Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 126 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
126
Dung lượng
1,66 MB
Nội dung
ESSAYS ON OUTSOURCING, TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION AND
UNEMPLOYMENT
BY
TAN CHIH WEI, RANDY
(B. SOC. SCI., HONS., 2003)
A THESIS SUBMITTED
FOR THE DEGREE OF MASTER OF SOCIAL SCIENCE
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF SINGAPORE
2005
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Much has happened during the past 2 years of my candidature here while doing
this course, the most significant of which is the Lord’s guiding hand in bringing me into
confession of my sins and acceptance of Christ. I recalled my feeling of being upset at
my final exam for Mathematical Economics 2 and how worried I was about missing out
on a 2nd upper. I was discussing this with my then, and now current, supervisor Dr Ho
Kong Weng and he somehow shared the Gospel with me. Through my supervisor, who
has assisted me in the understanding of the Gospel and explained some things in the
Bible which I could not understand, the Lord has helped me to understand more of His
revealed will. Looking back, it is interesting to think about how the Lord has shut the
doors in my futile search for a job after completing my Honours in Economics and
opening the door of a research scholarship and I am indeed indebted to the Lord for
opening this door and shutting the others, convicting me of my sins and enabling me to
embrace Christ as my and the only Saviour. I would also like to express my sincere and
heartfelt appreciation to Dr Ho for his efforts and valuable time in sharing with me the
word of God as well.
I would like to express my heartfelt appreciation to Dr Ho for his supervision and
a free hand in the process of doing this thesis as well as in the tutorial classes I have
conducted for his module and research assistance rendered and his valuable and creative
inputs throughout. Admittedly, I have a tendency of wanting things my own way and I
would express my sincere apologies for the offence and unpleasantness caused. Much
i
has been learnt whilst working with him in that I have learnt to be more open and critical
in my thought process, as well as how to help students learn and not excessively spoonfeeding them. These, and other lessons and attributes which I may have unintentionally
omitted, have certainly made it a great privilege for me to have worked with Dr Ho. I
must again thank him for the valuable assistance, time and opportunity cost incurred in
helping me throughout the 3 years of supervision for my Honours and Masters theses.
My sincere appreciation to Ms Sagi Kaur for her help in the administrative
assistance rendered for the departmental graduate presentation I conducted and the
summer meeting of the North American Economics and Finance Association held at the
80th Western Economics Association conference. I would also like to thank Mdm Foo
and Mdm Woo for their assistance in the printing of the transparencies and handouts for
the above-mentioned events. Financial assistance from NUS for the attendance and
presentation at the conference is acknowledged. I would also like to thank the rest of the
administrative staff for the handling of the administrative and teaching matters.
I would like to thank the Lord for His providential hand in guiding me through the
research programme, without which the completion of the coursework and thesis would
have been impossible. I would also like to thank A/P Zeng Jinli and A/P Zhang Jie for
sharing some research techniques during the Honours and Masters classes respectively,
which have certainly been useful during the course of my research work. Comments for
a shortened version of the first chapter from those who attended my presentation at the
Graduate Students’ Seminar on 27 June 2005 and Professor Daniel Mitchell at the 2005
ii
Summer Meeting of the North American Economics and Finance Association held during
the 80th Western Economic Association conference is also much appreciated. Finally, I
would also like to thank the following for the constant encouragement and friendship:
Shirley Fong, Daniel Soh, Enrico Tanuwidjaja, Grace Yong, Kelvin Foo, Koh Phuay
Leng, Oh Boon Ping, Yvonne Yau, Qiao Zhuo, Feng Shuang, Luckraz Shravan, Nicholas
Sim, Terence Cheng, Kuhan Harichandra, Swee Eik Leong, Gabriel Wong, Koo Ping
Shung, the Economics Graduate Students Society committee of 2004, students whom I
have taught or who I have come into contact with as a tutor for Econometrics 2 or
Macroeconomic Analysis 2 during the academic year 2004/05, everyone over at Pilgrim
Covenant Church and friends from my secondary and college days. My sincere apologies
go out to those whom I have omitted unintentionally. Any remaining errors or omissions
in this thesis is mine and views expressed in this thesis do not necessarily represent those
of the Department of Economics, National University of Singapore, or any of the abovenamed or group of individuals.
iii
ABSTRACT
This thesis is made up of two distinct essays.
In the first essay, titled
“Technology Adoption and Unemployment”, a model with employment of workers as an
investment decision within a small open economy is used to examine the relationship
between technology adoption and employment. Human capital plays a crucial role in the
technology adoption and, subsequently employment of workers. It is shown that as
human capital level increases, level of technology adopted within the economy increases.
There exists a threshold level of human capital beyond which employment falls, which
equivalently translates into higher unemployment in our model. Two opposing effects
are in place here as human capital increases. An increase in human capital enables better
use of existing technology and reduces job loss. However, this also has a positive impact
on the adoption of technology, thus raising the technology adoption aspect of creative
destruction which raises job loss at an increasing rate and thus reduces employment. The
latter effect dominates the former upon breaching the threshold, thus leading to the
increase in unemployment. We have therefore a non-monotonic relationship between
level of technology adopted and employment and hence human capital and employment.
The second essay, titled “Integration versus Domestic Outsourcing: An
Exploratory Study”, considers a two-country model of production of the service good that
differs in quality. The firm in each country competes with each other in price and in
quality. Constrained by local provision of the service good, the firm faces the choice of
either adopting the integrated mode of production or outsourcing the intermediates
iv
domestically.
There exists a threshold level of human capital whereby integration
(outsourcing) is adopted when human capital level is below (above) the threshold. As
human capital increases, the cost of outsourcing the intermediate decreases relative to
wage cost, thus the firm is able to reduce the per unit employment sufficiently and yet
produce a sufficiently high quality of the product at a low price-to-quality ratio. The
endogenous quality choice in our model thus allows for an extra avenue of response
towards increased competition.
v
CONTENTS
Acknowledgements
Abstract
Contents
List of Tables
List of Figures
i
iv
vi
vii
ix
CHAPTER 1:
TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION AND UNEMPLOYMENT
1.1
Introduction
1
1.2
The Model
10
1.2.1
1.2.2
1.2.3
1.2.4
1.2.5
1.3
Steady-State Analysis and Changes in Human Capital
1.3.1
1.3.2
1.3.3
1.3.4
1.4
The Production Process
Employment Decisions
Job Matching and Creative Destruction Dynamics
Optimization Behaviour Across the Firm and the Economy
Wage Bargaining Curve
Steady State Equilibrium
Parameterization
Simulation Results
Changes in the Human Capital Level of the Economically Active
Changes in Other Parameters
1.4.1
1.4.2
1.4.3
1.4.4
1.4.5
20
37
Matching Parameters
Wage Setting Parameters
Rate of Global Technological Progress
Productivity Parameter
Cost Parameters
1.5
General Discussion
51
1.6
Conclusion
52
1.7
Appendices
54
1.7.1
1.7.2
Proof of Proposition 1
Mathematical Intuition of Proposition 2
vi
CHAPTER 2:
INTEGRATION VERSUS DOMESTIC OUTSOURCING
2.1
Introduction
58
2.2
The Model
67
2.2.1
2.2.2
2.3
Equilibrium and Changes in Human Capital Level
2.3.1
2.3.2
2.3.3
2.4
The Northern Firm
Preferences
Analytical Solution
Numerical Example
Changes in the Human Capital Level of the Northern Economy
Other Comparative Statics
2.4.1
2.4.2
2.4.3
2.4.4
2.4.5
73
88
Price Charged by the Southern Firm
Quality of the Southern Firm’s Service Good
Cost of Outsourcing Manual Component
Wage Cost
General Productivity Level
2.5
Production Share Parameters
104
2.6
Modifying the Cost of Outsourcing
106
2.7
General Discussion
107
2.8
Conclusion and Further Research
109
References
113
LIST OF TABLES
Table 1.1:
Parameter values used for base case
22
Table 1.2:
Summary of slopes of demarcation curves and approximate
corresponding range of values of h
23
Table 1.3:
Simulation results for baseline case
25
vii
Table 1.4:
Summary of outcomes of comparative statics exercise of an
increase in respective parameters in 1.4.1 to 1.4.5
37
Table 1.5:
Simulation results for (a) ε = 0.2 and (b) ε = 0.3
39
Table 1.6:
Simulation results for (a) δ = 0.5 and (b) δ = 0.7
39
Table 1.7:
Simulation results for (a) 10% fall in χ (=0.144) and
(b) 10% rise in χ (=0.176)
41
Table 1.8:
Simulation results for (a) γ = 1.1 and (b) γ = 1.7
41
Table 1.9:
Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in ψ (=0.95) and
(b) 5% rise in ψ (=1.05)
42
Table 1.10:
Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in z (=0.0665) and
(b) 5% rise in z (=0.0735)
45
Table 1.11:
Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in B (=0.475) and
(b) 5% rise in B (=0.525)
46
Table 1.12:
Simulation results for (a) 10% fall in b (=0.09) and
(b) 10% rise in b (=0.11)
48
Table 1.13:
Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in q (=0.133) and
(b) 5% rise in q (=0.147)
49
Table 1.14:
Simulation results for (a) 25% fall in r (=0.03) and
(b) 25% rise in r (=0.05)
50
Table 1.15:
Simulation results for baseline case on the shift of
demarcation loci
57
Table 2.1:
Parameter values used for initial numerical analysis
80
Table 2.2:
Comparison of roots obtained with HN = 0.5
81
Table 2.3:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN
83
Table 2.4:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a 20% fall in price charged by
the Southern firm
90
viii
Table 2.5:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a 20% increase in the quality of
the Southern firm’s service good
94
Table 2.6:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a decrease in the cost of
outsourcing (10% fall in ρ and 10% fall in δ)
97
Table 2.7:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a 15% increase in the base wage
rate
100
Table 2.8:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a 20% increase in general per unit
productivity
102
Table 2.9:
Numerical results under both forms of production for
different values of HN with a change in the productive share
of the organizational component (β=1/3)
Table 2.10:
Summary of outcomes of comparative statics exercise of an
increase in respective parameters in sections 2.3.3 and 2.4
under the relevant production mode
104
110
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1.1:
Demarcation curves for low level of human capital (h=0.25)
23
Figure 1.2:
Demarcation curves for high level of human capital (h=0.7)
24
Figure 1.3:
Effect of an increase in h when h is below the threshold level
of human capital
31
Figure 1.4:
Effect of an increase in h when h is above the threshold level
of human capital
33
Figure 2.1:
Graphs of the first-order conditions around the intersection
point for HN=0.7 and HN=0.72
84
ix
1.
TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION AND UNEMPLOYMENT
1.1
Introduction
Human capital is known to have played a crucial role in the development process
of many economies.
The development of a more highly-skilled workforce through
improved educational and training opportunities have helped to enhance the
employability of workers at the individual level and reduce unemployment at the
aggregate level. The presence of skilled labour would, in turn, be a crucial factor in the
firm’s technology adoption decision, as implementation of newer and better technologies
is often infeasible without the presence of more highly-skilled workers.
Whilst it is true that firms may find it difficult to adopt new technologies, which
usually raise productivity, without the availability of skilled workers (for example, see
Haskel and Martin (1993); a mathematical exposition on the capital-skill complimentarily
is found in Lloyd-Ellis and Roberts (2002)), increases in the human capital of workers
actually present firms with the opportunity to implement a higher level of technology to
replace workers. For example, strikes by port workers from the United States over the
proposed retrenchment of workers involved in jobs that will be lost as a result of
automation is just one of many similar situations that have taken place throughout
history.1 The job of ticket conductors to punch bus tickets and collect payment was made
redundant with the introduction of various technologies to collect bus fares and dispense
bus tickets, enabling bus services to be run as one-man-operations. One good example
1
See, for example, The Wall Street Journal, 30 September 2002.
1
will be that of Singapore, where such a change has occurred in the late 1970s. IT
professionals have also found themselves becoming redundant as new variants of
computer technology become more intelligent. Highly-skilled journalists may no longer
require a cameraman to accompany them in news reporting should future technological
developments result in improved versions of the videophone.
Thus, technological
progress could potentially have destructive effects on employment, with serious
repercussions on job creation within the economy as well.
The above discussion leads to the following question: does improved skill profile
amongst the economically active result in increased employment? More importantly,
with the availability of better-skilled workers to work with better technology, will firms
take advantage of this to reduce the use of workers in the production process?
This paper attempts to study the relationship between technology adoption and
unemployment in a general equilibrium analysis. More importantly, our model considers
how the level of human capital within a small open economy affects the choice of
technology implemented by firms, which subsequently affect the employment situation
within the economy.
The underlying difference between the small open economy and the large
economy is its inability to play a significant role in pushing the world technological
frontier. Any advancement in the small open economy’s technology frontier is due to its
ability to adopt technologies quickly from the leading nations. Eaton and Kortum (1996)
did an empirical study to assess the proportion of a nation’s growth that can be attributed
2
to its own research efforts and found that such efforts within major economies, namely
United States, Japan and Germany, form a significant proportion of their growth. Nahuis
and van de Ven (1999) further postulated that efforts that concentrate on the adaptation of
technology are more appropriate for the small nations based on the empirical outcomes
from Eaton and Kortum (1996). Computations by Howitt and Mayer-Foulkes (2002)
revealed that 80% of the global R&D expenditure can be attributed to 5 countries, this
figure rising to 95% with the inclusion of another 6 countries, thus suggesting that most
other nations are embarking on technology adoption rather than being at the forefront of
the global technological frontier. Therefore, unlike previous works that incorporate the
research and development sector, this paper assumes that such a sector does not exist
directly in the small open economy, that is, the small open economy concentrates solely
on the adoption of technology.
There have been a myriad of reasons presented regarding the technology adoption
decisions of firms. These include the degree of willingness of workers to learn new skills
associated with such technologies, the age profile of such workers, asymmetric
information, availability of credit, externalities associated with network, market power
and learning, the required human capital level for implementation of a given technology
and the level of human capital available within the economy (see, for example, Besley
and Case (1993), Basu and Weil (1998) and Canton, de Groot and Nahuis (2002)). We
focus on the cost issues associated with the availability of human capital in the
implementation of a particular technology. To illustrate, suppose the United States has
developed a modern farming technology. With many studies showing that new variants
3
of technology are often skill-biased2, it is likely that such a technology is more suitable
for farmers in the United States and other nations that share similar levels of human
capital than the lowly-developed nations since they will be in a better position to make
productive use of that technology.
The availability of human capital plays a crucial role in the implementation of
higher levels of technology, which often comes at a price. Firms thus face both implicit
and explicit costs associated with such implementation. Explicit costs arise from the
effective per unit cost of implementation of such technologies for a given level of human
capital, which would generally include the purchase and installation of that unit as well as
the additional training required to help workers gain proficiency in using that particular
technology. Implicit costs may arise from the failure to harness fully the productive
capabilities of such technologies, such as the potential opportunity cost incurred to train
the workers during working hours as well as the possibility of damages caused resulting
from improper use of that state-of-the-art technology. Acemoglu and Zilibotti (2001)
highlighted that the mismatch between skill level and technology results in large
differences in productivity between the North and LDCs and that such skill shortages
play a key role in a multinational firm’s decision not to introduce such technologies in the
latter group of countries. Also, empirical studies by Bartoloni and Baussola (2001) on
the determinants influencing technology adoption decisions of Italian manufacturing
firms have revealed that the human capital level of a firm’s employees does play an
important role towards the firm’s decision on whether to adopt a certain technology.3
2
Empirical evidence on the skill-biased nature of technological innovations can be found in Berman, Bound and
Machin (1998), Machin and van Reenen (1998) and Morrison Paul and Siegel (2001).
3
An indirect manner in which higher levels of technology can have a negative impact on employment would be that
such technologies can actually allow firms to reorganize existing job scope to facilitate greater multi-tasking, subject to
the availability of workers with the desired level of human capital. Lindbeck and Snower (1996) noted that
technological advances have enabled firms to move from the Tayloristic structure to one that is more holistic. They
4
In our paper, the employment of workers is seen as an investment decision by the
firms due to the presence of labour market frictions, similar to that by Yashiv (2000).
Labour flow within the economy is determined by job creation and job destruction.
Conventional job matching technology (see Pissarides (2000)) dictates that the rate of job
match is determined by the unemployment and vacancy rates. Our paper takes on a
different approach by considering this probability as a function of human capital level
amongst the economically active and the level of unemployment. This suggests that from
the firm’s point of view, it is the skill profile and the availability of workers that will
determine whether a suitable applicant or interviewee can be matched to a position that
has been vacated due to job destruction or created due to various factors. In our paper,
we assume that these factors are taken into consideration in the firm’s decision in
selecting the number of interviewees for consideration. A wage bargaining curve, which
is dependent on the human capital of the workers and the level of employment within the
economy, is also introduced to endogenize the wage rate.
External and internal technological factors play the main role in the determination
of job destruction.
Our paper employs an implication resulting from the creative
destruction effect arising from an increase in the pace of technological progress. As
discussed in Aghion and Howitt (1994), growth is driven by the increase in knowledge
and that this knowledge is embodied via state-of-the-art technologies. Thus, a more rapid
increase in knowledge will translate into higher growth rates and higher job-turnover
gave the example of how increased use of computers in disseminating information within firms has enabled greater
complementarities across different tasks that were, in the past, clearly segregated. This would imply that firms can
actually require workers to undertake a wider job scope encompassing the different tasks with fewer workers. A more
complex work environment arising from such changes in the work environment, according to Tuijnman (1999), will
favour the more highly-skilled as they are more able to adapt to newer technologies and management strategies.
5
rates, with a more rapid introduction of new technologies leading to greater job
destruction.
