1. Trang chủ
  2. » Luận Văn - Báo Cáo

OPTIMAL CONTEST DESIGN WITH NONLINEAR COSTS

45 141 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Cấu trúc

  • Main body.pdf

    • Introduction

      • Related literature

      • The setting

    • Simultaneous entry

      • Disclosing the number of participants

      • Concealing the number of participants

        • Shortlisting under policy of concealment

      • Policy of disclosure vs. concealment

    • Sequential entry

    • Simultaneous vs. sequential entry

    • Concluding remarks

    • Simultaneous entry

      • Proof of Lemma ??

      • Proof of Lemma ??

Nội dung

OPTIMAL CONTEST DESIGN WITH NONLINEAR COSTS YAP WEIMING (B.Soc.Sci. (Hons.), NUS) A THESIS SUBMITTED FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SOCIAL SCIENCES DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE 2011 Acknowledgements I am indebted to Associate Professor Lu Jingfeng for his continuous guidance and encouragements. I would like to thank him for his patience and gracious supervision. Not only have I learnt the technicalities of the subject from A/P Lu, but also other important values that will be useful for my future career. I am grateful to Associate Professor Shandre M. Thangavelu for giving me many opportunities. I also thank Jiao Qian for many bene…cial discussions, helpful comments and suggestions. All confusions and errors remaining are my own. Lastly, I would like to thank my family, for everything. i Table of Content Section Page 1. Introduction 1 2. Related literature 5 3. The setting 8 4. Simultaneous entry 12 4.1. Disclosing the number of participants 14 4.2. Concealing the number of participants 19 4.2.1. Shortlisting under policy of concealment 25 4.3. Policy of disclosure vs. concealment 29 5. Sequential entry 32 6. Simultaneous vs. sequential entry 34 7. Concluding remarks 35 References 37 Appendix 39 ii Summary This paper studies the optimal contest design that maximises the total expected e¤ort of potential players when they have nonlinear cost functions. The contest organiser aims to induce higher e¤ort by utilising a combination of four instruments: shortlisting of potential players, entry sequence of participants (either simultaneous or sequential), entry fees paid by participants, and disclosure policy of the number of participants, whenever each is applicable. Shortlisted players decide whether to enter a contest upon observing the policy combination of the organiser. We derive and compare the optimal entry fees and optimal disclosure policy under each entry pattern for each number of shortlisted players. We …nd that the concavity (convexity) of the cost function plays a crucial role for the optimal design. Assuming that the contest is optimally designed after each entry pattern, simultaneous entry with a policy of disclosing the number of participants would induce the highest e¤ort when costs are concave. While the optimal number of shortlisted players is not explicitly solved, at the optimum each of them enters stochastically. Alternatively, when costs are convex, the organiser would optimally include all potential players who at the optimum, would enter with certainty. All combinations of entry pattern and disclosure policy induce the same amount of e¤ort at the optimum. iii 1 Introduction Many economic settings can be thought of as being competitive in nature where agents make costly investments in order to win a prize. Examples of competitions frequently studied include internal labour market competitions, political campaigns, and research and development (R&D) contests. Contest theory provides a systematic and consistent framework in which these competitions can be analyzed. A burgeoning literature has taken this approach and tried to incorporate various features of real-world competition into the framework. Some of the features studied are asymmetries among contestants (Cornes and Hartley (2005), Szymanski and Valletti (2005)), multiple prizes (Clark and Riis (1996, 1998), Schweinzer and Segev (2008)), multiple stages (Gradstein and Konrad (1999), Fu and Lu (2010b), Fullerton and McAfee (1999)) and di¤erent mechanisms to select the winner (Atsu Amegashie (2009), Nti (2004)). Clearly, the strategic interactions among contestants depend on these various dimensions in which contests di¤er. The primary focus here is to examine how the contest organizer makes use of a combination of instruments and in particular the order in which participants enter the contest to a¤ect e¤ort. Consider political campaigns, essaywriting competitions and R&D contests. Despite being canonical settings that can be modeled as contests, they primarily di¤er in the sequence players participate. In political campaigns, candidates usually acquire information on the existing number of rivals who have declared their intention to run for elec- 1 tion in a constituency before deciding whether to run.1 Such contests can be analysed by sequential entry. The analysis is quite di¤erent for R&D. Researchers often do not know who are competing for the same patent rights unless the organizer announces a shortlist. Likewise in a drawing competition, students submit their works before a stipulated deadline without knowing the number of other entries. The latter two examples can be analyzed by simultaneous entry, the essential di¤erence between them lies in whether participants observe the number of rivals they are competing against.2 Matters such as how these entry patterns a¤ect e¤ort upon entry are of interest to a contest designer and merit further investigation. Contests Simultaneous Entry No. of rivals is known (disclosed) Sequential Entry (number of participants is always known) No. of rivals is unknown (concealed) Figure 1: Comparison of entry patterns 1 Opposition candidates are afraid of splitting up the opposition votes. Simultaneous entry applies more generally in circumstances where players are large in numbers or separated geographically. 2 2 To avoid complicating the exposition unnecessarily, a convenient assumption is made such that the contests are optimally designed following each entry pattern. The objective is to understand how the contest organizer’s policy measures below directed at maximizing total e¤ort must take into account the circumstances of each entry pattern. An important component of the analysis is to assume players have non-linear costs.3 R&D contests o¤er a simple example. If e¤ort takes the form of monetary outlays, it is reasonable to think of …rms’marginal costs of e¤ort to be linear. Otherwise, if …rms incur high initial marginal cost of capital which becomes relatively lower when the …rm is more established, then it may be more appropriate to think of the e¤ort costs as concave. Other factors that add to the high initial costs include legal restrictions and market development. In contrast, if e¤ort su¤ers from diminishing returns then e¤ort costs may be convex. Subsequent results will be categorized according to whether the players’e¤ort costs are concave or convex. The organizer maximizes total e¤ort by utilizing a combination of three further policy measures, whenever each is applicable. First, the organizer has the ability to shortlist and to invite a subset of potential players to the contest. Perhaps surprisingly, the organizer may not always want all potential players to be involved in the contest. An excessive number of potential players, especially in the case where players have concave costs, destroy the incentives to exert e¤ort. Second, the organizer can collect entry fees from each player who would 3 Even though convex costs may be a more general mathematical representation of a cost function than linear costs, yet it is an implicit assumption that …rms do not innovate or improve their e¢ ciency to reduce their costs of exerting higher e¤ort. Thus in an economic sense, the latter could be thought of as being more general. 