consumer expenditure using data on individual households ... public housing wealth and private housing wealth in the context of Singapore Given the different institutional features, we expect that public housing and private housing mat have different wealth. .. 4.3 Public housing wealth effects Hypothesis 2: Public housing wealth effects are insignificant (significant) Public housing shares some commons with private housing in that homeowner can gain... different wealth effects 4.2 Private housing wealth effects Hypothesis 1: Private housing wealth effects are significant (insignificant) Private housing may impose significant wealth effects on consumption