Given the inability of the small open economy to shift the world
technological frontier, one can thus postulate that such effects are beyond the control of a
small open economy. Should the rate of creative destruction increase, the additional
value of introducing a relatively higher level of technology diminishes, since the time
available for the firm to recover various costs is reduced, which also reduces the
profitability of the firm’s production and will subsequently influence the firm’s decision
on job creation. On the whole, these will create a negative impact on job-loss within the
small open economy.
To endogenize overall job-loss, we incorporate the role of
domestic technology and human capital. This is in view of the increasingly workerreplacing capability of newer technologies that can be used in the production process
with the availability of better-trained workers in the workforce.
Our model uncovers an interesting result regarding the non-monotonic
relationship between technology adoption and employment under the onslaught of
increasing levels of human capital. Using appropriate parameters for our numerical
simulation, we find that while increases in human capital encourage adoption of higher
levels of technology and raises the sum of future discounted profits of an additional
worker, wages and interview rate, such increases can only raise employment up to a
threshold level of human capital.
Employment falls, or equivalently in our model,
unemployment rises upon the economy’s human capital level exceeding the threshold.
The adjustment process in the short run that brings about the above long-run outcome can
be summarized as follows. On the one hand, we have a job creation effect whereby
having higher-skilled workers means that it is easier to find workers and that you can
6
make better use of existing technology, which would contribute positively towards future
discounted profits and thus reducing job loss or promoting employment. However, we
have the job destruction effect where the presence of higher-skilled workers promotes
adoption of better technologies, thus raising the technological aspect of creative
destruction and job loss, reduces total future discounted profits (which is a negative
influence on job creation as well) and thus reduces employment. Before crossing the
threshold, the former effect dominates the latter. Recalling that the employment decision
of the firms is likened to that of an investment decision, increases in human capital level
that are below the threshold would actually result in the long-run outcome of higher
employment on the whole since there exist future gains in terms of higher total future
discounted profits by employing additional workers.
However, upon crossing the
threshold, the latter effect dominates. Thus, having additional workers over and above
the optimal level of employment will result in future losses in terms of lower total future
discounted profits from having these surplus workers, which will thus necessitate the
laying off or reduction in the optimal level of employment amongst the firms. Hence, we
have this non-monotonic relationship between unemployment and technology adoption
and also unemployment and human capital. Various comparative statics analysis will be
carried out to study the effect on employment, technology adoption, threshold level of
human capital, the sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker, wages and
interview rate upon changes in job matching, wage setting, global technological progress,
productivity and cost parameters.
The majority of existing literature has uncovered the relationship between human
capital and technology, human capital and unemployment and technology and
7
unemployment. Regarding the first instance, Nelson and Phelps (1966) showed that
human capital plays a crucial role in learning and technological diffusion. Acemoglu
(1997b) showed that an increase in human capital may or may not raise the level of
technology adopted. Chander and Thangavelu (2004) found that higher investment in
education by workers can provide the incentive for entrepreneurs to adopt better
technology. Empirical findings by Papageorgiou (2003) based on World Bank data
revealed that post-primary education contributes significantly towards technology
innovation and adoption whilst primary education contributes towards final output
production. Hollanders and Weel (2002) found a positive relationship between skill
upgrading and R&D intensity in manufacturing based on an empirical study of six OECD
countries.
Several writers have examined the issue of the relationship between technology
and unemployment, without incorporating the issue of human capital. Using a model of
frictional unemployment, the findings in Postel-Vinay (2002) do show that an increased
pace of technological progress raises equilibrium unemployment via job obsolescence.
However, the model does not feature any underlying mechanism that motivates firms to
adopt higher levels of technology. The findings by Aghion and Howitt (1994) suggest
that higher exogenous growth rate of leading technology can raise or lower
unemployment, depending on the rate of growth and that higher endogenous growth
arising from an increase in innovation size will strictly raise unemployment. Hoon (1993)
found that the effect of an increase in the level of technology on unemployment is
entirely transient in that unemployment rises only in the short run. However, increased
pace of technological progress will raise unemployment.
In an empirical study,
8
Danninger and Mincer (2000) found that an increase in the pace of technology has an
uncertain short-run impact on unemployment but can result in a fall in unemployment in
the long run as less skilled workers receive training. Nakanishi (2002) found in an
empirical study on Japan that there exists a negative relationship between IT capital and
labour and further indicated that the impact has increased during recent times.
Other writers have also studied the relationship between human capital and
unemployment. An increase in education capital is found to reduce unemployment by
Davis and Reeve (2003), regardless of whether the economy is closed or open. Empirical
studies by Richardson and van der Berg (2001) and Chan and Suen (2003) on evaluating
the effectiveness of training policies on employability of workers indicate that such
policies have a minimal impact on enhancing labour market performance. Nickell (1979)
has also found that there exists only a very limited impact of the number of years of
schooling from 13 years and above on unemployment rate.
Acemoglu (1997a) has attempted to incorporate all the above aspects. He found
that, subject to the extent of exogenous productivity increase, firms may or may not adopt
better technology. If the former is carried out, the firm will thus help enhance the human
capital of the workers. Such an outcome raises the proportion of skilled workers within
the workforce and would also lead to a reduction in unemployment. The findings here
seem to imply that increase in human capital is driven by technology adoption and that
unemployment falls as a consequence. His finding differs significantly from ours in that
we view the presence of human capital to be the driving force behind technology
9
adoption and that unemployment may or may not decrease depending on the strengths of
the job creation and job destruction effects.
To summarize, the above literature suggests that raising human capital level may
or may not result in implementation of higher level of technology. Faster technological
change or implementation of higher level of technology need not necessarily raise
equilibrium unemployment. The relationship between human capital and unemployment
cannot be clearly established. Our contribution is to integrate the aspects of human
capital and global technological advancement into a framework of unemployment and
technology adoption arising from changes in the former aspect, which is presently sorely
lacking in existing literature.
The rest of this chapter is organized as follows. Section 1.2 describes the various
aspects of the model and the optimization process. Steady-state and comparative statics
analysis of changes in human capital is carried out in section 1.3. We consider changes
in other parameters in section 1.4. Section 1.5 provides a general discussion of the
implications of the outcomes obtained. Section 1.6 concludes this chapter.
1.2
The Model
The economy consists of a collection of identical firms indexed from 0 to 1 that
are producing the final good. The population consists of economically active agents that
can also be indexed from 0 to 1, with Lt of these employed. Each agent is assumed to
possess an exogenous amount of human capital h, h∈(0,1], that is not technology-specific,
10
with the difference in level of human capital determining the degree of proficiency with a
given technology.4 It is also assumed that agents would not be looking for another job
when employed.
Each firm produces a single, all-encompassing final good of unitary price that is
identical across all firms, and operates within a perfectly competitive environment. Firm
i employs Lit of workers, and adopts a unit level of technology Ati that is freely available
for adoption, with Ati indexed from 0 to 1, at a cost of q units of final good per unit of
technology.
1.2.1
The Production Process
The firm requires a combination of technology, human capital and labour for
final-good production. Each of the firms in the economy takes on the Cobb-Douglas
production function which satisfies the usual Inada conditions:
F i ( hAti , Lit ) = B ( hAti ) Lit β
α
(1)
where α, β ∈(0, 1], and the superscript denotes the index associated with the firm. Here,
α represents the share of efficiency units of technology adopted by firms whilst β denotes
the production share attributed to the number of employed workers. No numerical
restriction is imposed regarding the sum of these two exponents. Thus, human capital,
4
We assume that human capital, h, is a slow moving variable that takes time to be accumulated. Therefore, we have
assumed it to be exogenous to allow us to focus on how changes to human capital will affect technology adoption and
unemployment.
11
technology and labour are seen as complementary in the production process. 5
We
augment human capital to technology rather than to labour in view of our assertion that
technology can only be an effective component of production through the implementation
of available knowledge. Rewriting the above production function to allow human capital
to augment labour would suggest that the total amount of effective workers increases at a
diminishing rate.6 B represents a productivity parameter that is exogenous to the firm.
Each firm also faces an exogenous per unit cost of technology q/h, which includes
the cost of the physical unit of that technology as well as training costs, with this cost
component decreasing in the human capital level of the economically active.
This
suggests that the availability of a better-trained workforce will help lower the cost of
adopting a particular level of technology. In the process, each infinitesimal improvement
in human capital presents firms the opportunity to make changes to existing work
practices and job scope of workers, which could lead to adjustments in employment, to
take advantage of possible use of higher levels of technology. For simplicity, the total
cost associated with technology implementation can be seen as a whole, rather than being
subjected to depreciation, upon the assumption that firms actually rent their machines
from an agency that supplies machines equipped with a given technology.
( q h ) Ati
Thus,
can be seen as the total cost of using machinery equipped with a certain
technology per time period t.
5
Given the Cobb-Douglas structure, human capital, technology and workers are complements. We thus conjecture that
the outcomes are likely to be the same if human capital is also endogenized. This issue can be explored in future
studies.
6
(
)
( ) ( h(
We may also rewrite the above production function as F i Ati , hLit = B Ati
α
α β)
Lit
)
β
, where effective labour
increases at a diminishing rate with respect to an increase in human capital.
12
1.2.2
Employment Decisions
Employment cost comprises of a recurring component and a one-off search cost.
Firms encounter a wage rate of wti units of final good per worker that is considered as
being exogenous to the firm.
Each firm also incurs search costs associated with
interviewing prospective applicants of job vacancies of b units of final good per
interviewed applicant. We also assume that firms face search costs which are increasing
in the number of interviews conducted.7 In the process, the firm thus also needs to decide
on the number of candidates Dit to be considered for an interview. In this paper, we
assume that the cost of selecting the candidates follows the specific quadratic form bDit2,
where b>0.
1.2.3 Job Matching and Creative Destruction Dynamics
The probability that the interviewee would be able to secure the job is dependent
on the average human capital level within the economy and the economy’s
unemployment level ut, which would be equivalent to (1-Lt). From the firm’s perspective,
a higher unemployment rate would mean a higher probability of finding that suitable
worker if there is a larger pool of unemployed workers to choose from. This can be seen
as a measure of tightness of the labour market. The average level of human capital is
included as it is in general easier for firms to find the suitable worker within an economy
with more better-skilled workers. Thus, the number of successful job interviewees that
7
Search costs can increase at an increasing rate through the tasks that can be undertaken due to loss of working time in
the process of interviewing prospective applicants, which can otherwise be used to raise output in a more than
proportionate manner. For example, the time taken to interview five candidates consecutively to fill up extra vacancies
can be used to do an amount of work that is more than five times that of the time taken for one candidate due to human
factors. The availability of a choice of candidates also leads to increased time required to select the worker arising
from the analytical process of selecting the right candidate.
13
are offered employment can be written as ς(h)utεDit, where ς(h) is a function that
generates a probability attributed to the human capital component in the selection process,
with ς’(h)>0 and ς’’(h) 0 ). The movement in the north-east direction
suggests the presence of a complementary effect that is stronger than that of the
substitution effect, thus raising the level of technology adopted and employment. With
an anticipated change, a jump in the level of technology implemented that is lower than
that of the instantaneous case occurs. We find that A&t and L&t will be positive and
negative respectively. The economy actually experiences a fall in employment, whilst
experiencing increasing levels of technology implemented along its adjustment trajectory
until it reaches the saddle path, whereby the economy will experience increasing
employment and level of technology adopted until it arrives at the equilibrium point.
Here, firms make the adjustment to implement better technology and releasing existing
workers prior to the increase in the average skill-profile workers since the overall higher
cost of technology implementation makes it not optimal to employ the existing number of
workers to work with the better technology as the net discounted future profit of having
the additional worker is negative. Once the changes actually take effect, firms will, at
this point, actually seek to hire workers to work with better technology as implementation
costs fall and output increases, with positive net discounted future profits from employing
additional workers, until arrival at saddle-path equilibrium. Again, the complementary
effect is much stronger relative to the substitution effect, thus resulting in higher level of
technology adoption and employment, the latter surpassing the previous level of
employment. The net effects arising from the short run adjustment process under either
type of change would thus be the positive effects of an increase in human capital on job
creation outweighing the negative effects of the same increase on job destruction.
30
Figure 1.3: Effect of an increase in h when h is below the threshold level of human
capital
At
New A&t = 0
Saddle
-Path
Old A&t = 0
New L&t = 0
Old L&t = 0
Lt
In the second scenario and with an unanticipated increase in h, we have an
immediate upward jump in the level of technology. This time, both A&t and L&t are
negative at that point after the upward jump. The latter thus suggests that the costs
associated with the technological and overall job loss impact of creative destruction
through adoption of better technologies now outweigh that of the benefits associated with
ease of finding workers and better use of existing technology. At the higher level of
human capital, the technological impact of creative destruction is now sufficiently large
enough and that acquiring more workers to work with better technology reduces
undiscounted profits and that each additional worker reduces net future discounted profits
31
(i.e. λ&t < 0 ).
From that point on, the firms should thus seek to lower both the level of
technology adopted and the number of workers employed in view of the optimal solution
lying along the demarcation curves.
With the technological impact of creative
destruction now sufficiently large, it would make sense for the firm to reduce
employment since the presence of these surplus workers actually reduce the current and
discounted future profits that the firm can enjoy. To elaborate further, on the one hand,
whilst having better-educated workers enables the firm to be able to work better with
existing technology, the advantage of ease of finding workers in an economy with bettereducated workers has diminished. Moreover, there is a slowdown in the increase of the
sum of discounted future profits from employing an additional worker as h increases. On
the other hand, the creative destruction impact of technology has become stronger such
that raising the technology level slightly, at a given level of employment, can raise job
loss rate very quickly. We thus have the situation where the substation effect outweighs
the complementary effect, as seen from the south-west movement towards the saddlepoint equilibrium. The south-west movement suggests that firms immediately implement
high levels of technology, but subsequently find that the costs of using that technology
with the higher-skilled and more highly-paid workers exceeding the gains in output of
using that technology. Thus, the large extent of shift in A&t = 0 can be seen as the
presence of a relatively and increasingly larger extent of substitution away from labour
and towards technology across all levels of employment. When the increase in the level
of human capital is anticipated, the economy will witness a jump in the level of
technology implemented that will be less than that of the instantaneous case. The extent
of the jump will determine the point the economy will attain on the new saddle path upon
32
Figure 1.4: Effect of an increase in h when h is above the threshold level of human
capital
At
New A&t = 0
Old A&t = 0
Saddle
-Path
New L&t = 0
Old L&t = 0
Lt
the increase. If this change is set to occur very soon, the economy is likely to jump
vertically upward to a point just below the new saddle path, with firms raising the level of
technology implemented and reducing employment. Upon arriving at the new saddle
path at the time the change takes effect, the economy will take on the same changes as
that of the unanticipated change. However, should the increase in human capital take a
longer time to take effect, the extent of the vertical jump is likely to be lower. The
economy will nevertheless embark on an adjustment process similar to the situation
33
discussed earlier, with the subsequent adjustment process upon the change taking place
similar to that of scenario 1, where once the change takes effect, the cumulative actions
of all firms would be to increase the level of technology further whilst using more
workers to work with the technology. Nevertheless, employment levels will not attain
the same levels as before due to the substitution effect outweighing the complementary
effect, with employment below its previous level prior to the increase in h. On the whole,
in terms of the net effects, the positive effects of an increase in human capital on job
creation are now outweighed by the negative effects of the same increase on job
destruction during the short run adjustment process under either type of change.
One implicit indication of the slowdown in equilibrium employment that
subsequently leads to a fall in employment arises from a decreasing rate of increase in the
equilibrium value of λt for any given increasing value of h at the saddle-path stable
equilibrium values of At and Lt. This is an indication that, beyond the threshold value of
h, keeping employment unchanged or raising employment when implementing higher
levels of technology would not be optimal as the additional output generated by having
the extra worker would only lead to a reduction in the firm’s profit since the net
discounted future profit is negative. The fact that the intersection point on the new
L&t = 0 curve is to the left of the previous intersection suggests that firms are more than
willing to employ less workers in favour of using better technology, which indicates
greater dominance of the technology mechanism of creative destruction. This would also
implicitly suggest that the firm’s profitability would be compromised if employment is
not reduced since the additional output generated by having the additional worker over
and above the optimal number of workers would not be sufficient to cover the costs of
34
keeping that worker. By employing fewer workers, firms do seek to suppress the overall
job loss, which would aim to soften the increase in costs associated with creative
destruction. Nevertheless, the creative destructive impact of technology arising from
relatively cheaper implementation costs based on a continually falling share of total costs
does continue to increase even beyond the threshold level of human capital, indicating
that firms increasingly use technology to replace workers in production.
We briefly discuss the impact of an increase in h on other variables. An increase
in h would raise the equilibrium value of λt throughout. Note that the availability of
better-skilled workers raises the marginal product of technology while reducing the
marginal cost counterpart. Subject to the technological impact of creative destruction,
optimal behaviour by all firms would require consideration of the labour-technology mix
such that there is an incentive in using these higher-skilled workers in the form of net
discounted future profit from employing that additional worker.
However, this
equilibrium net discounted future profit increases at a decreasing rate owing to the
increasing creative destruction impact arising from increasing levels of technology
adopted in the presence of higher-skilled workers.
We also note that the increase in h would lead to an increase in wages. The extent
of increase is higher than proportionate prior to the threshold owing to the improved
bargaining power arising from higher employment. Firms will need to pay more to hire
workers owing both to the human capital aspect as well as a premium attributed to the
higher probability of a worker being able to find an alternative job to encourage the
worker to take up the job. Beyond the threshold, an increase in h would still lead to
35
higher wages but the wages now increase in a lower than proportionate manner due to
reduced bargaining power arising from lower employment.
The firms can actually
reduce the premium paid to the worker to fill the job since it is now harder to find a job
from the viewpoint of the worker and easier from that of the firm.