3 like to participate in the contest.4 Our analysis lies in the ability of the contest organizer to add the sum of entry fees collected to the …nal prize.5 From an e¤ort-maximizing organizer’s perspective, doing so would create a diversity of possibilities. Higher entry fees discourage participation in the contest which reduces total e¤ort. Contrariwise, entry fees collected add to the size hence attractiveness of the …nal prize, hence encouraging players to exert more e¤ort. As will be shown later, entry fees can be used directly in the case of sequential entry to control the desired number of participants and this eliminates the role of shortlisting in sequential entry. Third, the organizer can also determine whether to disclose the number of participants in a contest. Again, this measure is not relevant in the case of sequential entry because potential players always observe the pre-existing number of participants before deciding whether to participate.6 The decision of whether to disclose the number of participants has important consequences in the simultaneous entry setting though. Numerous studies have provided strong predictions that participants exert higher e¤ort when they do not observe the number of rivals. In fact as Lim and Matros (2009) argued, each participant exerts more e¤ort under some uncertainty about the number of participants than under certainty. However, with the introduction of entry fees into the model, it may seem plausible that an organizer will instead prefer to disclose the number of participants in order for participants to fully inter4 Familiar names for entry fees include registration fees and admission fees. Schemes resembling negative entry fees (subsidies) are often prescribed in R&D contests to encourage participation. However, there may be circumstances where the organiser charges substantial entry fees to ensure that only …nancially healthy …rms participate in the contest. 6 If they are not observed, then this becomes a case of simultaneous entry. 5 4 nalize the e¤ects of entry fees in enhancing the …nal prize. When the number of participants is concealed, participants internalize the e¤ects of the enlarged …nal prize imperfectly and equilibrium e¤ort may be lower. In the next section, I explain how the setup of the model in this paper relates to the rest of the literature and in Section 3 I formally setup the model. Section 4 studies how should contests be designed in a simultaneous entry setting and I show that a policy of disclosure is a dominant strategy for the organizer. Section 5 considers contests where participants enter sequentially using a generalization of the results in Fu and Lu (2010a). Together these results are used to examine and compare the optimal entry pattern that induces the highest e¤ort in Section 6. When costs are concave, simultaneous entry with a policy of disclosure induces the highest e¤ort. Alternatively, when costs are convex, all entry patterns induce the same amount of e¤ort. 2 Related literature This paper integrates separate studies on shortlisting, entry sequences, entry fees and disclosure policy within a single framework. Fu and Lu (2010a) studied a contest in which players sequentially decide whether to participate upon observing the level of entry fees set by the contest organizer. The authors demonstrated that negative entry fees can be used as a form of subsidy to encourage participation by o¤setting players’entry costs. In settings without entry costs, such as the one considered in this paper, the importance of entry fees is less obvious and remains to be justi…ed. Fu and Lu (2010a) takes the 5 view in line with many other studies in the literature that at the optimum, the contest organizer should shortlist a subset of potential players to invite to the contest. This is based on the key assumption that players have a …xed entry cost and linear e¤ort costs. In this paper, by allowing players to have nonlinear e¤ort costs but no …xed entry cost, we propose an alternative result and show that shortlisting is only useful when players have concave costs but not when players have convex costs. Fu and Lu (2010a) developed their analysis in the context of sequential entry. In this paper, we further extend the analysis to simultaneous entry. Simultaneous entry contests have been studied by Myerson and Wärneryd (2006), Lim and Matros (2009), Fu et al. (2010), among others. These studies improved the ‡exibility of contest theory by relaxing the assumption that the number of participants is common knowledge. Instead, the presence of each participant is determined by a common prior probability distribution. The latter two papers speci…cally focused on the binomial distribution and compared whether disclosing or concealing the number of participants induces higher total e¤ort. Lim and Matros (2009) showed that with linear e¤ort costs, disclosing or concealing the number of participants does not a¤ect total e¤ort. By contrast, Fu et al. (2010) showed that the optimal disclosure policy depends on the impact function of the players. Here, we show that the optimal disclosure policy may also depend on the e¤ort cost function of the players. Furthermore, the above-mentioned studies on simultaneous entry typically assume variations in the number of participants depend on exogenous factors. The absence of an instrument to directly in‡uence the number of participants 6 limits our ability to make comparisons in total e¤ort across di¤erent contest designs. This paper improves the simultaneous entry literature along this dimension by allowing the organizer to in‡uence players’ entry decision by using the combination of instruments, including shortlisting and entry fees. This paper is most closely related to Fu et al. (2011) as it applies the same principles of endogenous entry in a simultaneous entry setting where the contest organizer is able to in‡uence the entry probability of the participants by utilizing the instruments on hand. However in Fu et al. (2011) instead of entry fees to be paid to the contest organizer, participants incur entry costs. Such di¤erent formulation of the setting leads to outcomes that are di¤erent from those in this paper. Fu et al. (2011) argued that when players have convex costs, the organizer avoids inviting the full set of potential players as it would increase the competitiveness and reduce the attractiveness of participating in the contest. Here in this paper, by allowing the organizer to collect entry fees and to add the sum collected to the …nal prize, the enhanced …nal prize o¤sets the e¤ect of increased competitiveness and inviting the full set of potential players may increase e¤ort instead. Furthermore, concealing the number of participants no longer dominates disclosing in terms of total e¤ort induced as disclosing the number of participants allows them to internalize the e¤ects of the enhanced …nal prize more e¢ ciently and exert a higher e¤ort. 7 3 The setting There is a set of identical7 and risk-neutral potential players at the start of the contest, represented by M. Denote the size of M by jMj = M . The contest organizer aims to induce the highest total expected e¤ort by utilizing four instruments: shortlisting of potential players, entry sequences of the shortlisted players, entry fees to be paid by the participants, and whether to disclose the number of participants. The organizer …rst decides whether to shortlist a subset of potential players to the contest and also the number to shortlist. He then announces the rule of the contest to the shortlisted players including their entry sequences, entry fees and whether to disclose the number of participants, after which the players would make their entry decisions. There are two types of entry sequences. First, shortlisted players can enter sequentially. In this case, whether to disclose the number of participants is not relevant as the number of participants is automatically revealed and the shortlisted players enter one at a time while observing the number of pre-existing participants. Second, the shortlisted players can also enter simultaneously without observing the entry decisions of others. In this case, the organizer can choose to disclose or conceal the number of participants. Regardless of the entry sequence and disclosure policy, the organizer sets the entry fees which must be paid by each participant. 