An increase in h would also raise the economy’s interview rate. This can be
attributed to the fact that having more skilled workers in the economy raises the
probability of finding a suitable worker. Indirectly, there is also an increased need to
replace workers arising from greater job destruction. For levels of human capital below
the threshold level, the pace of increase is slower owing to the opposing force arising
from reduced unemployment, which shrinks the pool of workers available for hire. The
pace of increase picks up when h is beyond the threshold since the pool of workers
available for hire increases.
The following summarizes the above findings concerning employment and level
of technology adopted:
Proposition 2: For levels of human capital below the threshold level, an increase in
human capital would raise the level of technology implemented and employment. For
levels of human capital above the threshold level, an increase in human capital would
raise the level of technology implemented but reduces employment.
Proof: See 1.7.2.
36
1.4
Changes in Other Parameters
This section provides a brief account and intuition of the effects of various
parameter changes on employment, technology adoption, threshold level of human
capital, future marginal discounted revenue of an additional worker, interviews and
wages. For all cases, we find that the behaviour of the system as h increases remains the
same as the discussion above with respect to the transition that the slopes of the
demarcation curves undergo. Tables 1.5 to 1.13 provide a numerical summary of the
changes to various variables as the values of the exogenous parameters changes. A 5%
increase is considered in most cases, with the exception of selected parameters such as
overall collective wage bargaining parameter, cost per unit vacancy and interest rate. For
ease of discussion, we consider only an increase in the relevant parameters unless
otherwise indicated. The opposite outcome prevails when the direction of change is
reversed. Table 1.4 summarizes the outcomes.
Table 1.4: Summary of outcomes of comparative statics exercise of an increase in
respective parameters in 1.4.1 to 1.4.5
Matching parameters
Wage parameters
Global tech progress
Productivity parameter
Cost parameters
Interest rate
Parameter
Lt
At
λt
wt
Dt
ε
δ
χ
-
+
+
+
-
+
+
+
-
γ
+
+
+
-
+
ψ
z
B
b
q
r
+
+
+
-
+
+
+
+
+
-
+
+
-
+
+
+
-
Thresh-old h
+
+
no
change
+
+
+
+
Current
Profit
+
+
+
37
1.4.1 Matching Parameters
Increases in either the human capital matching function parameter ε or the
matching parameter associated with unemployed workers δ results in a reduction in both
the level of employment and technology adopted. However, such an increase actually
raises the sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker and threshold level of
human capital. Looking at (8’), increased marginal product of technology together with a
reduction in the marginal creative destruction attributed to technology has resulted in the
increase in the sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker. This allows the
job creation effect to continue to dominate the job destruction effect, which had been
reduced by the fall in employment and technology level, at higher levels of human capital
resulting in a higher threshold level. In addition, it is more difficult to find workers when
ε or δ increases since the probability of finding the suitable worker falls, thus leading to
lower employment. Firms would therefore be better off to reduce technology level as
well to ensure no net discounted future profits of an additional worker.
Reduced
employment results in a fall in wages. The fall in wages together with an increase in the
sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker leads to an increase in the
interview rate.
1.4.2 Wage Setting Parameters
When the overall collective wage bargaining power has become stronger (i.e.
increase in χ), this leads to an upward shift of only the locus of A&t = 0 . This encourages
38
Table 1.5: Simulation results for (a) ε = 0.2 and (b) ε = 0.3
(a) ε = 0.2
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6300
0.6375
0.6400
0.6425
0.6500
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.930855
0.937213
0.939603
0.939773
0.939782
0.939783
0.939781
0.939769
0.939384
0.937207
0.93342
0.930995
At
0.180144
0.280378
0.399243
0.438122
0.448052
0.451381
0.454718
0.464784
0.533824
0.680329
0.834042
0.911900
λt
0.233733
0.253985
0.269985
0.274078
0.275054
0.275375
0.275694
0.276640
0.282494
0.292016
0.298925
0.301495
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6700
0.6725
0.6750
0.6775
0.6800
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.925035
0.933304
0.936901
0.937603
0.937606
0.937608
0.937608
0.937606
0.937546
0.936056
0.932867
0.930722
At
0.178037
0.277888
0.396496
0.489207
0.492648
0.496098
0.499556
0.503022
0.531044
0.677878
0.832456
0.911006
λt
0.252015
0.269019
0.281741
0.288582
0.288798
0.289012
0.289225
0.289436
0.291056
0.297532
0.301579
0.302794
wt
0.057891
0.073057
0.087982
0.092404
0.093139
0.093506
0.093872
0.094239
0.095337
0.102612
0.116891
0.130759
Dt
0.195866
0.210036
0.226229
0.231518
0.232872
0.233327
0.233782
0.235158
0.244653
0.265303
0.287997
0.300001
zAth
0.035265
0.037066
0.040350
0.041620
0.041959
0.042073
0.042189
0.042541
0.045110
0.051437
0.059452
0.064128
zAthLt
0.032827
0.034738
0.037913
0.039113
0.039432
0.039540
0.039648
0.039979
0.042376
0.048207
0.055494
0.059703
Profit
0.077583
0.097365
0.116952
0.122782
0.123752
0.124236
0.124721
0.125205
0.126656
0.136291
0.155311
0.173922
Dt
0.202269
0.215231
0.230292
0.242191
0.242637
0.243084
0.243533
0.243983
0.247636
0.267247
0.288939
0.300463
zAth
0.035100
0.036901
0.040183
0.043357
0.043484
0.043612
0.043741
0.043871
0.044946
0.051288
0.059350
0.064068
zAthLt
0.032468
0.034439
0.037647
0.040652
0.040771
0.040891
0.041012
0.041134
0.042139
0.048009
0.055366
0.059630
Profit
0.077270
0.097096
0.116722
0.130317
0.130800
0.131283
0.131766
0.132248
0.136101
0.155169
0.173841
0.182996
(b) ε = 0.3
wt
0.057385
0.072631
0.087628
0.097954
0.098320
0.098685
0.099051
0.099416
0.102331
0.116690
0.130650
0.137465
Table 1.6: Simulation results for (a) δ = 0.5 and (b) δ = 0.7
(a) δ = 0.5
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6075
0.6100
0.6125
0.6200
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.952738
0.956937
0.958207
0.958216
0.958216
0.958215
0.958206
0.957504
0.955249
0.951643
0.949370
At
0.186798
0.290551
0.414020
0.424004
0.427354
0.430713
0.440854
0.554451
0.708111
0.870166
0.952536
λt
0.189896
0.206456
0.220423
0.221382
0.221700
0.222016
0.222956
0.232323
0.242437
0.250908
0.254549
wt
0.059806
0.075219
0.090430
0.091562
0.091939
0.092315
0.093445
0.105394
0.120053
0.134346
0.141336
Dt
0.179909
0.193061
0.208688
0.209667
0.210397
0.210828
0.212131
0.226988
0.247989
0.271550
0.284188
zAth
0.035781
0.037732
0.041239
0.041565
0.041675
0.041787
0.042127
0.046324
0.053110
0.061765
0.066840
zAthLt
0.034089
0.036107
0.039516
0.039828
0.039934
0.040041
0.040366
0.044355
0.050734
0.058778
0.063456
Profit
0.078311
0.098183
0.117882
0.119363
0.119840
0.120329
0.121796
0.137353
0.156528
0.175314
0.184526
39
(b) δ = 0.7
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6200
0.6275
0.6300
0.6325
0.6400
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.913233
0.919936
0.922356
0.922466
0.922480
0.922481
0.922481
0.922470
0.921904
0.919294
0.914941
0.912204
At
0.175558
0.272753
0.387501
0.412299
0.421742
0.424906
0.428080
0.437649
0.516706
0.656457
0.802051
0.875392
λt
0.257136
0.283969
0.305068
0.308678
0.309983
0.310411
0.310837
0.312098
0.321273
0.333238
0.341526
0.344452
wt
0.056363
0.071179
0.085729
0.088602
0.089675
0.090033
0.090390
0.091460
0.099949
0.113775
0.127149
0.133651
Dt
0.202437
0.218520
0.236137
0.239871
0.241290
0.241765
0.242242
0.243678
0.255534
0.276708
0.299456
0.311308
zAth
0.034903
0.036558
0.039633
0.040414
0.040721
0.040825
0.040930
0.041249
0.044093
0.049988
0.057396
0.061687
zAthLt
0.031875
0.033631
0.036556
0.037280
0.037564
0.037660
0.037757
0.038051
0.040649
0.045953
0.052514
0.056271
Profit
0.077155
0.096812
0.116259
0.120118
0.121562
0.122043
0.122524
0.123965
0.135434
0.154263
0.172650
0.181642
firms to reduce the employment of workers and increase the level of technology used, as
it is now more costly to make use of the former. The sum of discounted future profits of
an additional worker, number of interviews and threshold level of human capital have all
decreased as a result. Since it now costs more to employ workers, firms would seek to
try to replace the use of workers with technology where possible, which subsequently
raises the job loss rate. Looking at (8’), the sum of discounted future profits of an
additional worker would fall due to the greater impact of creative destruction relative to
the marginal product of technology. The fall in the sum of discounted future profits of an
additional worker plays a crucial role here in the determination of the threshold level of
human capital. The overall effect of job creation, as a result of the preceding decrease,
has been weakened as firms are reluctant to hire workers due to lower per-worker
contribution to discounted future profits. The technology impact of job destruction is
now stronger due to the higher level of technology implemented. This increase in
technological implementation motivates greater substitution away from labour towards
technology across all levels of employment, which will raise the job destruction effect.
Weakened job creation together with stronger job destruction would result in the pace of
shift of L&t = 0 being relatively slower to that of A&t = 0 at a lower value of h,
40
subsequently lowering the new threshold level. The fall in employment is the main factor
behind the fall in wages. A relatively larger fall in the sum of discounted future profits of
an additional worker compared to the fall in employment pushes the interview rate down.
Increases in either the values of ψ and γ will result in an increase in the level of
employment but a fall in the level of technology adopted. The sum of discounted future
profits of an additional worker has also increased. However, the threshold value of
human capital remains unchanged for the latter case and increases in the former. An
increase in ψ in this context can be seen as a reduction in emphasis of the human capital
factor in wage bargaining. This lowers the wage costs, hence providing firms with the
incentive to use more workers and reduce the level of technology used. A similar
analogy can be used for an increase in γ, the employment level factor in wage bargaining.
The increase in threshold level with respect to an increase in ψ can be seen in light of the
reduced job loss from creative destruction effect attributed to lower technology levels
being adopted across all values of h relative to job creation. In the case of γ, it is likely
that the effect of lower wage costs of employing workers is exactly matched by the effect
of overall job loss from increased employment, hence no change in threshold level of
human capital. The sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker increases in
both cases and this is likely to be due to the impact of higher marginal product of
technology relative to the creative destruction impact from (8’).
The interview rate
increases as the advantage of increased total discounted future profits of an additional
worker exceeds the disadvantage of a reduced pool of workers to choose from.
41
Table 1.7: Simulation results for (a) 10% fall in χ (=0.144) and (b) 10% rise in χ (=0.176)
(a) 10% fall in χ (=0.144)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6150
0.6200
0.6225
0.6250
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.935573
0.940940
0.942746
0.942793
0.942797
0.942797
0.942796
0.942789
0.942168
0.939773
0.935869
0.933418
At
0.181028
0.281221
0.399828
0.419032
0.425509
0.428761
0.432023
0.438573
0.533830
0.679298
0.831360
0.908116
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6150
0.6175
0.6200
0.6250
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.931449
0.937061
0.938914
0.938947
0.938954
0.938956
0.938955
0.938951
0.938232
0.935601
0.931334
0.928652
At
0.181243
0.281906
0.401296
0.414160
0.420651
0.423911
0.427180
0.433747
0.536505
0.683736
0.838252
0.916527
λt
0.233777
0.256430
0.274682
0.277090
0.277875
0.278264
0.278651
0.279418
0.289271
0.300692
0.309316
0.312675
wt
0.052472
0.066118
0.079555
0.081549
0.082213
0.082544
0.082876
0.083538
0.092734
0.105605
0.118115
0.124220
Dt
0.196573
0.211622
0.228670
0.231416
0.232343
0.232808
0.233275
0.234213
0.247937
0.269420
0.292919
0.305306
(b) 10% rise in χ (=0.176)
λt
0.216151
0.236893
0.253662
0.255148
0.255879
0.256241
0.256601
0.257316
0.267113
0.277685
0.285699
0.288830
wt
0.063738
0.080345
0.096681
0.098297
0.099104
0.099507
0.099910
0.100715
0.112680
0.128271
0.143385
0.150741
Dt
0.188644
0.203105
0.219540
0.221303
0.222193
0.222639
0.223088
0.223988
0.238170
0.259007
0.281877
0.293968
zAth
0.035334
0.037121
0.040385
0.041000
0.041212
0.041319
0.041428
0.041647
0.045111
0.051374
0.059280
0.063875
zAthLt
0.033058
0.034929
0.038073
0.038654
0.038854
0.038956
0.039058
0.039264
0.042502
0.048280
0.055478
0.059622
Profit
0.083038
0.104228
0.125182
0.128301
0.129339
0.129858
0.130376
0.131413
0.145832
0.166093
0.185858
0.195515
zAth
0.035351
0.037166
0.040474
0.040886
0.041097
0.041204
0.041312
0.041531
0.045269
0.051643
0.059722
0.064437
zAthLt
0.032928
0.034827
0.038002
0.038389
0.038588
0.038689
0.038790
0.038995
0.042473
0.048317
0.055621
0.059840
Profit
0.072484
0.090829
0.109028
0.110838
0.111742
0.112194
0.112646
0.113550
0.127035
0.144789
0.162210
0.170765
Table 1.8: Simulation results for (a) γ = 1.1 and (b) γ = 1.7
(a) γ = 1.1
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6175
0.6200
0.6225
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.933163
0.938711
0.940556
0.940590
0.940601
0.940602
0.940601
0.940590
0.939913
0.937364
0.933216
0.930608
At
0.181171
0.281646
0.400719
0.413543
0.423262
0.426521
0.429789
0.439649
0.535442
0.681977
0.835553
0.913263
λt
0.223196
0.244884
0.262323
0.263864
0.264996
0.265369
0.265739
0.266839
0.276218
0.287036
0.295128
0.298242
wt
0.059311
0.074623
0.089742
0.091241
0.092364
0.092738
0.093112
0.094233
0.104620
0.119209
0.133458
0.140439
Dt
0.191855
0.206636
0.223355
0.225145
0.226502
0.226957
0.227413
0.228790
0.242244
0.263308
0.286364
0.298528
zAth
0.035345
0.037149
0.040439
0.040848
0.041165
0.041273
0.041381
0.041711
0.045206
0.051536
0.059549
0.064219
zAthLt
0.032983
0.034872
0.038035
0.038422
0.038720
0.038821
0.038923
0.039233
0.042490
0.048308
0.055572
0.059763
Profit
0.076626
0.096211
0.115566
0.117486
0.118924
0.119403
0.119882
0.121317
0.134621
0.153296
0.171487
0.180365
42
(b) γ = 1.7
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6175
0.6200
0.6225
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.934012
0.939441
0.941255
0.941290
0.941301
0.941302
0.941301
0.941292
0.940639
0.938167
0.934149
0.931627
At
0.181126
0.281516
0.400450
0.413256
0.422961
0.426215
0.429478
0.439323
0.534947
0.681121
0.834133
0.911460
λt
0.226830
0.248569
0.266166
0.267726
0.268875
0.269253
0.269630
0.270747
0.280311
0.291472
0.299991
0.303349
wt
0.056987
0.071940
0.086611
0.088060
0.089145
0.089506
0.089867
0.090948
0.100934
0.114838
0.128254
0.134758
Dt
0.193489
0.208242
0.225024
0.226824
0.228189
0.228646
0.229105
0.230492
0.244048
0.265315
0.288637
0.300955
zAth
0.035342
0.037141
0.040423
0.040831
0.041147
0.041254
0.041362
0.041692
0.045177
0.051485
0.059458
0.064099
zAthLt
0.033010
0.034891
0.038048
0.038434
0.038732
0.038833
0.038934
0.039244
0.042495
0.048301
0.055543
0.059716
Profit
0.078803
0.098739
0.118519
0.120486
0.121961
0.122452
0.122943
0.124416
0.138095
0.157404
0.176357
0.185666
Table 1.9: Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in ψ (=0.95) and (b) 5% rise in ψ (=1.05)
(a) 5% fall in ψ (=0.95)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6200
0.6250
0.6275
0.6300
0.6350
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.932614
0.938392
0.940413
0.940491
0.940496
0.940496
0.940495
0.940489
0.939929
0.937541
0.933575
0.931070
At
0.181196
0.281699
0.400772
0.426567
0.433111
0.436397
0.439692
0.446309
0.535432
0.681792
0.835014
0.912454
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6125
0.6150
0.6175
0.6200
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.934503
0.939735
0.941390
0.941411
0.941412
0.941412
0.941411
0.941408
0.940629
0.938005
0.933813
0.931192
At
0.181098
0.281462
0.400396
0.413205
0.416431
0.419667
0.422913
0.426167
0.534954
0.681296
0.834651
0.912238
λt
0.220898
0.243302
0.261551
0.264765
0.265547
0.265935
0.266321
0.267086
0.276303
0.288002
0.296982
0.300541
wt
0.060766
0.075767
0.090367
0.093237
0.093952
0.094309
0.094666
0.095378
0.104543
0.118261
0.131480
0.137890
Dt
0.190814
0.205942
0.223019
0.226693
0.227625
0.228093
0.228563
0.229507
0.242282
0.263747
0.287234
0.299624
(b) 5% rise in ψ (=1.05)
λt
0.228977
0.250074
0.266920
0.268402
0.268768
0.269131
0.269491
0.26985
0.280254
0.290569
0.298227
0.301152
wt
0.055603
0.070835
0.085992
0.087500
0.087877
0.088253
0.088630
0.089006
0.100985
0.115732
0.130148
0.137210
Dt
0.194448
0.208894
0.225350
0.227116
0.227561
0.228007
0.228455
0.228904
0.244023
0.264908
0.287816
0.299915
zAth
0.035347
0.037153
0.040442
0.041275
0.041493
0.041603
0.041714
0.041939
0.045205
0.051525
0.059514
0.064165
zAthLt
0.032966
0.034864
0.038032
0.038819
0.039024
0.039127
0.039232
0.039443
0.042490
0.048307
0.055561
0.059742
Profit
0.075264
0.095135
0.114976
0.118933
0.119921
0.120415
0.120909
0.121896
0.134694
0.154186
0.173337
0.182743
zAth
0.035340
0.037137
0.040420
0.040828
0.040933
0.041038
0.041144
0.041251
0.045177
0.051495
0.059491
0.064151
zAthLt
0.033025
0.034899
0.038051
0.038436
0.038534
0.038634
0.038734
0.038834
0.042495
0.048303
0.055554
0.059737
Profit
0.080101
0.099780
0.119103
0.121015
0.121493
0.121970
0.122447
0.122924
0.138047
0.156564
0.174583
0.183378
43
1.4.3 Rate of Global Technological Progress
As discussed earlier, the economies in question here depend very much on the
extent of global technological advancement. A higher rate of progress, i.e. higher z,
actually encourages the use of lower levels of technology and reduces employment in our
model. However, the threshold level of human capital increases when z is higher. The
direction of change in the level of technology and employment can be accounted by the
fact that an increase in z would affect the sum of discounted future profits of an additional
worker and changes the rate of creative destruction and thus job loss rate. With an
increase in z, the reduction in total discounted future profits and higher costs associated
with job loss and creative destruction result, which leads to a reduction in employment
and also technology level. It is somewhat ironic that the threshold level of human capital
increases when z increases and vice-versa. However, this can be seen in view of the fact
that a higher rate of technological progress would make firms more conservative in
technology usage due to the higher rate of creative destruction and job loss and the higher
share of costs spent on conducting interviews to fill up the vacancies. Thus it is more
cost optimal to hold on to the use of workers until their human capital level is sufficiently
high (i.e. at a higher threshold), where it would then be relatively more cost efficient to
make use of technology rather than workers. The increase in z reduces the sum of
discounted future profits of an additional worker and wages and increases the number of
interviews conducted. The reduction in the sum of discounted future profits arises due to
the increased creative destruction effect whilst the fall in wages can be attributed to
reduced employment.
The interview rate increases because the effect of a fall in
employment exceeds that of a fall in the sum of discounted future profits of employing an
44
additional worker. As indicated in our introduction, this overall increase in creative
destruction does lead to reduced undiscounted profits in our model since the lifetime of
the technology is reduced and this is supported by our simulation outcomes. Thus, the
firms’ technology adoption behaviour when z increases indicates that they are seeking to
extend the use of technology for as long as possible in order to attain sufficiently high
profitability, thus they do not have the room to upgrade their technologies too often.
Table 1.10: Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in z (=0.0665) and (b) 5% rise in z
(=0.0735)
(a) 5% fall in z (=0.0665)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6150
0.6175
0.6200
0.6250
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.936392
0.941631
0.943352
0.943382
0.943388
0.943389
0.943389
0.943384
0.942704
0.940231
0.936222
0.933702
At
0.182243
0.283331
0.403251
0.416175
0.422696
0.425971
0.429256
0.435854
0.539116
0.687138
0.842574
0.921349
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6150
0.6200
0.6225
0.6250
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.930837
0.936569
0.938506
0.938558
0.938563
0.938563
0.938562
0.938556
0.937901
0.935361
0.931215
0.928612
At
0.180069
0.279856
0.397959
0.417077
0.423525
0.426763
0.430009
0.436530
0.531340
0.676066
0.827279
0.903580
λt
0.226328
0.248182
0.265832
0.267395
0.268163
0.268544
0.268923
0.269675
0.279976
0.291085
0.299504
0.302793
wt
0.058374
0.073540
0.088474
0.089952
0.090690
0.091059
0.091428
0.092165
0.103120
0.117419
0.131309
0.138081
Dt
0.188853
0.203374
0.219892
0.221664
0.222559
0.223008
0.223459
0.224365
0.238634
0.259622
0.282690
0.294900
(b) 5% rise in z (=0.0735)
λt
0.223822
0.245398
0.262792
0.265087
0.265835
0.266206
0.266574
0.267305
0.276698
0.287583
0.295795
0.298988
wt
0.057890
0.072987
0.087838
0.090041
0.090774
0.091140
0.091506
0.092237
0.102385
0.116568
0.130326
0.137029
Dt
0.196383
0.211382
0.228352
0.231084
0.232006
0.232469
0.232933
0.233866
0.247509
0.268841
0.292141
0.304409
zAth
0.033658
0.035397
0.038563
0.038957
0.039159
0.039261
0.039365
0.039574
0.043152
0.049256
0.056999
0.061521
zAthLt
0.031517
0.033331
0.036378
0.036751
0.036942
0.037039
0.037136
0.037333
0.040679
0.046312
0.053364
0.057442
Profit
0.077902
0.097690
0.117293
0.119242
0.120215
0.120701
0.121187
0.122159
0.136657
0.155711
0.174362
0.183503
zAth
0.037022
0.038883
0.042285
0.042926
0.043147
0.043259
0.043372
0.043601
0.047212
0.053738
0.061969
0.066751
zAthLt
0.034462
0.036416
0.039685
0.040289
0.040496
0.040601
0.040707
0.040922
0.044280
0.050264
0.057706
0.061985
Profit
0.077562
0.097298
0.116835
0.119745
0.120713
0.121197
0.121681
0.122648
0.136112
0.155054
0.173566
0.182624
45
1.4.4 Productivity Parameter
An increase in the productivity parameter B would lead to an increase in both the
level of technology implemented and employment, and vice-versa.
However, the
increase in productivity would actually lower the threshold level of human capital. The
sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker is raised when B increases as the
effect of increased productivity raises the marginal product of technology from (8’)
relative to the creative destruction effect at all levels of At. It is likely that the subsequent
effect of an increase in job creation is not as strong as that of creative destruction, as an
increase in productivity can be seen to be dampening the significance of human capital in
production. Subsequently, the demarcation curve for L&t = 0 can thus be considered to
shift less quickly relative to the demarcation curve for A&t = 0 at a lower level of human
capital, thus resulting in the lower threshold level of human capital. Wages increase due
to the higher probability of workers finding employment. The economy’s interview rate
increases as the effect of increased total discounted future profits of an additional worker
overwhelms the fall in number of unemployed workers to choose from.
Table 1.11: Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in B (=0.475) and (b) 5% rise in B (=0.525)
(a) 5% fall in B (=0.475)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6300
0.6325
0.6350
0.6375
0.6400
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.931327
0.937374
0.939616
0.939758
0.939761
0.939762
0.939761
0.939759
0.939324
0.937112
0.933306
0.930872
At
0.167656
0.260987
0.371852
0.408165
0.411250
0.414343
0.417445
0.420556
0.497677
0.635103
0.779936
0.853606
λt
0.209042
0.229380
0.245892
0.250202
0.250549
0.250893
0.251236
0.251577
0.259214
0.269766
0.277861
0.281067
wt
0.057933
0.073075
0.087984
0.092402
0.092769
0.093136
0.093503
0.093869
0.102603
0.116874
0.130736
0.137496
Dt
0.182636
0.196075
0.211345
0.216322
0.216745
0.217170
0.217595
0.218023
0.228667
0.248063
0.269393
0.280693
zAth
0.034266
0.035761
0.038665
0.039804
0.039904
0.040006
0.040108
0.040211
0.042950
0.048683
0.055969
0.060227
zAthLt
0.031913
0.033521
0.036330
0.037406
0.037501
0.037596
0.037692
0.037789
0.040344
0.045621
0.052237
0.056064
Profit
0.068075
0.085343
0.102473
0.107580
0.108005
0.108429
0.108854
0.109278
0.119426
0.136145
0.152562
0.160629
46
(b) 5% rise in B (=0.525)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6025
0.6050
0.6075
0.6100
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.935517
0.940501
0.941954
0.941956
0.941957
0.941957
0.941955
0.941012
0.938220
0.933874
0.931183
At
0.194978
0.302672
0.429973
0.433380
0.436796
0.440223
0.443660
0.573500
0.728849
0.890568
0.971868
λt
0.240559
0.263553
0.281998
0.282408
0.282816
0.283222
0.283625
0.296655
0.308034
0.316156
0.319771
wt
0.058298
0.073416
0.088290
0.088658
0.089026
0.089394
0.089762
0.102861
0.117068
0.130848
0.137560
Dt
0.202380
0.218469
0.236703
0.237189
0.237676
0.238165
0.238656
0.257303
0.280247
0.305300
0.318481
zAth
0.036399
0.038511
0.042185
0.042297
0.042410
0.042524
0.042638
0.047432
0.054351
0.063066
0.068128
zAthLt
0.034052
0.036220
0.039737
0.039842
0.039948
0.040055
0.040163
0.044634
0.050993
0.058896
0.063440
Profit
0.087680
0.109994
0.132056
0.132604
0.133151
0.133699
0.134246
0.153792
0.175107
0.195882
0.206024
1.4.5 Cost Parameters
An increase in the interview cost per interviewee, b, which raises production costs,
will lead to a reduction in both the level of technology implemented and the employment
of workers. Since this cost component is a one-off cost, such an increase does not, in a
sense, have an impact on the total discounted future profits of an additional worker
directly, thus we do not see the outcome as in the increase in χ. The increase in the sum
of discounted future profits of an additional worker is likely to be due to the fact that with
reduced employment, the marginal product of each additional worker will thus increase,
with this effect being sufficiently strong enough to bring about this result. We also find
that the threshold level of human capital has increased.
This case is somewhat
complicated by the finding that there is an increase in the equilibrium sum of discounted
future profits of an additional worker. One way to reconcile this is simply that as the
number of workers employed falls, the marginal product of each worker actually
increases and thus the contribution of each worker to the discounted future profits
increases. Also, the overall job creation impact is still stronger relative to the job loss,
aided by the reduced technological impact of creative destruction. Looking at (8’), the
47
adjustment due to the latter effect is likely to be relatively weaker than the change in
marginal product of technology, hence the increase in the sum of discounted future
profits of an additional worker. Lower equilibrium employment drives wages down,
whilst the effect of higher per interviewee cost is the dominant factor in reducing the
economy’s interview rate.
An increase in q also results in a fall in the level of technology implemented but
an increase in the employment of workers. In this situation, this reduction in technology
level implemented actually reduces the productivity of a worker at every level of
employment, which thus leads to a decrease in the sum of discounted future profits
attributed to an additional worker. We also find that the threshold level of human capital
has risen. The intuition is fairly similar to that for the case of an increase in b, except that
the extent of increase in the threshold level of h is larger, since this cost has a direct
impact on technology adoption. Higher employment thus drives wages up whilst the
decrease in total discounted future profits of an additional worker plays a dominant role
in the fall in interview rate of the economy as it discourages creation of jobs.
Table 1.12: Simulation results for (a) 10% fall in b (=0.09) and (b) 10% rise in b (=0.11)
(a) 10% fall in b (=0.09)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6150
0.6175
0.6200
0.6250
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.936624
0.941828
0.943531
0.943559
0.943565
0.943565
0.943565
0.943560
0.942873
0.940398
0.936392
0.933874
At
0.182264
0.283354
0.403278
0.416203
0.422724
0.425999
0.429284
0.435882
0.539148
0.687177
0.842623
0.921405
λt
0.215421
0.236134
0.252853
0.254333
0.255060
0.255421
0.255781
0.256492
0.266245
0.276755
0.284714
0.287820
wt
0.058394
0.073561
0.088497
0.089976
0.090714
0.091083
0.091452
0.092189
0.103146
0.117448
0.131342
0.138117
Dt
0.199287
0.214566
0.231956
0.233822
0.234764
0.235238
0.235713
0.236667
0.251697
0.273807
0.298113
0.310979
zAth
0.035431
0.037262
0.040594
0.041009
0.041221
0.041329
0.041438
0.041659
0.045425
0.051851
0.060002
0.064763
zAthLt
0.033185
0.035094
0.038302
0.038694
0.038895
0.038997
0.039100
0.039307
0.042830
0.048760
0.056186
0.060480
Profit
0.077895
0.097683
0.117287
0.119235
0.120208
0.120694
0.121181
0.122153
0.136651
0.155704
0.174355
0.183496
48
(b) 10% rise in b (=0.11)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6150
0.6200
0.6225
0.6250
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.930742
0.936497
0.938447
0.938501
0.938506
0.938507
0.938506
0.938500
0.937850
0.935314
0.931170
0.928567
At
0.180103
0.279920
0.398065
0.417191
0.423641
0.426880
0.430128
0.436651
0.531504
0.676305
0.827613
0.903969
λt
0.234088
0.256744
0.275018
0.277430
0.278216
0.278606
0.278993
0.279762
0.289637
0.301087
0.309734
0.313100
wt
0.057882
0.072979
0.087830
0.090033
0.090766
0.091132
0.091498
0.092229
0.102378
0.116560
0.130318
0.137019
Dt
0.186873
0.201187
0.217375
0.219981
0.220860
0.221301
0.221744
0.222634
0.235645
0.255988
0.278207
0.289907
zAth
0.035262
0.037035
0.040278
0.040889
0.041100
0.041206
0.041314
0.041532
0.044973
0.051193
0.059039
0.063598
zAthLt
0.032820
0.034683
0.037799
0.038374
0.038572
0.038672
0.038773
0.038978
0.042178
0.047882
0.054976
0.059055
Profit
0.077577
0.097315
0.116853
0.119763
0.120732
0.121216
0.121700
0.122667
0.136133
0.155078
0.173593
0.182653
Table 1.13: Simulation results for (a) 5% fall in q (=0.133) and (b) 5% rise in q (=0.147)
(a) 5% fall in q (=0.133)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6025
0.6050
0.6075
0.6100
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.933157
0.938301
0.939797
0.939800
0.939801
0.939800
0.939798
0.938819
0.935930
0.931437
0.928658
At
0.195179
0.303026
0.430474
0.433883
0.437303
0.440733
0.444173
0.574106
0.729485
0.891130
0.972348
λt
0.229917
0.251874
0.269492
0.269884
0.270273
0.270660
0.271045
0.283491
0.294356
0.302448
0.305550
wt
0.058092
0.073176
0.088007
0.088374
0.088741
0.089108
0.089474
0.102526
0.116668
0.130370
0.137038
Dt
0.197644
0.213386
0.231211
0.231685
0.232161
0.232639
0.233118
0.251329
0.273715
0.298133
0.310970
(b) 5% rise in q (=0.147)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6300
0.6325
0.6350
0.6375
0.6400
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.933994
0.939801
0.941937
0.942067
0.942069
0.942069
0.942068
0.942066
0.500523
0.939470
0.935769
0.933404
At
0.168733
0.262571
0.374030
0.410537
0.413638
0.416748
0.419866
0.422994
0.941631
0.638670
0.784243
0.858277
λt
0.220412
0.241875
0.259282
0.263822
0.264187
0.264550
0.264911
0.265270
0.273309
0.284407
0.292909
0.296272
wt
0.058165
0.073340
0.088288
0.092720
0.093089
0.093457
0.093824
0.094192
0.042502
0.117286
0.131219
0.138020
Dt
0.188046
0.201911
0.217672
0.222811
0.223248
0.223686
0.224126
0.224567
0.235559
0.255597
0.277644
0.289326
zAth
0.036414
0.038533
0.042215
0.042327
0.042440
0.042553
0.042668
0.047467
0.054389
0.063102
0.068160
zAthLt
0.033980
0.036156
0.039673
0.039779
0.039885
0.039992
0.040100
0.044563
0.050904
0.058776
0.063297
Profit
0.081054
0.101655
0.122033
0.122539
0.123045
0.123551
0.124056
0.142120
0.161831
0.181055
0.190446
zAth
0.034354
0.035869
0.038801
0.039949
0.040051
0.040153
0.040256
0.040360
0.067114
0.048901
0.056248
0.060540
zAthLt
0.032086
0.033710
0.036548
0.037635
0.037731
0.037827
0.037924
0.038022
0.033592
0.045941
0.052635
0.056509
Profit
0.074644
0.093621
0.112432
0.118036
0.118502
0.118968
0.119434
0.119900
0.049748
0.149350
0.167313
0.176129
The findings for the increase in interest rate or discounting factor appear puzzling.
The increase reduces employment but actually increases the level of technology
49
implemented, which resulted from an upward shift of only the locus of A&t = 0 . However,
the impact of the increase in r is only minimal. An increase in r will actually lead to a
higher discounting of the sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker at all
levels of employment. This will thus discourage the use of workers, hence the reduced
employment and greater use of technology. Another factor that would have influenced
the fall in the sum of discounted future profits of an additional worker would be that the
marginal creative destruction impact is greater than the change in net marginal product of
technology adoption in the process of replacing labour with technology, based on (8’).
The threshold level of human capital is found to have increased though. This outcome
can be seen in view of the fact that the fall in the sum of discounted future profits of an
additional worker is not sufficiently large enough to encourage a greater substitution of
labour with technology and that the marginal product of each worker would have
increased when employment falls. Wages and interview rate have decreased. The former
is due to lower employment, but this factor is overwhelmed by the reduction in the total
discounted future profits of an additional worker in determining the outcome of the latter.