7 Other studies such as Cornes and Hartley (2005), and Szymanski and Valletti (2005) have accomodated asymmetry among the players. Discrimination, di¤erences in capabilities are various interpretations of asymmetry among the players, where players who exert the same e¤ort have unequal chances of winning the competition. When players di¤er in their capabilities, an e¤ort-maximising contest organiser may choose to make use of multiple prizes to encourage weaker players to exert e¤ort so as to maintain a healthy level of competition. 8 Denote the set of players who chooses to participate in the contest after learning the rules of the contest by N M and the size of N by jN j = N . Henceforth, I call active players participants, that is, players who chose to participate. Denote by F 0 the entry fees charged to each participant of the contest. As a feature of the analysis, the sum of entry fees collected from all participants can be added to the total budget of the organizer to enhance the …nal prize, which would create more incentive for the participants to exert higher e¤ort. The organizer is able to o¤er all the entry fees collected as the …nal prize, in addition to his initial budget B0 . Thus in a contest with N participants, the value associated by the …nal prize is denoted by VN . We can also state the budget constraint of the organizer in terms of the number of participants. De…nition 1 (Feasible Contest). A contest is feasible if for all N , 0 < VN B0 + N F . Suppose an estate conducts a drawing competition and the organizer with an initial budget of $50 charges a registration fee of $2 per student, then the value of the …nal prize should be no more than $90 when there are 20 participants. Participants compete for the …nal prize by exerting a costly e¤ort simultaneously and independently. A typical participant i chooses an e¤ort ei 2 Ei = R+ . Higher e¤ort leads to a higher overall performance that might rely on more than one factor. Organizers evaluate participants based on the relative ranking of this stochastic performance produced by their e¤ort. In the context of a R&D contest, higher e¤ort exerted by the competing …rms 9 may be in the form of increasing investments to purchase advance equipments, hire the best researchers, or devoting more man-hours to the project, all of which could eventually lead to better innovation and a higher quality of the prototype. With some regularity conditions, Fu and Lu (2011) have shown that the winning probabilities of the participants follow the well-adopted Tullock contest models, which is a type of imperfectly discriminatory contest 8 where the participants with the highest e¤ort does not win the contest with certainty, but with the highest probability. To give an illustration of such an evaluation mechanism, consider again the R&D contest where the esthetical design of the prototype plays a role in the outcome. Whether the judges like the design of the prototype depends on their tastes and preferences, which is unobservable. Consequently, it is reasonable to say that the …rm with the highest e¤ort does not win the contest with certainty but only with the highest probability. Formally, the probability Pi : j2N Ej ! [0; 1] that participant i wins the contest satis…es Pi (e jN ) = 8 > > > > < > > > > : 1 if N = 1; 1 N if 8i; j 2 N ; ei = 0 or ei = ej ; j 6= i; P f (ei ) j2N f (ej ) otherwise, where e = (e1 ; : : : ; eN ) represents the vector of participants’e¤ort and (1) P i2N Pi = 1. In case of a tie where participants exert the same e¤ort9 , the tied partic8 The complement of an imperfectly discriminatory contest is a perfectly discriminatory contest, also known as an all-pay contest. Siegel (2009, 2010) derived the equilibrium payo¤s and also provided an algorithm that constructs the unique equilibrium in these contests. 9 For example, all players exert the same e¤ort under a symmetric equilibrium. Because 10 ipants win the prize with equal probabilities. f ( ) is known as the impact function and can be interpreted as a player’s production technology. We typically assume f 0 ( ) > 0 with f (0) = 0. In this paper, we focus on the popularly adopted Tullock contest success function where f (ei ) = eri , where the parameter r > 0 measures the responsiveness of the winning probability to participant i’s increases in e¤ort.10 It is costly for a participant to exert an e¤ort. The cost function usually takes a linear form in the literature. According to Szidarovszky and Okuguchi (2008), in a contest where players have impact function f ( ) and linear effort costs, concavity of f ( ) provides a su¢ cient condition for the existence and uniqueness of a symmetric equilibrium. In this paper, we allow the cost function to be nonlinear. We make the following assumptions. Assumption A1: For all i, the e¤ort cost function of the players takes the form of c (ei ) = ei , where Assumption A2: r > 0. M : M 1 According to A1, the cost function can be concave ( ( < 1) or convex > 1). Later analysis shows that the concavity (convexity) of the cost players are identical, the way these e¤orts translate into winning probability is identical for all players and they value the prize equally so a symmetric equilibrium is a relevant solution concept. 10 When r = 0, e¤ort has no impact on winning probability so the contest becomes a random lottery. When r tends to in…nity, the player with the highest e¤ort wins with certainty and the contest becomes an all-pay auction. For example in a two-player contest, r for every ei > ej ; Pi = eri eri + erj = 1 [1 + (ej ei ) ] ! 1. A standard all-pay r!1 auction is a special type of all-pay contests. 11 function has important implications for the optimal design of the contest. A2 guarantees the existence and uniqueness of a symmetric pure-strategy bidding equilibrium in a standard Tullock contest with N M participants and a single …xed prize (Schweinzer and Segev, 2008). The analysis in Fu et al. (2010) further implies that it is also a su¢ cient condition for a unique symmetric purestrategy bidding equilibrium when N M participants enter with a symmetric non-dengenerate probability into a contest with a single …xed prize. 4 Simultaneous entry In a contest with simultaneous entry, after learning the level of entry fees and …nal prize, the shortlisted potential players decide simultaneously whether they want to participate in the contest. Although stated to be a simultaneous entry contest, it does not necessarily imply that potential players enter simultaneously. It su¢ ces that each potential player chooses his entry decision without knowledge of other players’ decisions. Uncertainty about the number of rivals can be modeled by introducing an element of randomness in the presence of each participant in the contest. The number of participants depends on a common binomial distribution with the endogenous probability of a player participating in a contest denoted by 0 q 1, where q is the probability of success in a binomial distribution that depends on the number of shortlisted players, the entry fees and whether the number of participants is disclosed.11 The timing of the simultaneous entry contest is as follows: 11 The mean number of participants is M q and variance is M q (1 q). 