Table 1.14: Simulation results for (a) 25% fall in r (=0.03) and (b) 25% rise in r (=0.05)
(a) 25% fall in r (=0.03)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6150
0.6175
0.6200
0.6250
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
Lt
0.934393
0.939735
0.941485
0.941515
0.941521
0.941522
0.941521
0.941516
0.940816
0.938289
0.934209
0.931651
At
0.181104
0.281461
0.400358
0.413161
0.419619
0.422863
0.426116
0.432650
0.534824
0.680987
0.834039
0.911417
λt
0.228494
0.250078
0.267453
0.268989
0.269743
0.270118
0.270490
0.271228
0.281322
0.292158
0.300310
0.303470
wt
0.058200
0.073333
0.088229
0.089703
0.090439
0.090807
0.091175
0.091909
0.102831
0.117080
0.130913
0.137657
Dt
0.194232
0.208896
0.225579
0.227369
0.228272
0.228726
0.229181
0.230095
0.244491
0.265624
0.288785
0.301012
zAth
0.03534
0.037137
0.040417
0.040825
0.041035
0.041141
0.041248
0.041465
0.045170
0.051477
0.059452
0.064096
zAthLt
0.033022
0.034899
0.038052
0.038438
0.038635
0.038735
0.038836
0.039040
0.042496
0.048300
0.055541
0.059715
Profit
0.077673
0.097433
0.116998
0.118942
0.119913
0.120398
0.120883
0.121853
0.136312
0.155302
0.173873
0.182966
50
(b) 25% rise in r (=0.05)
h
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6150
0.6200
0.6225
0.6250
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
1.5
Lt
0.932800
0.938431
0.940339
0.940391
0.940396
0.940397
0.940396
0.940390
0.939752
0.937260
0.933179
0.930610
At
0.181188
0.281693
0.400799
0.420098
0.426607
0.429876
0.433155
0.439739
0.535549
0.682086
0.835609
0.913258
λt
0.221670
0.243498
0.261152
0.263486
0.264247
0.264625
0.265000
0.265744
0.275321
0.286469
0.294937
0.298255
wt
0.058061
0.073190
0.088078
0.090287
0.091022
0.091389
0.091756
0.092489
0.102668
0.116900
0.130711
0.137442
Dt
0.191165
0.206028
0.222844
0.225552
0.226466
0.226926
0.227386
0.228311
0.241847
0.263050
0.286274
0.298534
zAth
0.035347
0.037152
0.040444
0.041064
0.041278
0.041386
0.041495
0.041717
0.045212
0.051543
0.059553
0.064219
zAthLt
0.032971
0.034865
0.038031
0.038616
0.038817
0.038919
0.039022
0.039230
0.042488
0.048309
0.055573
0.059763
Profit
0.077788
0.097553
0.117127
0.120044
0.121015
0.121500
0.121985
0.122954
0.136454
0.155459
0.174049
0.183154
General Discussion
The above comparative statics analysis has yielded some interesting outcomes
with respect to changes in various parameters.
We attempt to provide a general
discussion on the implications of some issues and policy implications associated with the
existence of a threshold level of human capital.
The key point to note is that in general, it is beneficial for a country with very low
levels of human capital to undertake efforts to raise the skill level of the economically
active through training courses and to provide more higher education opportunities for
the schooling population.
Such a move can raise both employment and earnings.
However, over-emphasis on training and education such that human capital level is
beyond the threshold level can lead to higher unemployment arising from creative
destruction effect attributed to technology and reduced profitability in the use of workers.
An empirical study carried out by Ho and Tan (2005) has revealed such a phenomenon
occurring in Singapore.
51
As the economy matures, the level of human capital within the workforce is likely
to reach an apex. If this apex be beyond the threshold level of human capital, a solution
needs to be found to help workers, who are likely to have spent a fairly large amount to
attain the level of human capital, gain employment to help them recoup the investment in
education. Policies that target the wage parameters and employment cost parameter can
be implemented to help to boost the employment level and thus, in our model, reduce
unemployment.
1.6
Conclusion
In this paper, we have studied the interaction between technology adoption and
employment (unemployment), with an emphasis on how changes in human capital
influence the technology-employment mix of firms within the economy. Whilst the
increasing skill level of the labour force has enabled the use of higher levels of
technology, as found in several empirical studies, we observe also that workers have
become increasingly replaceable by technology. We have shown that higher levels of
human capital promote the use of higher levels of technology throughout. Also, such
increases raise employment (lower unemployment) at lower levels of human capital and
that, beyond a certain threshold, further increases in the level of human capital lead to
lower employment (higher unemployment). A corresponding relationship that is similar
in nature between employment and technology adoption can be obtained. Comparative
statics analysis was carried out for various parameters, with the effects of increased pace
of global technological advancement, increase in subsidy to technology adoption and
52
decreases in wage rate per unit of human capital being studied. Some implications on
the above findings are discussed.
53
1.7
Appendices
1.7.1 Proof of Proposition 1
We first differentiate (15) and (16) with respect to h but keeping Lt fixed to obtain the
vertical shift of the demarcation loci. The results are as follows:
Differentiation of A&t = 0 with respect to h:
∂L&t
∂h
⎧ A − h ⎡αβ BhL β −1 ( hA )α ⎤
⎫
t
t
⎪ t ⎣
⎦ − λt ⎪ +
⎨
⎬
h 2 zLt
Lt ⎪
⎪⎩
⎭
⎧⎧
⎫
⎡ −h ⎛ 2
α +1 β −1 α −1 ∂At
α β −1 α ⎞ ⎤ ⎫
+
+
−
α
β
α
α
β
A
Bh
L
A
Bh
L
A
1
(
)
⎪⎪
t
t
t
t ⎟ ⎥ ⎪ ⎪
⎢ t ⎜
∂h
⎝
⎠ ⎥ ⎪ ⎪
⎪ ⎪h 2 zL ⎢
−
t
⎪
⎪⎨
⎢⎛ − h −1 ∂At
⎥ ⎪⎬ ⎪
α
⎞
β −1
−h
+ At ln At ⎟ αβ BhLt ( hAt )
⎪⎪
⎢⎜ hAt
⎥ ⎪ ⎪
∂h
⎠
⎣⎝
⎦
⎪⎪
⎪ ⎪⎪
α
⎪ ⎪ −h
β −1
⎪⎭ ⎪
⎪ ⎩ At αβ BhLt ( hAt ) ( 2hzLt )
−
2
⎪
⎪
2
h
zL
(
)
t
⎪
⎪
L&t ⎨
⎬=
⎡⎛
⎤
α
⎞⎡
− h −1 ∂At
−h
β
⎪
⎪
−hAt
− At ln At ⎟ α BhLt ( hAt ) − qAt ⎤ +
⎥
⎣
⎦
⎪ 2 2 ⎢⎜⎝
⎪
∂h
⎠
⎥−
⎪ h zLt ⎢
⎪
⎢
⎥
A
A
∂
∂
−h ⎛ 2
α +1 β
α −1
α β
α
⎪
⎪
t
t ⎞
⎢ At ⎜ α Bh Lt At ∂h + α (α + 1) Bh Lt At − q ∂h ⎟ ⎥
⎪
⎪
⎝
⎠⎦
⎣
⎪
⎪
α
⎪
⎪ At − h ⎡α BhLt β ( hAt ) − qAt ⎤ ( 2hzLt 2 )
⎣
⎦
⎪
⎪
2
2 2
⎪
⎪
h
zL
( t)
⎪⎩
⎭⎪
(
)
2δ −1
2ε
⎫⎪
∂At
∂λt ⎧⎪ δ h (1 − Lt )
β −1 α −1 α
ψ −1 γ
λt + zAt h ⎬ +
−αβ BLt h At
− αβ BLt h At +ψχ h Lt +
⎨r +
∂h
∂h ⎪⎩
2b
⎭⎪
⎧⎪ ⎡ 2δε h 2ε −1 (1 − L )2δ −1 ⎤ δ h 2ε (1 − L )2δ −1 ∂λ ⎛
∂A
⎞ ⎫⎪
t
t
t
λt ⎨λt ⎢
+ ⎜ hzAt h −1 t + zAt h ln At ⎟ ⎬
⎥+
2b
2b
∂h ⎝
∂h
⎠ ⎭⎪
⎥⎦
⎩⎪ ⎢⎣
β −1 α
α −1
(A1)
54
Differentiation of L&t = 0 with respect to h:
2ε h 2ε −1 (1 − Lt )
2b
2δ
h 2ε (1 − Lt )
λt +
2b
2δ
∂λt
∂A
⎡
⎤
− zLt ⎢ hAt h −1 t + At h ln At ⎥ = 0
∂h
∂h
⎣
⎦
(A2)
where:
∂λt
1
=
∂h ( h 2 zL )2
t
and
⎧
⎧⎛
⎫ ⎫
α
⎞
− h −1 ∂At
− At − h ln At ⎟ ⎡ − qA + α BhLt β ( hAt ) ⎤ +
⎪
⎪⎜ −hAt
⎪ ⎪
⎦
∂h
⎠⎣
⎪ ⎪
⎪h 2 zL ⎨⎪⎝
⎬ −⎪
t
⎪
∂
∂
A
A
⎡
⎤
⎪ A − h − q t + α 2 Bhα +1 L β A α −1 t + α (α + 1) Bhα L β A α ⎪ ⎬
⎨
t
t
t
t ⎥
⎪⎩ t ⎢⎣ ∂h
⎪
∂h
⎦ ⎭⎪ ⎪
⎪
⎪
α
⎪ At − h ⎡ −qAt + α BhLt β ( hAt ) ⎤ ( 2hzLt )
⎪
⎣
⎦
⎩
⎭
∂L&t
would be equal to the left-hand side of (A2).
∂h
Note that the derivatives of At with respect to h are not equal in both (A1) and (A2) in
general. However, at the threshold level of human capital, both derivatives would be the
same. In addition, the extent of vertical shift would be the same at the threshold level of
human capital, thus this point would correspond to the situation where both A&t and L&t
would be zero. Solving the equation formed by (A1) and (A2) at the threshold level of
human capital (i.e. eliminating the derivatives of At with respect to h) together with (15)
and (16) would yield the solutions for the threshold h, the level of technology
implemented at the threshold and the maximum level of employment (minimum level of
unemployment) attainable within the economy.
55
1.7.2
Mathematical Intuition of Proposition 2
The outcomes associated with result 1 can be obtained by re-examining the equations in
section 1.7.1. First, substitute the left-hand side of (A2) into (A1) and rewrite both (A1)
and (A2) such that the terms associated with the derivative of At with respect to h are
brought together. Assume that the final form is as follows:
From (A1), i.e., locus of A&t = 0 :
Ω1
∂At
= Ω2
∂h
(B1)
From (A2), i.e., locus of L&t = 0 :
Ω3
∂At
= Ω4
∂h
(B2)
Thus, for values of h beyond the threshold level, Ω2Ω3 – Ω1Ω4 > 0, with Ω2Ω3 – Ω1Ω4 < 0
being the outcome for values of h below the threshold level. The former corresponds to
the case where the locus of A&t = 0 shifts by a larger extent than that of L&t = 0 , with the
opposite occurring for the latter case. The case where Ω2Ω3 – Ω1Ω4 = 0 will correspond
to the situation where the derivatives of At with respect to h are eliminated as in
Appendix A, that is, both graphs shift by the same extent. The following table presents a
numerical simulation of the baseline case.
56
Table 1.15: Simulation results for baseline case on the shift of demarcation loci
h
0.3000
0.3170
0.3500
0.4000
0.5000
0.6000
0.6100
0.6175
0.6200
0.6225
0.6300
0.7000
0.8000
0.9000
0.9500
(Ω2/Ω1)
-0.597485
0.464564
0.682390
0.837116
1.070960
1.268620
1.286660
1.299970
1.304400
1.318010
1.321740
1.433310
1.557800
1.632670
1.648630
(Ω4/Ω3)
0.686148
0.725035
0.799214
0.907800
1.107400
1.275520
1.290180
1.300880
1.304370
1.307880
1.318160
1.400880
1.471380
1.476350
1.452180
(Ω2/Ω1)- (Ω4/Ω3)
-1.28363
-0.26047
-0.11682
-0.07068
-0.03644
-0.00690
-0.00352
-0.00091
3E-05
0.01013
0.00358
0.03243
0.08642
0.15632
0.19645
Remarks
0 , and δ ∈ ( 0,1) .
The cost decreases with an increase in the economy’s human capital HN, H N ∈ ( 0,1) , and
increases exponentially with an increase in the quality required from the supplier. The
cost is considered to be decreasing in HN because human capital improves the reliability
of the manual component being produced. Though better-trained workers are assumed to
be more efficient in supplying the manual good, but such efficiency diminishes with
further increases in human capital through the parameter δ , which would reflect the
similar characteristic as encountered by the integrated firm in producing the manual
component. The per-unit cost of quality is assumed to increase exponentially to indicate
that higher quality will require greater customization and hence increased costs, which
are passed down to the firm.
Here, ρ can be seen as an indexing parameter that
represents the base cost of outsourcing. A lower ρ would also represent cost savings
from the supplier being passed down to the user of the manual component. Under the
domestic outsourcing scenario, one unit of the final good of quality level VNO can be
produced based on the following production function:
VNO = λ (VM )
1− β
( H N LNO )
β
(1)
where β and 1 − β denote respectively the production shares attributed to the manual
and organizational components. Note that β ∈ ( 0,1) .
λ is an indexation parameter for
overall production, with λ > 0 . LNO denotes the number of workers employed for each
unit of service good produced under the case of outsourcing the manual component. In
this case, the manager is assumed to be able to devote all his time into the production of
69
the organizational component and that there is perfect coordination between the firm and
the supplier.
Workers employed by the firm enter into the production of the
organizational component of the good only, and thus it can be said that there exists
diminishing marginal quality of per-unit employment.
Under integrated production, the manager has one unit of time that is equally
divided between supervising the production of the two components.16 One unit of the
final good of quality level VN can be produced based on the following production
function:
1− β
⎛ H ηL ⎞
VNI = λ ⎜ N NI ⎟
⎝ 2 ⎠
⎛ H N LNI ⎞
⎜ 2 ⎟
⎝
⎠
β
(1’)
where LNI denotes the total number of workers required in the integrated firm to produce
one unit of the final service good of quality VN. η is a parameter that indicates the
effectiveness of the human capital component, with η ∈ ( 0,1) .17 Given that the manual
component does not involve a high level of skill utilization, thus further increases in the
level of human capital will only have a diminishing positive impact on the quality of the
manual component.
From the above forms of production function for quality, it is possible that the
quality of the manual component under the fragmented form of production would be
16
We have assumed the time allocation to be exogenous and equally divided for simplicity, to concentrate
on the firm’s decision on the mode of production to undertake as human capital increases. The time
allocation is likely to be closely related to the productivity of human capital in each of the components.
17
Here, η does not take the value of 1 as this would then result in no differentiation of the human capital
element in producing the manual and organizational component.
70
lower than that under the integrated mode. However, overall quality of its service or
infrastructural good can be higher under the fragmented mode of production as the firm
concentrates on raising the quality of the organizational component. While outsourcing
the manual component allows the firm to pursue a differentiated cost strategy leading to
cost reduction, it also provides a potential avenue for the firm to improve the overall
quality of its infrastructural or service good.
Firms face a wage cost that is the outcome of negotiations between the firm and
an agency that oversees the setting of wages. Employment can thus be considered to be
demand-determined. 18 The firm thus faces a per worker wage rate of wH N ε , where
ε > 0 determines the extent of change in wages per unit change in human capital. w can
be considered as the base wage before adjusting for the human capital level of the worker.
The firm faces two different profit functions, depending on the choice of
production favoured by the firm. The profit functions can be written as follows, with
π NO and π NI denoting the profit of the firm under outsourcing and integration
respectively:
Outsourcing
:
π NO = PN QNO − wH N ε QNO LNO −
No outsourcing
:
π NI = PNI QNI − wH N ε QNI LNI
ρ
HN
δ
eVM QNO
18
Such an assumption can be taken where the government plays a major role in setting general guidelines
on the determination of wages.
71
where QNk, where k={O, I}, is the quantity of the service good sold by the Northern firm.
Note that with the above definition of the production function, the total number of
workers employed by the firm is denoted by QNOLNO or QNILNI, which differs from the
conventional setup since in this case the output is determined by demand from consumers.
The above can be re-expressed as follows for ease of interpretation:
⎡
Outsourcing
:
π NO = QNO ⎢ PNO − wH N ε LNO −
No outsourcing
:
π NI = QNI ⎡⎣ PNI − wH N ε LNI ⎤⎦
⎣
ρ
HN
δ
⎤
eVM ⎥
⎦
(2)
(2’)
where the term in square brackets denotes the profit made for each unit of the service
good of quality VNk sold, or in short, the per-unit profit.19
2.2.2 Preferences
We make a slight modification to the standard model of product quality
differentiation by Mussa and Rosen (1978), Shaked and Sutton (1982), Tirole (1988),
Motta (1993) and others. In this context, though each firm is a monopolist within its own
economy, the nature of the good is such that they compete within a global context since
domestic demand is insignificant. The utility of a consumer i when he consumes product
j is denoted by the following:
19
In the above model, whilst the direct cost of the organizational component increases as human capital
increases via the wage bill, this cost can decrease indirectly via reduction in per-unit employment. This is
because as human capital increases, each worker is now more capable of producing a higher quality of the
organizational component, and thus fewer workers will be needed to produce a given level of this
component.
72
U ij = θi log (V jk ) − χ Pjk
(3)
In the above, j={NI, NO, S} and θi denotes consumer i’s taste parameter or willingness to
pay for quality, θ ∈ ⎡⎣θ , θ ⎤⎦ . A higher value of θ indicates a greater willingness to pay
for quality. χ is a common parameter indicating the consumer’s responsiveness to price
changes. We consider the natural logarithmic formulation here based on the assumption
of diminishing utility of quality. All consumers here are assumed to have either zero or
unitary demand for the service good. The above utility can be seen as the surplus that
consumer i derives from consuming the service good.
2.3
Equilibrium and Changes in Human Capital Level
The equilibrium is attained based on a sequential process akin to a three-stage
game, starting with the determination of employment per unit of service good produced
within the Northern firm and, if the firm outsource the manual component, the quality
required from the supplier. This is followed by the choice of price and finally the overall
quantity demanded of the service good from the consumers. We segregate the firm
optimization process into two stages for ease of analysis as this will not change the
solution. We make use of backward induction to obtain the equilibrium. The solutions
obtained will allow us subsequently to determine the quality of the final service good
provided, total employment and profits made by the Northern firm.
73
2.3.1 Analytical Solution
Based on the above consumer preferences, there exists the marginal consumer
with taste θ = θ * who is indifferent between buying the service good from the North or
South such that θ * log (VNk ) − χ PNk = θ * log (VS ) − χ PS , which yields the taste parameter
of the marginal consumer as:
θ* =
χ ( PNk − PS )
(4)
log (VNk ) − log (VS )
Therefore, all consumers with taste parameter in excess of θ * will buy the service good
from the North. Hence, the quantity demanded from the Northern firm will be:
QNk = θ − θ * = θ −
χ ( PNk − PS )
(5)
log (VNk ) − log (VS )
At the second stage, the Northern firm caries out the optimization with respect to
price, taking into account the quantity demanded of its service good. We first consider
the case where the firm carries out outsourcing (hence k=O subsequently), noting that
similar results can be obtained for the other case by omitting the term corresponding to
the cost of outsourcing. Substituting the quantity demanded from (5) into the profit
function (2) and maximizing with respect to PNO yields:
PNO =
1
2χ
⎡
⎛
ρ VM
ε
e
⎢θ ( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) ) + χ ⎜ PS + wLNO H N +
δ
H
N
⎝
⎣
⎞⎤
⎟⎥
⎠⎦
(6)
74
At this juncture, the solutions of PNO and QNO are functions of LNO and VM (function of
LNI only, where LNI replaces LNO, if we consider the case under no outsourcing). On
solving, the solution of QNO is as follows:
QNO
⎡
⎛
⎞⎤
ρ
χ ⎜ wLNO H N ε + δ eVM − PS ⎟ ⎥
⎢
HN
1
⎠⎥
= ⎢θ − ⎝
⎥
2⎢
log (VNO ) − log (VS )
⎢
⎥
⎢⎣
⎥⎦
(7)
The price charged by the Northern firm in equation (6) is positively related to the
net difference in utility derived from consuming both goods, the responsiveness to price
changes, price charged by the Southern firm, employment, the economy’s human capital
level, cost of purchasing and quality of the manual component. The opposite holds for all
items in terms of its relationship with quantity demanded except for the net difference in
utility derived from consuming both goods and price charged by the Southern firm. For
(7) to hold, the following condition must be fulfilled:
0 < wLNO H N ε +
ρ
HN
η
eVM − PS <
θ ( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) )
χ
The left-hand inequality indicates that the total per unit cost incurred by the Northern
firm should be less than the price charged by the Southern firm. This is to ensure that the
demand does not exceed θ . The right-hand inequality indicates that quantity demanded
cannot be negative.
75
At the first stage, the Northern firm chooses the number of workers to hire per
unit of service good produced as well as the quality required from the supplier.
Substituting the above solutions for PNO and QNO and the per-unit production function for
quality represented by equation (1’), the optimization problem yields two first order
conditions that implicitly solve for the optimal levels of LNO and VM as follows:
⎡ 1 ⎛ βθ
⎤
⎞
⎡
ρ VM ⎤
+ χ wH N ε ⎟ − wH N ε ⎥ QNO + ⎢ PNO − wLNO H N ε −
e ⎥
⎢ ⎜
δ
2
L
H
χ
NO
N
⎝
⎠
⎣
⎦
⎣
⎦
⎡ χβ
⎢
⎢ LNO
⎢
⎢
⎣⎢
⎤
⎛
⎞
ρ VM
ε
e − PS ⎟ − χ wH N ε ( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) ) ⎥
⎜ wH N LNO +
δ
HN
⎝
⎠
⎥=0
2
⎥
( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) )
⎥
⎥⎦
(8)
⎡ 1 ⎛ (1 − β ) θ
⎡
χρ VM ⎞ ρ VM ⎤
ρ VM ⎤
e ⎟−
e ⎥ QNO + ⎢ PNO − wLNO H N ε −
e ⎥
+
⎢ ⎜
δ
δ
HN
H Nδ
⎥⎦
⎣
⎦
⎠ HN
⎣⎢ 2 χ ⎝ VM
⎡ (1 − β ) ⎛
⎤
⎞
ρ VM
ρ eVM
ε
wH
L
e
P
χ
χ
log (VNO ) − log (VS ) ) ⎥
+
−
−
⎢
⎜
N
NO
S ⎟
δ
δ (
VM ⎝
HN
HN
⎠
⎢
⎥=0
2
⎢
⎥
( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) )
⎢
⎥
⎣⎢
⎦⎥
(9)
The above can be expressed as the following:
76
⎡ 1 ⎛ βθ
⎞⎤
⎡
ρ VM ⎤
+ χ wH N ε ⎟ ⎥ QNO + ⎢ PNO − wLNO H N ε −
e ⎥×
⎢ ⎜
H Nδ
⎠⎦
⎣
⎦
⎣ 2 χ ⎝ LNO
⎡ χβ ⎛
⎞⎤
ρ VM
ε
e − PS ⎟ ⎥
⎢
⎜ wH N LNO +
δ
HN
⎠ ⎥ = wH ε Q +
⎢ LNO ⎝
N
NO
2
⎢
⎥
log (VNO ) − log (VS ) )
(
⎢
⎥
⎢⎣
⎥⎦
⎤
⎡
χ wH N ε
ρ VM ⎤ ⎡
ε
e
⎢
⎥
⎢ PNO − wLNO H N −
⎥
H Nδ
⎣
⎦ ⎣⎢ ( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) ) ⎦⎥
(8a)
⎡ 1 ⎛ (1 − β ) θ
⎡
χρ VM ⎞ ⎤
ρ VM ⎤
ε
+
e
Q
+
P
−
wL
H
−
e ⎥×
⎢ ⎜
⎥
⎟
NO
NO
NO
N
⎢
H Nδ
H Nδ
⎣
⎦
⎠ ⎥⎦
⎣⎢ 2 χ ⎝ VM
⎡ (1 − β ) ⎛
⎞⎤
ρ VM
ε
e − PS ⎟ ⎥
⎢χ
⎜ wH N LNO +
δ
VM ⎝
HN
⎠ ⎥ = ρ eVM Q +
⎢
NO
2
⎢
⎥ H Nδ
log (VNO ) − log (VS ) )
(
⎢
⎥
⎣⎢
⎦⎥
⎤
⎡
ρ VM ⎤ ⎡
χρ eVM
ε
−
−
P
wL
H
e
⎢
⎥
⎢ NO
⎥
NO
N
δ
δ
HN
⎣
⎦ ⎢⎣ H N ( log (VNO ) − log (VS ) ) ⎥⎦
(9a)
The above first-order conditions (8a) and (9a), obtained from (8) and (9)
respectively, can be easily interpreted as follows. For (8a), the left-hand side terms
denote the overall benefit of having an additional worker, which comprises respectively
of the overall marginal revenue product of having an additional worker and the additional
positive contribution to profit that can be obtained from the additional demand that can be
generated as a result of employing the additional worker (recall that the employment of
an additional worker raises the quality of the service good, which can affect quantity
demanded). The right-hand side terms denote the overall marginal cost of having the
77
additional worker. These terms respectively denote the total additional remuneration
required in employing an additional worker for every unit of service good produced and
the negative contribution to profit arising from the additional demand that has to be
fulfilled as a result from employing the additional worker.
In a similar fashion, the left-hand side terms in (9a) denote the overall marginal
benefit of a unitary increase in the quality of the manual component from the supplier.
These comprise respectively of the overall marginal revenue product of a unitary increase
in the quality of the manual component from the supplier and the additional positive
contribution to profit that can be obtained from that unitary increase. The right-hand side
of (9a) would denote the overall marginal cost of a unitary increase in the quality of the
manual component from the supplier. These comprise respectively of the total additional
cost of the unitary increase in the quality of the manual component from the supplier and
the negative contribution to profit arising from the additional demand that has to be
fulfilled due to that unitary increase.
We also list the corresponding results for the price and quality of the service good
and the first-order condition for per-unit employment for the case where the firm does not
outsource the manual component:
PNI =
1
⎡θ ( log (VNI ) − log (VS ) ) + χ ( PS + wLNI H N ε ) ⎤
⎦
2χ ⎣
χ ( wLNI H N ε − PS ) ⎤
1⎡
⎥
QNI = ⎢θ −
2⎢
log (VNI ) − log (VS ) ⎥
⎣
⎦
(6’)
(7’)
78
⎤
⎞
1⎡ 1 ⎛ θ
1
+ χ wH N ε ⎟ − wH N ε ⎥ QN + ⎡⎣ PNI − wLNI H N ε ⎤⎦
⎢ ⎜
2 ⎣ 2 χ ⎝ LNI
2
⎠
⎦
⎡ χ
⎤
ε
ε
⎢ L ( wH N LNI − PS ) − χ wH N ( log (VNI ) − log (VS ) ) ⎥
⎢ NI
⎥=0
2
⎢
⎥
log
log
−
V
V
( S ))
( ( NI )
⎢⎣
⎥⎦
(8’)
Given the non-linear nature of the above solutions, it is not possible to obtain
analytical solutions for LNO or LNI and VM as well as for PNk, QNk, VNk, and profits. In
addition, we may have multiple equilibria for LNO or LNI and VM. Nevertheless, a unique
solution for LNk and VM such that profits are globally maximized will emerge. We will
thus proceed to use numerical methods for further analysis.
2.3.2
Numerical Example
We will be using a numerical example here to study the solutions obtained in this
model. We will not attempt to calibrate the base model as many of the above parameters
do not have real-world counterparts, but will instead choose sensible parameter values
that would enable us to gain some insights and policy implications arising from changes
in human capital of the Northern economy as well as competitiveness of the Southern
economy. Table 2.1 shows the parameter values used in the base case, with HN=0.5 to
demonstrate the nature of the solution. We have allowed the production share attributed
to the organizational component to be larger, indicating the greater role of this component
towards the per-unit overall quality of the service good. For simplicity, we impose the
condition that θ − θ = 1 , with θ = 1 .
79
Table 2.1: Parameter values used for initial numerical analysis
Production share of organizational component, β
Human capital of Northern economy, HN
Effectiveness of human capital in manual component, η
Indexing parameter for quality production, λ
Indexing parameter for wages, w
Wage behaviour parameter, ε
Base cost of outsourcing, ρ
Outsourcing cost parameter associated with human capital, δ
Per-unit price charged by Southern firm, PS
Quality of service good of Southern firm, VS
Consumer taste for quality, θi
Consumer responsiveness to price, χ
0.67
0.5
0.8
1.5
0.24
0.67
0.075
0.75
0.3
0.5
uniformally distributed
between 0 to 1
1
Multiple roots can be found in the case where no outsourcing is undertaken
whereas multiple equilibria exist under the case of outsourcing of the manual component.
Under the latter case, we find infinitely many solutions where the graphs overlap each
other as well as a couple of points of intersection between the two graphs. All solutions
that are classified under the former observation are not optimal to the firm as they earn no
profits and thus optimal output level is zero. This would directly suggest that the graph
depicting the overlapping portions to correspond to either a plot of QN=0 or per-unit
profit being zero in both (8) and (9), which can be attained by the combination of LNI and
VM depicted by the overlapping portions of the graph.
Unique solutions can be found for each of the intersection points. However, one
of the points, where the per unit of service good employment and required quality of the
outsourced manual component are low, would require the quality of the Northern firm’s
service good to be fairly similar in quality to that of the Southern firm’s. Under such a
80
product differentiation model, it is actually not optimal for the firms to produce goods of
similar quality as these goods then become close substitutes, which would suggest a
higher degree of competition between the two firms. Profit in this case is also found to
be not a global maximum. As for the other intersection point, where per unit of service
good employment and required quality of the outsourced manual component are higher,
the Northern firm’s service good is now vastly superior to that of the Southern firm’s in
terms of quality, which suggests a high degree of product differentiation, and we find that
profits are higher under this equilibrium than in the previous one.
The above explanation applies when the firm takes on an integrated form of
production. We find three roots, out of which one root has properties similar to the case
of overlapping graphs, whilst out of the other two roots, the root with higher employment
per service good yields higher quality and profit.
Table 2.2 provides a numerical
summary of the discussion of the solutions for a particular value of HN.
Table 2.2: Comparison of roots obtained with HN = 0.5
Integrated production
Local max
Global max
LNI
VNI
QNI
PNI
πNI
1.5895
4.1977
0.6242
1.6486
0.7697
0.3918
0.4011
1.0756
0.1315
0.1831
Employment
(QNI LNI)
1.2234
1.6446
Fragmented production
Local max
Global max
LNO
VM
VNO
QMO
PNO
πNO
0.7808
2.9493
0.3159
0.7630
0.5457
1.7758
0.8303
0.3590
0.3648
1.1624
0.0602
0.1633
Employment
(QNO LNO)
0.6483
1.0588
81
2.3.3 Changes in the Human Capital Level of the Northern Economy
In this section, we will be analysing how the form of production taken on by the
firm, price and quality of the Northern good, the Northern firm’s profits and the quantity
demanded will be affected by changes in the economy’s human capital level. Consider
the progression of the human capital level within the Northern economy HN. We allow
HN to vary between 0.15 and 0.9 and compare between the profits of the firm under both
the cases of integrated production and outsourcing of the manual component, with the
results shown in Table 2.3.
As the human capital level of the Northern economy increases, the benefits come
in the form of improved quality of the service good and, if outsourcing is undertaken,
reduced prices for the outsourced manual component. However, higher levels of human
capital translate into higher wages per worker. For the case of integrated production,
employment per unit of service good produced falls as human capital rises. This is likely
to be due to the fact that for a given level of per-unit employment, the marginal cost of
using the same number of workers to produce one unit of the good exceeds the marginal
benefit from the increase in human capital, thus the reduction.
In the case where
outsourcing is carried out, in terms of the graphs surrounding the global maximum, the
graph of the first-order condition corresponding to (8) shifts to the left whilst that of (9)
shifts upwards and becomes steeper, leading to a decrease in employment per unit of
service good and an increase in the quality level of the outsourced manual component
required from the supplier. A similar explanation holds in this case in terms of the effect
82
Table 2.3: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.61
0.62
0.63
0.64
0.65
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
10.4471
8.38926
6.18747
5.00070
4.24594
3.71807
3.67373
3.63065
3.58877
3.54805
3.50842
3.32529
3.02002
2.77493
VNI
1.33375
1.40092
1.50853
1.59471
1.66753
1.73109
1.73704
1.74292
1.74874
1.75449
1.76019
1.78779
1.83917
1.88628
QNI
0.29216
0.31142
0.33451
0.34845
0.35805
0.36521
0.36583
0.36644
0.36703
0.36761
0.36817
0.37082
0.37538
0.37919
PNI
0.99449
1.00943
1.03488
1.05570
1.07322
1.08834
1.08975
1.09114
1.09251
1.09386
1.09520
1.10165
1.11354
1.12428
πNI
0.08375
0.09992
0.12357
0.14082
0.15442
0.16564
0.16667
0.16767
0.16866
0.16964
0.17060
0.17520
0.18353
0.19091
QNI LNI
3.05224
2.61258
2.06980
1.74249
1.52028
1.35788
1.34396
1.33040
1.31718
1.30429
1.29170
1.23309
1.13366
1.05223
PNI/ VNI
0.74563
0.72055
0.68602
0.66200
0.64360
0.62870
0.62736
0.62604
0.62474
0.62346
0.62221
0.61621
0.60546
0.59603
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
8.70591
0.54796
1.46649
0.11520
1.25206
0.01428
1.00294
0.85378
0.20
6.60848
0.59594
1.52024
0.18638
1.20476
0.03863
1.23166
0.79248
0.30
4.55785
0.67471
1.62075
0.26468
1.16477
0.08239
1.20637
0.71866
0.40
3.54392
0.73926
1.71154
0.30738
1.15229
0.11627
1.08934
0.67325
0.50
2.93447
0.79455
1.79390
0.33450
1.15020
0.14295
0.98159
0.64117
0.60
2.52497
0.84316
1.86924
0.35337
1.15271
0.16466
0.89224
0.61667
0.61
2.49120
0.84772
1.87644
0.35494
1.15310
0.16662
0.88424
0.61452
0.62
2.45849
0.85223
1.88358
0.35648
1.15352
0.16854
0.87639
0.61241
0.63
2.42678
0.85669
1.89066
0.35796
1.15395
0.17043
0.86870
0.61034
0.64
2.39602
0.86111
1.89768
0.35941
1.15441
0.17229
0.86116
0.60832
0.65
2.36617
0.86548
1.90466
0.36082
1.15487
0.17412
0.85376
0.60634
0.70
2.22926
0.88667
1.93873
0.36730
1.15742
0.18283
0.81882
0.59700
0.80
2.00470
0.92612
2.00327
0.37807
1.16320
0.19838
0.75791
0.58065
0.90
1.82772
0.96227
2.06360
0.38665
1.16948
0.21193
0.70669
0.56672
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
on per-unit employment whilst for a given level of quality of the manual component from
the supplier, the effect of a lower marginal cost of outsourcing is likely to dominate in the
shifting of the graph associated with (9). The graph below compares the cases between
HN=0.7 and HN=0.72, with dashed lines denoting the latter case.
83
In both cases, we see a fall in per unit employment as the presence of bettertrained workers would reduce the labour requirement across all quality levels of the
service good produced, without compromising on the quality. Quantity demanded and
quality of the service good and the quality of the manual component from the supplier
under the fragmented form of production all increase. Overall employment increases
slightly for a not-too-low level of human capital under the fragmented form of production
and decreases for subsequent increases in the level of human capital, whereas the latter
holds throughout under the integrated form of production.