12 Stage 1 Organizer announces a shortlist of potential players. Stage 2 Organizer announces the level of entry fees, the …nal prize scheme and whether he would disclose the number of participants to the set of shortlisted players. Stage 3 After the organizer’s announcement, shortlisted players simultaneously and independently decide whether to participate. Stage 4 Upon observing the actual realization of participants, the organizer discloses or conceals the number of participants, according the announced rule of the contest. Stage 5 Unless the organizer chose a policy of disclosure in the previous stage, participants exert their e¤ort simultaneously without observing the number of rivals and the winner is selected. The tendency to shortlist a subset of potential players is a familiar theme in the literature. O’Kee¤e et al. (1984) noted that an advantage of contests is to entice the right types of people to participate. This logic is also the basis of many later studies such as Che and Gale (2003), Fullerton and McAfee (1999) and Taylor (1995) that focused on asymmetric players and the ways the organizer should select the appropriate types to participate. Such views are di¢ cult to be justi…ed in settings where players are symmetric. This gap in the literature was highlighted by Fu et al. (2011) who studied the case where entry involves a sunk cost and e¤ort cost function is linear. Here, in this paper, we will assume there is no sunk cost for entry but the e¤ort cost function can be nonlinear. 13 Suppose K potential players are shortlisted. Once the level of entry fees and …nal prize scheme (VN ; N = 1; 2; :::; K) are announced, the K shortlisted players play a game. The entry and bidding behavior upon entry would depend on the disclosure policy of the organizer. We …rst consider the case where the number of participants is disclosed by the organizer. 4.1 Disclosing the number of participants Disclosing the number of participants can be thought of as a benchmark case in a contest with simultaneous entry. After all participants have entered, the organizer announces the number of participants. Because the number of rivals is announced, there is no uncertainty in the actual number of participants when participants choose their optimal e¤ort and each contest after the entry stage is a proper subgame. In this case, for a particular realization of N , participant i’s problem is to maximize Di (N ) = Pi (e) VN | {z } Expected revenue from participation (ei + F ); | {z } (2) Costs of participation where the subscript D denotes a policy of disclosure by the organizer. Furthermore note that for a given N number of participants, the expected revenue from participation depends on the pro…le of e¤ort e = (e1 ; e2 ; : : : ; eN ) from all participants while the costs of participation only depend on player i’s own e¤ort level. Costs are incurred regardless of whether the participant wins or loses and constitutes of e¤ort costs and an entry fee. It is analogous to a two-part tari¤ in industrial organization literature where a per-unit price is 14 charged in addition to a …xed payment made upfront. The payo¤ function is standard and equilibrium e¤ort is characterized in the following lemma. Lemma 1 (Equilibrium e¤ort under policy of disclosure). Under Assumptions A1 and A2, in the subcontest with N 2 entrants, the symmetric equilibrium e¤ort is eD (N ) = N 1 N2 r VN 1 . (3) When N = 1; eD (1) = 0. Proof. See appendix A.1. Now we are ready to characterize the symmetric entry equilibrium, i.e. equilibrium entry probability q. Suppose all other shortlisted players enter with probability q. The ex ante payo¤ of a shortlisted contestant i from participating in the contest with disclosure of number of entrants is K X K D (q; K) = N N =1 1 N q 1 1 (1 q)K N 8 > > < > > : VN |N [eD (N )] {z F } Payo¤ given a realization of N participants 9 > > = > > ; : (4) De…nition 2 (Simultaneous entry equilibrium under policy of disclosure). Suppose K potential players are shortlisted. With simultaneous entry and disclosure of the number of participants, an entry probability qe 2 [0; 1] constitutes an entry equilibrium if (i) qe = 0; or (iii) D (qe ) D (qe ) = 0 and qe 2 (0; 1); or (ii) D (qe ) 0 and 0 and qe = 1. The payo¤ function in (4) above is de…ned in terms of q. An equilibrium number of participants is attained when either (i), (ii) or (iii) are satis…ed. The 15 …rst part of (i), (ii) and (iii) states that in an entry equilibrium, participants should at least break even, otherwise no player is willing to participate. The second part states that entry stops when further entry leads to payo¤s falling below break even point (i.e., (q) = 0) or when the entire subset of players who are willing to join after observing the level of entry fee joins (i.e., q = 1). In other words, for q 2 (0; 1) to constitute a mixed-strategy equilibrium, the payo¤ must be zero. That is, each potential player must be indi¤erent between participating and not participating. Because of the de…nition of entry equilibrium, there is necessarily complete rent dissipation when q 2 (0; 1). Lemma 2 (Existence of simultaneous entry equilibrium under policy of disclosure). For each feasible contest with simultaneous entry where the number of participants is disclosed, a symmetric entry equilibrium must exist. Proof. If D (1; K) 0, qe = 1 must be an entry equilibrium. If qe = 0 must be an entry equilibrium. If must exist qe 2 (0; 1) such that D (1; K) D (qe ; K) > 0 and = 0 as D (0; K) D (1; K) D (0; K) 0, < 0, there 0 and D (q; K) is continuous in q. Thus a symmetric entry equilibrium must exist. In an entry equilibrium qe , denote by T E D the total e¤ort under a policy of disclosure. That is, T ED K X K N qe (1 N N =1 qe )K N N eD (N ). (5) Lemma 3 (Size of …nal prize scheme). For the optimal contest design with simultaneous entry and policy of disclosure, there is no loss of generality to adopt the prize scheme VN = B0 + N F 16 Proof. Note that an entrant’s expected payo¤ when N enters is D (N ) VN F [eD (N )] N VN r N 1 = 1 N N = F; which increases with VN . For a given F , each VN is maximised when all the entry fees N F collected are added to the winner prize. This implies that every D (N ) would also be maximised. If qe = 1 is originally an entry equilibrium, it would still be an entry equilibrium when all entry fees are added to the budget B0 as the …nal prize. If qe = 0 is originally an entry equilibrium, the new entry equilibrium must be higher as D (1) = B0 > 0 when entry fees are added to winner prize. If the original entry equilibrium qe falls within (0; 1), we must have D (qe ; K) 0 when entry fees are added to winner prize. For the …nal prize scheme, note that D (1; K) might be higher or lower than 0: In either case, there must exist an entry equilibrium probability which is higher than the original one when the new prize scheme is adopted. Note that with the new prize scheme, every eD (N ) is weakly higher and eD (N ) increases with N . In addition, the new prize scheme admits an entry equilibrium with weakly higher entry probability. Denote the original entry equilibrium by qe and the new entry equlibrium by q~e . We have q~e qe . With- out loss of generality we assume q~e > qe . We …rst study how the probabilities change in the event that the number of participants N change. Consider ratios N = K N K N q~eN (1 q~e )K N qeN (1 qe )K N = 1 1 q~e qe K q~e (1 qe (1 qe ) q~e ) N : 17 Clearly, 0 = 1 q~e 1 qe K < 1, which means that for the event of zero par- ticipation, the new prize scheme leads to a lower probability. For the event of K entrants, clearly the new prize scheme leads to a higher probability, i.e. N > 1. Note that q~e > qe and 1 This means that ^ exists a N N qe > 1 q~e , which leads to that q~e (1 qe ) qe (1 q~e ) > 1. increases with N . Based on the above discussion, there ^ 1 and N K 1 such that N < 1 when N ^ and N N >1 ^ . Thus the new prize scheme leads to lower probabilities for when N > N events with lower numbers of entrants, and higher probabilities for events with high numbers of entrants. Since every eD (N ) is weakly higher and eD (N ) increases with N when the new prize scheme is adopted, we must have that the new entry equilibrium q~e leads to higher total expected e¤ort with the new prize scheme. In summary, there is no loss of generality to adopt prize scheme VN = B0 + N F for optimal contest design with simultaneous entry and disclosure of number of entrants. We further have the following result. Lemma 4. With prize scheme VN = B0 + N F , entry equilibrium qe is unique and decreases with the entry fee F . Proof. When VN = B0 + N F , D (N ) 1 VN [eD (N )] F N B0 r (B0 + N F ) N 1 = N N2 B0 rN 1 r F 1 = 1 1 N N N = ; 18 which decreases with N . One can verify that d D (q; K) dq = (K 1) K X1 N =1 K N 2 N q 1 1 (1 q)K N 1 [ D (N + 1) D (N )] < 0; which means that entry equilibrium is unique. It is also straightforward that d D (q;K) dF < 0. We thus have qe must decrease with F . The next question is what is the optimal qe or equivalently the optimal entry F that maximizes the total expected surplus given K potential players are shortlisted? Then one can ask what is the optimal number K that should be shortlisted. We consider these issues in a later stage. 4.2 Concealing the number of participants Alternatively, the organizer may choose to conceal the number of participants. This induces additional uncertainty in the expected revenue of a participant. Suppose K potential players are shortlisted. When other shortlisted players enter with probability q, an entrant i’s expected payo¤ can be rewritten as 2 K 6 X 6 6 Ci (e;q) = 4 N =1 | K N 1 N 1 q (1 1 {z K N q) } Binomial density of encountering N 1 rivals where K 1 N 1 qN 1 (1 q)K N 3 7 7 7 Pi (e) VN 5 (ei ) F; (6) is the probability that N out of K players par- ticipate (or equivalently, participant i faces N 1 rivals) and the subscript C denotes a policy of concealment by the organizer. In the extreme event in which q = 1, every potential player participates conditional of the level of 19 entry fees and the contest becomes similar to that under a policy of disclosure. Thus the e¤ect of whether to disclose or conceal the number of participants is only relevant when q < 1. For the following analysis, we focus on the cases where equilibrium entry probability is non-zero as inducing no entry can never be optimal. Lemma 5 (Equilibrium e¤ort under policy of concealment). Under A1 and A2, if the entry equilibrium q 2 [0; 1], the symmetric bidding equilibrium is eC (q) = " K r X K N N =1 1 N q 1 1 q)K (1 N N 1 N2 VN #1 : (7) Proof. See appendix A.2. De…ne the expected payo¤ of a participant, if the other K 1 shortlisted players enter with probability q K X K C (q; K) = N N =1 1 N q 1 1 (1 q)K N VN N [eC (q)] F: (8) Lemma 6. Suppose K potential players are shortlisted. In a contest with simultaneous entry and concealment of the number of participants, entry probability qe is an entry equilibrium if (i) C (qe ) 0 and qe = 0; or (iii) C (qe ) C (qe ) = 0 and qe 2 (0; 1); or (ii) 0 and qe = 1. Compare the payo¤ of a participant under a policy disclosure and concealment, we …nd from expression (4) and (8) that D (q; K) = C (q; K). Together with the entry equilibrium existence Lemma 2 when number of participants is disclosed, we have the following result. 20 Lemma 7. The entry equilibrium analysis is identical regardless of the disclosure policy. Corollary 1 (Existence of simultaneous entry equilibrium under policy of concealment). For each feasible with simultaneous entry where the number of participants is concealed, a symmetric entry equilibrium must exist. Corollary 2. With prize scheme, VN = B0 + N F , entry equilibrium qe is unique and decreases with the entry fee F . In an equilibrium qe , denote by T E C the total e¤ort under a policy of concealment. That is, T EC (9) Kqe eC (qe ). Lemma 8 (Maximum total e¤ort under a policy of concealment). Under a policy of concealment, if K potential players are shortlisted and entry probability induced is qe = q 2 e[0; 1], total e¤ort in equilibrium is bounded above by 1 T E C (qe ; K) B0 K 1 1 n qe 1 h 1 qe )K (1 Proof. At an entry equilibrium, it must be true that io 1 (10) : C (q; K) 0. This gives that the total e¤ort costs of the shortlisted players Kq[eC (q)] K X K N q (1 N N =1 In particular, if q 2 (0; 1), Kq[eC (q)] q)K PK N =1 K N N VN KqF: q N (1 q)K N VN KqF . 21 Note that the total expected e¤ort 1= ; KqeC (q) = [KqeC (q)] (Kq) 1 ( " K X K 1= (Kq) 1 q N (1 ) [KqeC (q)] (Kq) 1 N N =1 As VN q)K N VN KqF #)1= : B0 + N F; we have ( KqeC (q) (Kq) 1 " K X K N q (1 N N =1 q)K N (B0 + N F ) KqF #)1= q)K io1= : where ( (Kq) 1 " K X K N q (1 N N =1 q)K N (B0 + N F ) n = B0 (Kq) KqF 1 h 1 #)1= (1 : Lemma 9. For given entry equilibrium qe 2 (0; 1], there exists entry fees Fe 0 such that the prize scheme VN = B0 + N F would induce the upper bound T E C (qe ; K). Proof. We …rst show that for any q 2 (0; 1], there exists an F 0 such that prize scheme VN = B0 + N F induces the entry equilibrium q. Note that when F = 0, qe = 1. When VN = B0 + N F , a participant’s expected payo¤ decreases with F for any q. Thus there must exist an F^ 0 such that a partic- ipant’s expected payo¤ is exactly zero. Any F > F^ would induce equilibrium 22 entry qe < 1. According to Corollary 2, as F increases, the equilibrium entry probability must decrease. To induce any entry equilibrium qe 2 (0; 1), we need to set an fee Fe as follows. C (qe ; K) = = K X K N N =1 K X K N N =1 1 N q 1 e K r X K N N =1 1 N q 1 e 1 (1 1 (1 qe )K N 1 N q 1 e 1 (1 qe )K N B0 + N Fe N (eC (qe )) Fe (B0 + N Fe ) N 1 N2 = 0: B0 N qe )K N Clearly, when entry fee is set at Fe as above, equilibrium entry qe is then induced. As the above inequality indicates the participants’expected payo¤s are h io1= n K 1 1 (1 qe ) zero, the total expected e¤ort induced is exactly B0 (Kqe ) . Further restrictions are placed on the entry probability q to ensure that the contest following entry is optimally designed.12 Similarly a subscript C has been appended to represent the optimal entry probability under a policy of concealment. Lemma 10 (Optimal entry probability under policy of concealment). Suppose the organizer adopts a policy of concealment. (i) When < 1, Total e¤ort is maximized when the participants play mixed entry strategies. That is, 0 < qC < 12 Note that the subsequent analysis does not explicitly shows how to induce the optimal entry probability. As such, an appropriate notion of inducing a particular level of entry probability may be unclear. 23 1. (ii) When > 1, total e¤ort is maximized when the participants enter with probability qC = 1. Proof. Begin by showing the relationship between T E C and q. 1 @T E C @q = B0 M | 8 > > > :| 1 n q 2 q 1 M 1 M q (1 q) {z 1. This implies that Now consider 1 q)M (1 {z Always non-negative i Always non-negative Suppose …rst h +( } | h 1) 1 io 1 } q)M (1 {z Sign depends on value of @T E C @q 9 > = i> > }> ; : (11) 0, thus q = 1 is optimal. < 1. The …rst property is that for q = 1, @T E C @q < 0. The second property is that for q ! 0, T E C ! 0 by L’Hôpital rule. Since T E C is continuous in q, this means that there is an optimal qC 2 (0; 1) that maximises total e¤ort and is the solution to M qC (1 M 1 qC ) @T E C @q = (1 = 0. That is, qC solves h ) 1 (1 M qC ) i . The sharpest distinction of this paper from Fu et al. (2011) is the introduction of entry fees and its role on the entry decision of players. Assuming > 1, Fu et al. (2011) in their paper noted that the optimal entry probability is less than one. In contrast, the results in Lemma 10 above showed that qC = 1 when > 1. This is the implication of the introduction of entry fees. Having qC = 1 alleviates the distortions caused by incomplete information on 24 the number of participants and allows participants to internalize the e¤ects of entry fees more e¢ ciently, which increased the size of the …nal prize, by exerting higher e¤ort. Without entry fees to enhance the attractiveness of the …nal prize, the organizer in Fu et al. (2011) can only increase e¤ort when participants are uncertain of the number of rivals they are competing against, that is, when q < 1. 