The fall in overall
employment can be explained by the fact that despite the improvement in quality, the
response on quantity demanded is insufficient to overcome the fall in per-unit worker
requirement. However, unlike the integrated form of production where the price of the
Figure 2.1: Graphs of the first-order conditions around the intersection point for HN=0.7
and HN=0.72 (dashed lines denote latter)
VM
Shift of graph
associated with
equation (8)
0.91
LN O
2.15
0.89
2.2
2.25
2.3
Shift of graph
associated with
equation (9)
0.88
0.87
84
good increases as human capital increases, the price under the fragmented form of
production somewhat falls throughout until it increases when human capital exceeds a
particular level.
The above findings indicate that the Northern firm’s profits are higher when the
integrated form of production of the service good is undertaken at low levels of human
capital.
However, profits under the fragmented form of production increase fairly
quickly and will eventually catch up and subsequently overtake that of the integrated
form of production. This suggests the existence of a threshold level of human capital HN*
whereby below the threshold level, the Northern firm undertakes the integrated form of
production. For levels of human capital beyond the threshold level, the Northern firm
outsources the manual component and concentrates on the organizational component.
This threshold level will enable us to obtain the threshold employment per unit of service
good under integrated and under fragmented production and the required quality of the
manual component. Our numerical solution yields a threshold level of HN* that falls
between 0.61 and 0.62. The following proposition summarizes the above observation.
Proposition 3: There exists a threshold level of human capital in the Northern economy,
HN*, such that the profits under either form of production would be equal, which yields
the threshold level of employment per unit of service good under integrated production,
LNI*, the threshold level of employment per unit of service good under fragmented
production, LNO*, and the required quality of the manual component from the supplier,
VM*.
85
Proof. At HN*, we can equate the profit equations (2) and (2’) to obtain the following:
ε
QNO ⎡⎢ PNO − w ( H N * ) LNO − ρ eVM
⎣
(H )
* η
N
⎤=Q
NI
⎥⎦
⎡ P − w ( H * )ε L ⎤
N
NI ⎥
⎢⎣ NI
⎦
(10)
Equation (10), together with the first order conditions (8), (8’) and (9), where we replace
HN with HN*, will provide us with a system of 4 equations with 4 unknowns, which
implicitly allows us to solve for the solution set (HN*, LNI*, LNO*, VM*). ■
A likely reason to explain the existence of the threshold level of human capital is
as follows. First, note that at low levels of human capital, profit will be lower if they
make use of the outsourcing mode of production to produce the same product quality as
in the fragmented mode, suggesting that it is not cost-effective to outsource the manual
component. Moreover, with outsourcing costs being relatively higher at low levels of
human capital relative to the use of workers, this mode of production does not enable the
Northern firm to reduce the per unit employment sufficiently so as to allow the quality of
the good to be of a sufficiently high level. This would subsequently lead to the firm
incurring high wage and outsourcing costs and translates into high per-unit cost of
production of a given quality and a high price-to-quality ratio, which results in relatively
higher prices. Per unit profits are also lower in this case. To summarize, the strengths of
the push factor, in the form of higher wages, and the pull factor, in the form of low
outsourcing cost, are less prominent, thus the continued use of the integrated mode of
production at low levels of human capital. From the preference side, the high price
difference to difference in utility of quality ratio if the fragmented mode of production
was used would thus raise the taste index required for indifference to occur, which
86
subsequently reduces overall demand from the Northern firm. On the whole, though the
number of workers required per unit produced is higher, the cost of hiring more workers
does not exceed the cost to outsource the manual component, which thus translates into a
relatively lower price differential.
Beyond the threshold level of human capital, the fragmented form of production
is preferred by the firm. In this situation, the cost of outsourcing is now sufficiently
relatively lower compared to pre-threshold levels of human capital. Whilst the increase
in human capital allows the firm to reduce the per-unit labour requirement, the firm can
also now reduce the number of workers they employ sufficiently and yet be able to
produce a sufficiently high level of quality of the product. Moreover, the increase in
wages arising from the increase in human capital results in such cost being relatively
higher compared to the cost of outsourcing the manual component. Thus, it is relatively
more cost-effective to undertake the fragmented form of production, which translates into
the firm being able to price the service good relatively lower in a manner such that it
reflects the benefits of a falling price-to-quality ratio. In addition, since human capital is
less productive in the manual component and that the production share attributed to this
component is low, there would be a higher divergence between the productivities of each
of the two components, which would render the use of the same compensation strategy
relatively more costly. As a result, the firm thus pursues a differentiated cost strategy
here. In summary, the strengths of the push factor of relatively higher wage cost and pull
factor of relatively lower cost of outsourcing are sufficiently strong such that the change
in mode of production occurs. From the preference side, a lower price difference to
difference of utility of quality ratio due to the relatively stronger effect arising from
87
greater product differentiation helps to reduce the taste index required for indifference to
occur, which subsequently raises the overall demand from the Northern firm.
Thus, regardless of the relevant form of production the firm will undertake based
on the human capital level of the economy, we can conclude that quality of the service
good, profits and quality of the manual component from the supplier all increase
throughout whilst the per-unit employment and overall employment falls, starting from a
not-too-low level of human capital. It is also useful to note that upon the firm changing
to the fragmented form of production, there will be a sudden fall in quantity demanded
and employment but an upward jump in the price of the service good as well as the
quality of the service good sold. Intuitively, this suggests that it is more profitable for the
firm to let go of some fringe customers in favour of higher-end customers who are
willing to pay a higher price for a service good of higher quality. It turns out that product
differentiation can be enhanced in our model. The sudden fall in employment by the
Northern firm would reflect the reduced dependence of workers upon the firm
outsourcing the manual component to the supplier, with the remaining workers in the
firm now focussing on the organizational component.
2.4
Other Comparative Statics
In this section, we consider the effects of external factors, such as a change in
price charged by and quality of the Southern firm’s service good, and internal factors
such as cost of outsourcing, wage cost and general productivity, on the various decision
variables of the Northern firm as well as quantity demanded and overall employment.
88
The subsequent discussion centers only on the effect arising from a specified particular
direction of change. The opposite outcomes apply for changes in the other direction.
2.4.1 Price Charged by the Southern Firm
We now consider the effects of a change in the unit price of the service good from
the South. The quality of the good from the Southern firm will be kept unchanged here.
This analysis can be seen as an indication on how a change in the competitiveness of the
Southern economy can affect the Northern economy. We consider the case of a 20% fall
in the price charged by the Southern firm, which can be seen as the Northern firm’s
service good becoming less competitive as it is now relatively more costly. The effects
differ somewhat from the base case in 2.3.3, depending on the form of production
undertaken. The numerical results are shown in Table 2.4.
The manner in which the variables change as human capital increases is similar to
that under the case in the preceding section. We next compare across the findings in this
and the preceding section to evaluate the changes that have taken place for the different
variables.
Under integrated production, the quality and price of the service good as well as
per unit employment has increased. However, the quantity demanded of the Northern
good falls, with this fall sufficient to generate a fall in overall employment within the
firm across all levels of human capital. Profits are also lower for all levels of human
89
Table 2.4: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a 20% fall in price charged by the Southern firm
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.59
0.60
0.61
0.62
0.63
0.64
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
10.9884
8.82055
6.49878
5.24697
4.45101
3.94266
3.89454
3.84781
3.80241
3.75828
3.71536
3.48067
3.15915
2.90113
VNI
1.40286
1.47294
1.58443
1.67324
1.74807
1.80709
1.81325
1.81935
1.82538
1.83134
1.83723
1.87132
1.92390
1.97207
QNI
0.25548
0.27602
0.30103
0.31636
0.32705
0.33437
0.33508
0.33578
0.33646
0.33713
0.33779
0.34142
0.34661
0.35096
PNI
1.00809
1.02219
1.04617
1.06578
1.08230
1.09525
1.09659
1.09792
1.09923
1.10053
1.10181
1.10919
1.12045
1.13064
πNI
0.06734
0.08231
0.10452
0.12089
0.13388
0.14365
0.14465
0.14563
0.14660
0.14755
0.14849
0.15385
0.16188
0.16902
QNI LNI
2.80736
2.43464
1.95634
1.65994
1.45570
1.31829
1.30499
1.29202
1.27937
1.26704
1.25499
1.18838
1.09498
1.01817
PNI/ VNI
0.71859
0.69398
0.66028
0.63695
0.61914
0.60608
0.60477
0.60347
0.60220
0.60094
0.59971
0.59273
0.58238
0.57333
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
8.98952
0.55939
1.50851
0.08638
1.24888
0.00824
0.7765
0.82789
0.20
6.84355
0.60908
1.56744
0.15743
1.20271
0.02832
1.07741
0.76731
0.30
4.73526
0.69019
1.67517
0.23606
1.16365
0.06737
1.11779
0.69465
0.40
3.68743
0.75624
1.77079
0.27934
1.15133
0.09867
1.03003
0.65018
0.50
3.05542
0.81255
1.85667
0.30707
1.14907
0.12371
0.93824
0.61889
0.59
2.66604
0.85720
1.92722
0.32485
1.15093
0.14238
0.86605
0.59720
0.60
2.62976
0.86187
1.93471
0.32653
1.15128
0.14427
0.85869
0.59506
0.61
2.59462
0.86649
1.94215
0.32816
1.15164
0.14613
0.85146
0.59297
0.62
2.56057
0.87106
1.94952
0.32975
1.15202
0.14796
0.84436
0.59093
0.63
2.52757
0.87558
1.95682
0.33130
1.15242
0.14976
0.83738
0.58892
0.64
2.49555
0.88005
1.96407
0.33280
1.15284
0.15153
0.83052
0.58696
0.70
2.32187
0.90591
2.00636
0.34102
1.15563
0.16159
0.79180
0.57598
0.80
2.08779
0.94576
2.07270
0.35229
1.16105
0.17648
0.73550
0.56016
0.90
1.90317
0.98221
2.13455
0.36133
1.16696
0.18950
0.68768
0.54670
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
capital. Intuitively, the increase in quality of the service good helps the firm to exercise
greater product differentiation in order to reduce the competition between the two firms.
This can be seen from (4), where an increase in quality of the Northern good lowers the
level of point of indifference in terms of taste for quality. Under this form of production,
the only way to raise the quality of the service good is to employ more workers per unit
of service good produced. Nevertheless, the effect of trying to differentiate their service
90
good is insufficient to overcome the increase in price differential and thus results in a fall
in quantity demanded. The effect of the fall in quantity demanded exceeds that of the
increase in per-unit employment and thus drives down employment by the Northern firm.
In addition, in terms of per-unit profit, the increase in price is insufficient to cover the
increased wage bill, which thus results in a fall in per-unit profit. This, together with a
fall in quantity demanded, subsequently drives down overall profits of the Northern firm.
Under the situation where the firm outsources the manual component, the graphs
corresponding to (8) and (9) display a rightward and upward shift respectively at all
levels of human capital. Our numerical results here indicate an increase in per unit
employment and both the quality of the manual component from the supplier and that of
the service good. However, the quantity of the service good sold across all levels of
human capital falls, with this fall sufficient in leading to a reduction in overall
employment as well. The price of the service good is actually lower than that in the base
case across all levels of human capital compared to the base case, though they behave in
a similar manner in terms of its changes as human capital changes.20 Given the nature of
the production function, it is optimal to raise the inputs attributed to each of the
components to raise the overall quality of the service good, which acts to increase the
extent of product differentiation for similar reasons as documented above. Despite the
increase in quality and fall in price of the Northern firm’s service good, the fall in
quantity demanded would suggest that the price differential effect dominates the product
differential effect, with this outcome dominating the per-unit increase in employment and
thus decreasing overall employment.
20
We have also considered a different set of parameter values and found that it is possible for the price to
be higher for some levels of human capital compared to the base case. Nevertheless, the mode of
production undertaken by the Northern firm is based on profitability considerations.
91
One interesting point to note at this juncture is that by considering the relevant
forms of production applicable, we find that whilst quality increases throughout, the price
charged under this case is higher throughout prior to the threshold level of human capital
and is minimally lower beyond the threshold level as compared to the base case. We also
note that the increase in quality that is larger relative to that of price for the former, thus
reducing the price-to-quality ratio. Conventionally, a decrease in the price charged by a
competitor should trigger a similar reaction by other competing firms. However, our
study suggests in fact that the firm, when facing increased competition, can actually raise
the price of its good, depending on the mode of production adopted, while at the same
time raising the quality. Supposing that we consider the two changes separately, the
increase in the latter can be seen as reducing the competitive pressure faced by the
Northern through further differentiation in its product, whilst the former can be
considered as a response arising from a fall in competition. Our model of endogenous
quality thus enables us to capture such an overall response which would otherwise not be
possible under models where the quality cannot be varied in a continuous manner.
It is also interesting to note that the threshold level of human capital has dropped
slightly compared to the preceding section. Recall that the per-unit employment has
increased. This increase in per-unit employment actually reduces the marginal product of
an additional worker per unit of the service good produced and thus the integrated form
of production can be considered to be less productive due to its greater use of workers.
The fall in threshold level of human capital can be explained by the following. The
above situation coupled with the form of production function used brings about the
92
situation where the fragmented mode can be seen as being a more productive form of
production at a lower level of human capital relative to the integrated mode. An increase
in product quality can be spread between the two distinct factors of production under the
former compared to the latter, which will be more optimal. Subsequently, this may
suggest that the cost of undertaking outsourcing may be seen by the Northern firm as
being sufficiently low relative to that of employing workers at a lower level of human
capital. Hence, we have a transition from the integrated to the fragmented form of
production at a lower threshold level of human capital. Applying the relevant mode of
production based on the level of human capital, the variables do change in a similar
manner as that in the preceding section, with intuitions that can be applied in the same
manner with respect to the transition from integrated to fragmented form of production.
2.4.2 Quality of the Southern Firm’s Service Good
We consider the other factor in our model associated with the competitiveness of
the Southern firm, a change in the quality of the Southern firm’s service good. In this
analysis, we consider a 20% increase in the quality of the service good produced by the
Southern firm, which in this framework can be considered as an attempt to reduce the
degree of product differentiation and thus an increase in competition between each firm’s
good. The numerical results for this case are displayed in Table 2.5.
We compare this situation with the base case situation.
Under integrated
production by the Northern firm, there is an increase in the per-unit employment and the
93
Table 2.5: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a 20% increase in the quality of the Southern firm’s service good
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.59
0.60
0.61
0.62
0.63
0.64
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
11.2955
9.00272
6.57499
5.28038
4.46324
3.94404
3.89501
3.84741
3.80118
3.75626
3.71260
3.47411
3.14818
2.88733
VNI
1.44206
1.50336
1.60301
1.68390
1.75287
1.80772
1.81347
1.81916
1.82479
1.83035
1.83587
1.86780
1.91722
1.96269
QNI
0.23468
0.26107
0.29284
0.31201
0.32520
0.33413
0.33500
0.33585
0.33668
0.33749
0.33828
0.34266
0.34887
0.35404
PNI
0.97111
0.97873
0.99494
1.00996
1.02344
1.03438
1.03553
1.03667
1.03781
1.03892
1.04003
1.04646
1.05641
1.06555
πNI
0.04829
0.06260
0.08427
0.10046
0.11338
0.12313
0.12413
0.12511
0.12608
0.12703
0.12797
0.13334
0.14139
0.14855
QNI LNI
2.65081
2.35032
1.92539
1.64752
1.45145
1.31783
1.30484
1.29215
1.27978
1.26769
1.25589
1.19046
1.09832
1.02224
PNI/ VNI
0.67342
0.65103
0.62067
0.59978
0.58386
0.57220
0.57102
0.56986
0.56873
0.56761
0.56651
0.56026
0.55101
0.54290
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
9.47711
0.57854
1.58021
0.03682
1.23272
0.00131
0.34898
0.78010
0.20
7.13399
0.62494
1.62534
0.12168
1.17529
0.01475
0.86803
0.72310
0.30
4.85847
0.70073
1.71273
0.21618
1.12216
0.04902
1.05031
0.65519
0.40
3.74389
0.76280
1.79398
0.26830
1.10140
0.07884
1.00449
0.61394
0.50
3.07952
0.81607
1.86911
0.30161
1.09357
0.10337
0.92881
0.58508
0.59
2.67395
0.85857
1.93205
0.32284
1.09188
0.12188
0.86326
0.56514
0.60
2.63632
0.86303
1.93880
0.32485
1.09188
0.12377
0.85640
0.56317
0.61
2.59991
0.86744
1.94549
0.32679
1.09192
0.12563
0.84964
0.56126
0.62
2.56466
0.87180
1.95214
0.32868
1.09199
0.12745
0.84296
0.55938
0.63
2.53051
0.87612
1.95875
0.33052
1.09208
0.12925
0.83638
0.55754
0.64
2.49740
0.88040
1.96530
0.33231
1.09220
0.13102
0.82990
0.55574
0.70
2.31825
0.90517
2.00373
0.34205
1.09338
0.14108
0.79295
0.54567
0.80
2.07798
0.94347
2.06453
0.35533
1.09664
0.15602
0.73837
0.53118
0.90
1.88948
0.97864
2.12173
0.36592
1.10087
0.16912
0.69141
0.51886
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
quality of the service good. However, the per-unit price, quantity demanded of the
service good, overall profits and employment have all decreased. As indicated above,
these findings reflect the presence of reduced product differentiation, which also suggests
increased competition occurring between the two firms and thus can explain the decrease
in the price of the service good. In view of the results obtained and looking at equation
(4), the decrease in quantity demanded suggests that the product differentiation effect is
94
now weaker relative to the price difference effect. The increase in quality of the service
good is not sufficient relative to that by the Southern firm, which explains the weaker
effect. The increase in per-unit employment would correspond to the rise in quality
arising from the increased competition. The effect of the decrease in quantity demanded
exceeds that of a rise in per-unit employment, leading to the decrease in overall
employment. Overall profits decrease due to the twin effects of a decrease in per-unit
profit and quantity demanded.