4.2.1 Shortlisting under policy of concealment With stochastic entry, the organizer is unable to consistently implement the optimal actual number of participants N . From the de…nition of simultaneous entry equilibrium, so long as (q) > 0, participants must be entering the contest with pure strategy (q = 1). The transition to mixed entry strategies occurs at (q) = 0. When participants enter with mixed strategies, attracting the optimal N may be infeasible in practice as participants enter the contest stochastically and many realizations of N are not optimal. In this case, the organizer may alternatively choose to …nd out whether total e¤ort conditional on the expected number of participants varies systematically with the number of potential players K, given the optimal qC in Lemma 10. Proposition 1 (Entry fees under policy of concealment). Suppose the organizer adopts a policy of concealment. (i) When < 1, the organizer induces the maximum total e¤ort by shortlisting 2 potential players, which leads to entry fees of FC = B0 2 2 r 2 qC 1 1 : (12) 25 1 The total e¤ort is 2 (ii) When 1 B0 1 (qC ) 1 qC )2 (1 1 . > 1, the organizer induces the maximum total e¤ort by at- tracting all M potential players, which leads to entry fees of FC = The total e¤ort is M B0 M B0 M r M M 1 (13) 1 : 1 . Proof. Now show the optimal number of potential players the organiser would like to shortlist (i.e. K that maximises total e¤ort) conditional on . Consider two cases: Case 1, < 1: Recall from Lemma 9 that 1 T E C = B0 K 1 1 n q 1 h 1 (1 q)K io 1 : After taking an increasing transformation by raising it to the power of and taking a log transformation, R.H.S. becomes ( h 1) log K + log 1 (1 i q)K + log B0 + ( 1) log q: Applying the Envolope Theorem (optimal q depends on K), F.O.C. with respect to K is @T E C = @K 1 K q)K log (1 (1 1 (1 K q) q) : 26 Making use of the inequality log (1 1 q)K log (1 (1 K 1 q) q)K (1 q , 1 q q) > 1 < K we have + q)K q (1 1 1 q)K (1 : From (11), the optimal q must satisfy , ( h (1 ) K 1) 1 K q) 1 +h i h K 1 + K q (1 q)K q (1 1 1 q) i = 0: 1 q (1 K (1 q) i = 0; Therefore, q)K log (1 (1 1 K 1 (1 q) q)K < K +h 1 q)K 1 q)K (1 i = 0: Hence the …rst-order condition of the transformed problem is less than zero. Therefore @T E C @K < 0. Total e¤ort is decreasing in the number of potential players and the organiser would like to attract two potential players. It cannot be that the organiser attracts one potential player otherwise the player can exert zero e¤ort and win the prize with certainty. Using the fact that FC (K) = B0 C (qC ; K) = 0, the optimal entry fees can be derived as PK N 1 K 1 (1 N =1 N 1 (qC ) PK N 1 K 1 (1 N =1 N 1 (qC ) qC )K N qC )K 1 N N 1 r r N 1 N N 1 N : (14) Substituting K = 2 into the expression (14), FC (2) = B0 2 2 r 2 qC (2) 1 1 > 0: 27 Case 2, B0 K 1 > 1: Given q = 1 from Lemma (10), at optimum, T E C = and @T E C = @K 1 B0 K 1 > 0; thus the organiser would like to attract the maximum M number of potential players. Substituting q = 1 and K = M into expression (14) above, ) FC (M ) = B0 M r M M 1 1 0: The proposition identi…es the optimal number of participants conditional on the cost parameter . Entry fees are higher in (12) than in (13). Intu- itively, increasing e¤ort is relatively less expensive with concave costs. As a result, players favor participation in the contest. The number of participants increases, expected payo¤ decreases hence eroding the incentive to exert effort. This explains why the organizer should set higher entry fees to limit entry when costs are concave. Similarly, when players have convex costs, the organizer should lower entry fees to encourage a desirable level of competition. With convex costs, exerting e¤ort becomes relatively more expensive. In order to attain a desired level of total e¤ort, the organizer has to attract more participants. The increased number of participants reduces payo¤s, but the organizer o¤sets this by lowering the entry fees. 28 4.3 Policy of disclosure vs. concealment A primary aim for the introduction of entry fees is to present the organizer with an instrument to in‡uence the entry decisions of players in a contest with simultaneous entry. It does not follow most of the literature on simultaneous entry which assumed that entry decisions are based on exogenous factors. Such reformulation of the simultaneous entry setting a¤ects the equilibrium behavior of participants and therefore requires a reexamination of the organizer’s optimal disclosure policy by comparing the results from the previous two subsections. Although the optimal design under a policy of disclosure has not been explicitly derived, it is seldom required for the analysis. Lemma 11. With simultaneous entry, both policies of disclosure and concealment induce the same entry probabilities in equilibrium for any given prize scheme. However, a policy of disclosure dominates concealment if concealment dominates disclosure if < 1;and > 1. The …rst part of this Lemma is implied by Lemma 7. The second part about the comparison of disclosure policy is shown by Fu et al. (2011). Consider the …rst possibility that players have concave costs. In this case, from Proposition 1 the optimal design under a policy of concealment simply requires that the non-degenerate entry probability to be qC 2 (0; 1) and MC = 2. However, Fu et al. (2010) Theorem 1 guarantees that all things being equal, when costs are concave, a policy of disclosure must dominate concealment. In other words, a contest under a policy of disclosure with qC and MC = 2 will induce higher total e¤ort than a contest under a policy of concealment with 29 qC and MC = 2 (the latter of which is already the optimal design under a policy of concealment). Thus the best design under a policy of disclosure must necessarily induce higher total e¤ort than a policy of concealment. This result is put into the follow proposition. Proposition 2. Suppose simultaneous entry and < 1, the optimal design under a policy of disclosure must necessarily induce higher total e¤ort than a policy of concealment. In fact with a policy of disclosure, the optimal entry probability qD must also be non-degenerate for any K 2 shortlisted. Suppose in contradiction qD = 1, both disclosure and concealment policy must induce the same e¤ort. Yet from Lemma 10, under a concealment policy, total e¤ort when entry equilibrium q < 1 is greater than total e¤ort at q = 1. Therefore if qD = 1, total e¤ort under a policy of disclosure would have been dominated by total e¤ort under a policy of concealment, which is a contradiction. Since the optimal design under a policy of disclosure should induce higher total e¤ort than policy of concealment at q, qD is less than one. Corollary 3. Suppose simultaneous entry and < 1. For any K 2 short- listed, the optimal equilibrium entry qD is less than one when the number of participants is disclosed. However, to pin down the optimal shortlisted K under a policy of disclosure is not an easy task. The irrelevance of an explicit derivation of the optimal design under policy of disclosure can be extended to the second possibility where players have 30 convex costs. All things being equal, convex costs mean that total e¤ort under a policy of concealment dominates disclosure except when q = 1, where both policies induce the same e¤ort. When > 1, qC = 1 and KC = M induces the maximum total e¤ort under a policy of concealment hence in a sense the organizer is indi¤erent between either policy. We thus have the following result. Proposition 3. Suppose simultaneous entry and > 1. The disclosure policy is not relevant. The subsequent analysis is meant to justify the di¤erence in …ndings between Proposition 1 above and Fu et al. (2011). Besides the di¤erence in optimal entry probability between the two papers, it has been argued in Fu et al. (2011) that even with convex costs the organizer avoids inviting the full set of potential players because this increases the competitiveness of the contest. As a result, players enter less often and exert lesser e¤ort. By proposing an alternative setting whereby the organizer is able to collect entry fees and to add the sum collected to the …nal prize, the enhanced …nal prize o¤sets the e¤ect of increased competitiveness and having more participants may increase e¤ort instead. Based on similar arguments for the case of results for the case of < 1, we have the following > 1. Corollary 4. Suppose simultaneous entry and > 1. For any K 2 short- listed players, the optimal equilibrium entry qD exactly equals to 1 when the number of participants is disclosed. 31 Corollary 5. Suppose simultaneous entry and > 1, when the number of participants is disclosed, at the optimum the organizer includes all potential players and everyone enters. 5 Sequential entry Consider now the relatively simple case of sequential entry to analyze the optimal design. Note that with sequential entry, the number of entrants is always observed by all potential contestants. Thus there is no role here for disclosure policy on the number of participants. The only possible equilibrium entries are discrete. In addition, for sequential entry, there is no role for shortlisting of potential players. If not, it must be true that at the optimum all the shortlisted (K < M ) enter but each of them enjoy a positive surplus. In this case, the organizer can further increase the entry fee without changing the winner prize to make their payo¤ to be zero, which means K of them entering the contest would be an entry equilibrium without shortlisting. The total e¤ort remains the same. We can extend the analysis of Fu and Lu (2010a) to cases with nonlinear costs. Similar to the case of > 1 in Proposition 1, we have the following result. Proposition 4. Given an entry equilibrium of N participants is induced, the organizer induces the maximum total e¤ort by charging an entry fee of F (N ) = B0 Ne Ne r Ne 1 1 : 32 1 The total e¤ort is Ne B0 Ne . Proposition 5 (Entry fees under sequential entry). (i) Suppose < 1. The organizer induces the highest possible e¤ort of the contest with an entry equilibrium of Ne = 2 by setting F = B0 2 2 r 1 ; (15) and VN = B0 + N F . The total e¤ort is then 2 (ii) Suppose (16) 1 B0 2 . The organizer induces the highest possible e¤ort of > 1. the contest with an entry equilibrium of Ne = M by setting F = B0 M r M M 1 1 ; (17) and VN = B0 + N F : The total e¤ort is then M B0 M (18) 1 . Again such behavior can be justi…ed by the same logic underlying shortlisting in the case of simultaneous entry. Concave e¤ort costs mean that the organizer should set an entry fee that attracts only two participants. In contrast, convex e¤ort costs mean that the organizer should set an entry fee that attracts all potential players. A further insight obtained from the above 33 proposition is that when < 1, entry fees under simultaneous entry with con- cealment are higher than under sequential entry. Expression (12) makes clear the source of distortion and shows that the higher entry fees are a consequence of participants entering the contest with probability less than one. The higher the probability of entry qC , the closer are the two levels of entry fees. Entry fees do not directly a¤ect participants’ e¤ort level in equilibrium, yet they are used by the organizer to control the number of participants and also to capture any of their remaining surpluses. 6 Simultaneous vs. sequential entry In this section, I compare the total e¤ort elicited under each entry pattern and thereby state the main results of the paper. If < 1, simultaneous entry with a policy of concealment also dominates sequential entry. This is because maximum total e¤ort under sequential entry is 2 B0 2 1 is Bo 2 1 . Total e¤ort under simultaneous entry with a policy of concealment 1 (qC ) 1 1 (1 qC )2 1 , which is equal to 2 B0 2 1 if and only if qC = 1: However, the argument in Lemma 10 proves that a non-dengenerate qC induces a higher level of e¤ort than when qe = 1. Theorem 1 (Optimal entry sequence with concave costs). Suppose < 1 and contest is optimally designed for each case in terms of shortlisting and entry fees. Their performance in terms of total e¤ort can be ranked in the following descending order: simultaneous entry with disclosure (highest), simultaneous entry with concealment, sequential (lowest). 34 From an applied perspective, the results provides a rationale why governments tend to announce a shortlist of …rms in numerous contest where …rms’ costs can be formulated as being concave.13 Theorem 2 (Optimal entry sequence with convex costs). Suppose > 1 and contest is optimally designed for each case in terms of shortlisting and entry fees. All entry sequences and disclosure policy induce the same e¤ort at the optimum. These results are summarized in Table 1 below. 7 Concluding remarks By capturing features of contests in a simple manner, this paper hopes to improve our understanding of contest design with nonlinear e¤ort costs. The contrived theory provides a basis for the logic underlying policy designs in many competitive settings and a clear sense of the interaction between the four instruments available to the contest organizer: shortlisting of potential players, entry sequence of participants (either simultaneous or sequential), entry fees paid by participants, and disclosure policy of the number of participants. We found that the nonlinearity of the e¤ort cost function plays a critical role for 13 In Singapore, competitions to design and build the integrated resorts and sports hub, to name a few, all exhibit the above characteristics. Another prominent example in Singapore is the competition among transport operators for the license to operate a package of bus routes for a …xed period of time. Operators compete based on their e¢ ciency and service quality. It is reasonable to take the view that operators’ costs are concave (e.g., higher marginal costs of e¤ort which decreases with learning-by-doing). Together the above results predict that the government should shortlist a subset of operators for consideration (prominent operators are SBS Transit and SMRT). 35 1 Simultaneous Disclosure Concealment Sequential Optimal q qD = 1 qC = 1 q =1 Optimal K M M M Table 1: Summary of results the optimal design of the contest. If cost functions are concave, simultaneous entry with a policy of disclosure would induce the highest e¤ort when the right number of contestants are shortlisted. If cost functions are convex, all combinations of entry pattern and disclosure policy induce the same optimal entry and the same amount of total e¤ort when the contests are optimally designed in each scenario. The discussion is still imperfect in certain ways. For example, we could not explicitly pinned down the optimal number of contestants being shortlisted under simultaneous entry with a policy of disclosure. This step can be avoided, however, when ranking the performance of each combination of entry pattern 36 and disclosure policy. References Atsu Amegashie, J. (2009). American idol: should it be a singing contest or a popularity contest? Journal of Cultural Economics, 33(4):265–277. Baye, M., Kovenock, D., and De Vries, C. (1994). The solution to the Tullock rent-seeking game when r> 2: Mixed-strategy equilibria and mean dissipation rates. Public Choice, 81(3):363–380. Che, Y. and Gale, I. (2003). Optimal design of research contests. The American Economic Review, 93(3):646–671. Clark, D. and Riis, C. (1996). A multi-winner nested rent-seeking contest. Public Choice, 87(1):177–184. Clark, D. and Riis, C. (1998). In‡uence and the discretionary allocation of several prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 14(4):605–625. Cornes, R. and Hartley, R. (2005). Asymmetric contests with general technologies. Economic Theory, 26(4):923–946. Fu, Q., Jiao, Q., and Lu, J. (2010). On disclosure policy in contests with stochastic entry. Public Choice, Forthcoming. Fu, Q., Jiao, Q., and Lu, J. (2011). Contests with endogenous and stochastic entry. Working Paper. 37 Fu, Q. and Lu, J. (2010a). Contest design and optimal endogenous entry. Economic Inquiry, 48(1):80–88. Fu, Q. and Lu, J. (2010b). The optimal multi-stage contest. Economic Theory, Forthcoming. Fu, Q. and Lu, J. (2011). A micro-foundation for generalised multi-prize contests: A noisy ranking perspective. Social Choice and Welfare, Forthcoming. Fullerton, R. and McAfee, R. (1999). Auctioning entry into tournaments. The Journal of Political Economy, 107(3):573–605. Gradstein, M. and Konrad, K. (1999). Orchestrating rent seeking contests. The Economic Journal, 109(458):536–545. Lim, W. and Matros, A. (2009). Contests with a stochastic number of players. Games and Economic Behavior, 67(2):584–597. Myerson, R. and Wärneryd, K. (2006). Population uncertainty in contests. Economic Theory, 27(2):469–474. Nalebu¤, B. and Stiglitz, J. (1983). Prizes and incentives: towards a general theory of compensation and competition. The Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1):21–43. Nti, K. (2004). Maximum e¤orts in contests with asymmetric valuations. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(4):1059–1066. O’Kee¤e, M., Viscusi, W., and Zeckhauser, R. (1984). Economic contests: Comparative reward schemes. Journal of Labor Economics, 2(1):27–56. 38 Schweinzer, P. and Segev, E. (2008). The optimal prize structure of symmetric Tullock contests. Public Choice, Forthcoming. Siegel, R. (2009). All-pay contests. Econometrica, 77(1):71–92. Siegel, R. (2010). Asymmetric contests with conditional investments. The American Economic Review, 100(5):2230–2260. Szidarovszky, F. and Okuguchi, K. (2008). On the existence and uniqueness of pure Nash equilibrium in rent-seeking games. 40 Years of Research on Rent Seeking 1: Theory of Rent Seeking, 1:271. Szymanski, S. and Valletti, T. (2005). Incentive e¤ects of second prizes. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(2):467–481. Taylor, C. (1995). Digging for golden carrots: An analysis of research tournaments. The American Economic Review, 85(4):872–890. Appendix A A.1 Simultaneous entry Proof of Lemma 1 To begin, participant i’s problem with the Tullock contest success function is max ei eri + er Pi r j6=i ej VN ei F: 39 Let e^i = ei and R = r be a monotonic transformation of the problem. Participant i’s problem becomes max e^i e^R i + e^R i P ^R j j6=i e VN e^i F: First-order condition: e^R i + P ^R j j6=i e e^R i + R^ eR i 1 e^R i + R^ eR i P 1 ^R j j6=i e P e^R eR i R^ i ^R j j6=i e VN 2 ^R j j6=i e P 1 2 VN 1 = 0; 1 = 0: (19) At the symmetric equilibrium (8i 2 N ; e^i = e^), equation (19) becomes R^ e2R 1 (N 1) VN 1 = 0; N 2 e^2R R (N 1) ) e^ = VN : N2 1 r VN N 1 : )e = N2 (20) By an increasing transformation, existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium is guaranteed by Szidarovszky and Okuguchi (2008). Q.E.D. 40 A.2 Proof of Lemma 5 By construction of participant i’s payo¤, his problem is M X M max eCi N N =1 1 N q 1 1 M N (1 Let e~Ci = (eCi ) and R = q) r (eCi )r P VN (eCi )r + j6=i (eCj )r (eCi ) F: be a monotonic transformation of the problem. His problem becomes M X M max e~Ci N N =1 1 N q 1 1 (1 q)M N First-order condition: M X N =1 (~ eCi )R VN P eCj )R (~ eCi )R + j6=i (~ R 1 M N 1 N q 1 1 q)M (1 N hP R i eCj ) R (~ eCi ) j6=i (~ i2 h P eCj )R (~ eCi )R + j6=i (~ e~Ci F: 1 = 0: (21) VN At the symmetric equilibrium (8i 2 N ; e~Ci = e~C ), equation (21) becomes M X M N N =1 1 N q 1 1 (1 q)M N (N 1) R (~ eC )2R N 2 (~ eC )2R 1 VN 1 = 0; M X M 1 N 1 N 1 ) e~C = R : q (1 q)M N VN 2 N 1 N N =1 " M #1 r X M 1 N 1 N 1 q (1 q)M N VN ) eC = : 2 N 1 N N =1 (22) Existence and uniqueness has been proven in Fu et al. (2011). Q.E.D. 41 [...]... well-adopted Tullock contest models, which is a type of imperfectly discriminatory contest 8 where the participants with the highest e¤ort does not win the contest with certainty, but with the highest probability To give an illustration of such an evaluation mechanism, consider again the R&D contest where the esthetical design of the prototype plays a role in the outcome Whether the judges like the design of... the contest becomes a random lottery When r tends to in…nity, the player with the highest e¤ort wins with certainty and the contest becomes an all-pay auction For example in a two-player contest, r for every ei > ej ; Pi = eri eri + erj = 1 [1 + (ej ei ) ] ! 1 A standard all-pay r!1 auction is a special type of all-pay contests 11 function has important implications for the optimal design of the contest. .. standard Tullock contest with N M participants and a single …xed prize (Schweinzer and Segev, 2008) The analysis in Fu et al (2010) further implies that it is also a su¢ cient condition for a unique symmetric purestrategy bidding equilibrium when N M participants enter with a symmetric non-dengenerate probability into a contest with a single …xed prize 4 Simultaneous entry In a contest with simultaneous... equilibrium q~e leads to higher total expected e¤ort with the new prize scheme In summary, there is no loss of generality to adopt prize scheme VN = B0 + N F for optimal contest design with simultaneous entry and disclosure of number of entrants We further have the following result Lemma 4 With prize scheme VN = B0 + N F , entry equilibrium qe is unique and decreases with the entry fee F Proof When VN = B0 +... total e¤ort than a contest under a policy of concealment with 29 qC and MC = 2 (the latter of which is already the optimal design under a policy of concealment) Thus the best design under a policy of disclosure must necessarily induce higher total e¤ort than a policy of concealment This result is put into the follow proposition Proposition 2 Suppose simultaneous entry and < 1, the optimal design under a... have concave costs In this case, from Proposition 1 the optimal design under a policy of concealment simply requires that the non-degenerate entry probability to be qC 2 (0; 1) and MC = 2 However, Fu et al (2010) Theorem 1 guarantees that all things being equal, when costs are concave, a policy of disclosure must dominate concealment In other words, a contest under a policy of disclosure with qC and... equilibrium, so long as (q) > 0, participants must be entering the contest with pure strategy (q = 1) The transition to mixed entry strategies occurs at (q) = 0 When participants enter with mixed strategies, attracting the optimal N may be infeasible in practice as participants enter the contest stochastically and many realizations of N are not optimal In this case, the organizer may alternatively choose... surplus In this case, the organizer can further increase the entry fee without changing the winner prize to make their payo¤ to be zero, which means K of them entering the contest would be an entry equilibrium without shortlisting The total e¤ort remains the same We can extend the analysis of Fu and Lu (2010a) to cases with nonlinear costs Similar to the case of > 1 in Proposition 1, we have the following... complement of an imperfectly discriminatory contest is a perfectly discriminatory contest, also known as an all-pay contest Siegel (2009, 2010) derived the equilibrium payo¤s and also provided an algorithm that constructs the unique equilibrium in these contests 9 For example, all players exert the same e¤ort under a symmetric equilibrium Because 10 ipants win the prize with equal probabilities f ( ) is known... qe )K N N eD (N ) (5) Lemma 3 (Size of …nal prize scheme) For the optimal contest design with simultaneous entry and policy of disclosure, there is no loss of generality to adopt the prize scheme VN = B0 + N F 16 Proof Note that an entrant’s expected payo¤ when N enters is D (N ) VN F [eD (N )] N VN r N 1 = 1 N N = F; which increases with VN For a given F , each VN is maximised when all the entry fees ... of …rms in numerous contest where …rms’ costs can be formulated as being concave.13 Theorem (Optimal entry sequence with convex costs) Suppose > and contest is optimally designed for each case... contests in a simple manner, this paper hopes to improve our understanding of contest design with nonlinear e¤ort costs The contrived theory provides a basis for the logic underlying policy designs... Sequential Optimal q qD < Optimal K qC < q =1 2 >1 Simultaneous Disclosure Concealment Sequential Optimal q qD = qC = q =1 Optimal K M M M Table 1: Summary of results the optimal design of the contest

Ngày đăng: 12/10/2015, 17:33

TỪ KHÓA LIÊN QUAN

TÀI LIỆU CÙNG NGƯỜI DÙNG

TÀI LIỆU LIÊN QUAN

w