The graphs corresponding to (8) and (9) display a rightward and upward shift
respectively under the case where the firm makes use of the outsourcing mode of
production at all levels of human capital. Our numerical results indicate that the direction
of change of the variables is similar to that under the case where the integrated form of
production is undertaken. In addition, the Northern firm now purchases a higher quality
of the manual component from the supplier.
Intuitively, given the nature of the
production function, a rise in the quality of the Southern firm’s service good (which does
not affect the cost of outsourcing) leading to a increase in the Northern firm’s quality of
the service good is best achieved by raising the quality of both components that constitute
the service good.
Combining the results of the two forms of production, the firm will now choose to
outsource the manual component at a lower level of human capital compared to the
benchmark case. This is because as the labour requirement per unit of service good
produced is now higher, the marginal product of an additional worker would now be
lower. Such an effect has a greater influence under the integrated mode of production
95
compared to the outsourcing mode, hence the choice of the former at lower levels of
human capital. This may have also contributed towards the relatively lower cost of
outsourcing the manual component compared to the costs of employing better-educated
workers at all levels of human capital, thus the decrease in the threshold level of human
capital.
2.4.3 Cost of Outsourcing Manual Component
We now turn our attention to internal factors influencing the production process
of the Northern firm. In this analysis, we consider the impact of a 10% decrease in the
base cost of outsourcing the manual component to the supplier on the various variables.
The other analysis deals with a 10% fall in δ (which also has the effect of reducing the
cost of outsourcing), the parameter representing diminishing overall cost of outsourcing
the manual component associated with human capital. It is useful to note that this change
will have no impact on the Northern firm if it is undertaking the integrated form of
production. The numerical results for this case are shown in Table 2.6.
The actual effects and explanations associated with either of the above changes
are similar and thus it suffices to account for the above changes together. Comparing the
base case with this situation under the fragmented mode of production, the graphs
corresponding to (8) and (9) around the intersection display a leftward and upward shift
respectively at all levels of human capital. We find a fall in per-unit employment and
price of the service good, the latter changing in a similar manner as human capital
96
Table 2.6: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a decrease in the cost of outsourcing (10% fall in ρ and 10% fall in δ)
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.51
0.52
0.53
0.54
0.55
0.56
0.57
0.58
0.59
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
10.4471
8.38926
6.18747
5.00070
4.24594
4.18499
4.12612
4.06921
4.01415
3.96087
3.90926
3.85926
3.81077
3.76373
3.71807
3.32529
3.02002
2.77493
VNI
1.33375
1.40092
1.50853
1.59471
1.66753
1.67426
1.68089
1.68744
1.69391
1.70029
1.70660
1.71283
1.71899
1.72508
1.73109
1.78779
1.83917
1.88628
QNI
0.29216
0.31142
0.33451
0.34845
0.35805
0.35886
0.35964
0.36041
0.36115
0.36187
0.36257
0.36326
0.36392
0.36458
0.36521
0.37082
0.37538
0.37919
PNI
0.99449
1.00943
1.03488
1.05570
1.07322
1.07483
1.07641
1.07798
1.07952
1.08104
1.08254
1.08402
1.08548
1.08692
1.08834
1.10165
1.11354
1.12428
πNI
0.08375
0.09992
0.12357
0.14082
0.15442
0.15563
0.15683
0.15800
0.15914
0.16027
0.16138
0.16248
0.16355
0.16460
0.16564
0.17520
0.18353
0.19091
QNI LNI
3.05224
2.61258
2.06980
1.74249
1.52028
1.50183
1.48393
1.46656
1.44970
1.43331
1.41739
1.40190
1.38683
1.37216
1.35788
1.23309
1.13366
1.05223
PNI/ VNI
0.74563
0.72055
0.68602
0.66200
0.64360
0.64197
0.64038
0.63882
0.63730
0.63580
0.63433
0.63288
0.63146
0.63007
0.62870
0.61621
0.60546
0.59603
QNO LNO
1.19024
1.33436
1.24984
1.11284
0.99617
0.98582
0.97569
0.96578
0.95609
0.94660
0.90213
0.82595
0.76330
0.71091
PNO/ VNO
0.83584
0.77745
0.70683
0.66316
0.63219
0.62955
0.62698
0.62447
0.62202
0.61963
0.60847
0.58938
0.57348
0.55992
Fragmented production (10% fall in base cost of outsourcing, ρ)
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.51
0.52
0.53
0.54
0.55
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNO
8.45416
6.43911
4.46237
3.48091
2.88900
2.84231
2.79737
2.75408
2.71234
2.67207
2.49018
2.20154
1.98193
1.80857
VM
0.57530
0.62605
0.70913
0.77695
0.83484
0.84020
0.84549
0.85071
0.85588
0.86097
0.88557
0.93087
0.97186
1.00934
VNO
1.46161
1.51891
1.62477
1.71946
1.80483
1.81292
1.82094
1.82889
1.83676
1.84457
1.88258
1.95406
2.02028
2.08204
QNO
0.14079
0.20723
0.28008
0.31970
0.34482
0.34684
0.34879
0.35067
0.35250
0.35426
0.36227
0.37517
0.38513
0.39308
PNO
1.22166
1.18088
1.14843
1.14028
1.14100
1.14133
1.14169
1.14208
1.14250
1.14295
1.14549
1.15168
1.15859
1.16577
πNI
0.02126
0.04772
0.09245
0.12624
0.15262
0.15495
0.15724
0.15948
0.16167
0.16383
0.17400
0.19185
0.20712
0.22041
97
Fragmented production (10% fall in the diminishing cost of outsourcing associated with
human capital, δ)
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
8.37031
0.58520
1.46021
0.14931
1.21171
0.02389
1.24977
0.82982
0.20
6.41551
0.63055
1.51882
0.21013
1.17761
0.04906
1.34811
0.77534
0.30
4.47555
0.70412
1.62412
0.27796
1.15065
0.09102
1.24401
0.70848
0.40
3.50223
0.76367
1.71657
0.31553
1.14428
0.12280
1.10506
0.66661
0.50
2.91155
0.81423
1.79916
0.33970
1.14549
0.14776
0.98906
0.63668
0.55
2.69437
0.83700
1.83744
0.34887
1.14746
0.15841
0.93998
0.62449
0.56
2.65540
0.84138
1.84488
0.35053
1.14792
0.16042
0.93080
0.62222
0.57
2.61774
0.84571
1.85225
0.35214
1.14840
0.16239
0.92182
0.62000
0.58
2.58133
0.84999
1.85956
0.35370
1.14890
0.16433
0.91303
0.61783
0.59
2.54609
0.85422
1.86680
0.35522
1.14942
0.16623
0.90442
0.61571
0.60
2.51198
0.85840
1.87398
0.35669
1.14995
0.16810
0.89600
0.61364
0.70
2.22199
0.89774
1.94254
0.36937
1.15586
0.18516
0.82073
0.59503
0.80
2.00095
0.93329
2.00592
0.37923
1.16241
0.19979
0.75882
0.57949
0.90
1.82623
0.96575
2.06496
0.38715
1.16917
0.21258
0.70703
0.56620
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
increases as in the base case. Increases in the quality of the manual component, quantity
demanded, profits and overall employment are observed in this case. The lower cost of
purchasing the manual component from the supplier thus actually leads to the firm
placing a higher emphasis in the manual component of its service good, since the fall in
per-unit employment is tantamount to a fall in the quality of the organizational
component. However, we find that the quality of the service good is lower at low levels
of human capital, with this quality being higher than the base case beyond some level of
human capital. Nevertheless, these observations associated with quality of service good
and price occurs at levels of human capital below the threshold level of human capital
where the form of production undertaken is changed.
The change from integrated to fragmented form of production occurs at a much
lower level of threshold level of human capital. This decrease can be solely attributed to
an overall lower cost of outsourcing the manual component at every level of human
capital relative to the wage cost of employing workers. The intuition for the transition
98
from the integrated to fragmented mode of production as human capital increases would
be the same as in section 2.3.3.
2.4.4 Wage Cost
We consider a 25% increase in the wage rate per worker before adjustments for
the human capital level of the worker paid by the service good firm. Table 2.7 provides
the numerical results obtained for this case.
Under the integrated form of production, we find that there is a fall in per-unit
employment, the quality and price of the service good, quantity demanded, overall profits
and overall employment. In this case, the firm is faced with a higher cost of production
that cannot be adjusted by use of other factors of production. The fall in the number of
workers employed per unit of service good produced due to the higher wage cost would,
based on the production function, subsequently lead to a fall in the quality of the service
good. A fall in the quality of the service good would thus require a fall in the per unit
price in order to ensure that this good is still competitively priced. The wages paid out
for every unit produced has actually increased. This, together with a fall in price, lead to
a fall in per unit profit and subsequently overall profit as the quantity demanded falls. The
fall in quantity demanded is the result of the reduced product differential effect
which dominates the fall in price differential, thus raising the level of point of
indifference in terms of taste for quality from equation (4).
99
Table 2.7: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a 15% increase in the base wage rate
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.49
0.50
0.51
0.52
0.53
0.54
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
9.62886
7.68841
5.62882
4.52774
3.88958
3.83147
3.77540
3.72125
3.66893
3.61834
3.34661
2.98706
2.70838
2.48516
VNI
1.22929
1.28388
1.37233
1.44388
1.49904
1.50475
1.51039
1.51596
1.52145
1.52688
1.55814
1.60594
1.64938
1.68931
QNI
0.24974
0.27429
0.30379
0.32158
0.33277
0.33383
0.33485
0.33585
0.33682
0.33776
0.34293
0.35004
0.35581
0.36062
PNI
0.97492
0.98438
1.00293
1.01945
1.03260
1.03398
1.03533
1.03667
1.03800
1.03931
1.04686
1.05841
1.06887
1.07842
πNI
0.05611
0.07095
0.09318
0.10967
0.12158
0.12278
0.12396
0.12511
0.12624
0.12736
0.13367
0.14298
0.15111
0.15833
QNI LNI
2.40472
2.10882
1.70998
1.45604
1.29433
1.27904
1.26420
1.24978
1.23576
1.22214
1.14764
1.04560
0.96368
0.89620
PNI/ VNI
0.79308
0.76672
0.73083
0.70605
0.68884
0.68714
0.68547
0.68384
0.68224
0.68067
0.67186
0.65906
0.64804
0.63838
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
7.89183
0.56281
1.38588
0.07763
1.24034
0.00614
0.61263
0.89498
0.20
5.96489
0.60997
1.43092
0.15545
1.18801
0.02541
0.92727
0.83024
0.30
4.08779
0.68723
1.51658
0.24159
1.14153
0.06476
0.98757
0.75270
0.40
3.16428
0.75056
1.59505
0.28882
1.12501
0.09677
0.91389
0.70531
0.49
2.65676
0.79975
1.66000
0.31638
1.12032
0.12011
0.84054
0.67489
0.50
2.61158
0.80486
1.66691
0.31889
1.12014
0.12245
0.83281
0.67198
0.51
2.56816
0.80990
1.67377
0.32131
1.12001
0.12474
0.82518
0.66915
0.52
2.52639
0.81488
1.68057
0.32365
1.11992
0.12699
0.81767
0.66639
0.53
2.48617
0.81980
1.68732
0.32591
1.11988
0.12919
0.81028
0.66370
0.54
2.44742
0.82466
1.69401
0.32810
1.11988
0.13136
0.80300
0.66108
0.60
2.24157
0.85266
1.73309
0.33983
1.12062
0.14356
0.76176
0.64660
0.70
1.97521
0.89551
1.79441
0.35532
1.12379
0.16133
0.70183
0.62627
0.80
1.77346
0.93441
1.85160
0.36727
1.12836
0.17660
0.65135
0.60940
0.90
1.61483
0.97009
1.90520
0.37681
1.13367
0.18994
0.60848
0.59504
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
The graphs around the intersection corresponding to equations (8) and (9) display
a leftward and upward shift respectively under the fragmented form of production as
compared to the base case at all levels of human capital. The effect of the increase in
wage rate on the various variables is similar to that under the integrated form of
production.
In addition, the quality of the manual component purchased from the
supplier by the firm is now higher. The increase in wage rate now makes the cost of
100
outsourcing the manual component relatively cheaper. Under this form of production and
in view of the relatively lower outsourcing cost, the firm will, whilst reducing per unit
employment, and thus the quality of the organizational component, replaces this with an
increase in the quality of the manual component. This accounts for the relatively smaller
drop in quality of the service good under fragmented production compared to the
situation for integrated production. A smaller fall in quality would thus allow the firm to
reduce the price charged by a smaller extent. The effect arising from reduced product
differentiation is now less dominant compared to the fall in price differential, resulting in
a smaller fall in quantity demanded compared to the integrated mode of production.
By comparing the profits under the two types of production, we find that the
threshold level of human capital has decreased by a large extent. The higher cost of
employing workers at any level of human capital relative to the cost of outsourcing the
manual component at a lower level of human capital would explain the large decrease in
the threshold level.
2.4.5 General Productivity Level
The final internal factor we will examine is the change in the general productivity
level of the firm. We consider a 20% increase in the general productivity parameter, with
Table 2.8 providing the numerical results for this case.
101
Table 2.8: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a 20% increase in general per unit productivity
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.61
0.62
0.63
0.64
0.65
0.70
0.80
0.90
LNI
9.82922
7.94334
5.90538
4.79638
4.08655
3.58777
3.54578
3.50497
3.46529
3.42668
3.38911
3.21529
2.92495
2.69128
VNI
1.50584
1.59175
1.72771
1.83546
1.92592
2.00451
2.01185
2.01911
2.02628
2.03337
2.04039
2.07438
2.13752
2.19531
QNI
0.33403
0.34802
0.36485
0.37507
0.38215
0.38746
0.38792
0.38837
0.38881
0.38924
0.38966
0.39164
0.39505
0.39790
PNI
1.03424
1.05498
1.08754
1.11269
1.13320
1.15055
1.15214
1.15372
1.15527
1.15680
1.15831
1.16559
1.17887
1.19078
πNI
0.12301
0.14025
0.16506
0.18294
0.19694
0.20845
0.20950
0.21053
0.21154
0.21254
0.21352
0.21823
0.22672
0.23424
QNI LNI
3.28321
2.76444
2.15460
1.79898
1.56168
1.39011
1.37547
1.36122
1.34733
1.33380
1.32060
1.25922
1.15549
1.07087
PNI/ VNI
0.68682
0.66278
0.62947
0.60622
0.58839
0.57398
0.57268
0.57140
0.57014
0.56891
0.56769
0.56190
0.55151
0.54242
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
8.10650
0.52309
1.65227
0.17612
1.28478
0.03708
8.10650
0.77759
0.20
6.20438
0.57267
1.72607
0.23613
1.24644
0.06908
6.20438
0.72212
0.30
4.32958
0.65420
1.86017
0.30151
1.21769
0.11943
4.32958
0.65461
0.40
3.39292
0.72089
1.97842
0.33689
1.21206
0.15611
3.39292
0.61264
0.50
2.82515
0.77784
2.08406
0.35930
1.21458
0.18428
2.82515
0.58280
0.60
2.44104
0.82777
2.17968
0.37486
1.22041
0.20689
2.44104
0.55990
0.61
2.40926
0.83245
2.18877
0.37616
1.22109
0.20892
2.40926
0.55789
0.62
2.37845
0.83708
2.19778
0.37743
1.22178
0.21091
2.37845
0.55592
0.63
2.34857
0.84165
2.20671
0.37865
1.22248
0.21287
2.34857
0.55398
0.64
2.31958
0.84618
2.21557
0.37985
1.22319
0.21479
2.31958
0.55209
0.65
2.29143
0.85065
2.22435
0.38101
1.22391
0.21668
2.29143
0.55023
0.70
2.16211
0.87236
2.26718
0.38636
1.22763
0.22566
2.16211
0.54148
0.80
1.94930
0.91270
2.34798
0.39525
1.23537
0.24163
1.94930
0.52614
0.90
1.78094
0.94960
2.42315
0.40235
1.24322
0.25549
1.78094
0.51306
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
We find that there is a fall in the per unit employment level but an increase in the
quality of the service good, the quantity demanded, price of the service good, profits and
overall employment under the integrated mode of production. With a general increase in
per-unit productivity, the endogenous factor used in production, which is labour in this
case, is more productive and thus less workers per unit of output produced is required.
The increase in quality of the service good suggests that the firm does not reduce the
102
employment level in a one-for-one manner. Here, a reduction in the number of workers
used to produce each unit reduces the firm’s cost and yet raising the quality of the service
good provides the firm with the opportunity to raise its price slightly. These changes
result in a definite increase in per unit profit.
Moreover, the increase in quantity
demanded suggests that the quality differential effect is relatively stronger compared to
the price differential effect, thus the increase in quantity demanded, with this subsequent
effect being relatively stronger to drive the increase in overall employment.
Profit
increases unambiguously as a result of higher per unit profit and quantity demanded.
Under the fragmented mode of production, the graphs associated with (8) and (9)
have shifted to the left and shifted downwards respectively, at all levels of human capital.
The effect on the various variables considered above is the same with similar intuitions.
In addition, we also find that there is a decrease in the quality of the manual component
being purchased from the supplier. The intuition for this decrease would be similar to
that of the decrease in per unit employment. This additional avenue of cost reduction
arising from higher per unit productivity would result in an unambiguous increase in per
unit profit. We also note that the quantity demanded of the service good can be higher
under the fragmented mode of production compared to the integrated mode of production.
Interestingly, we note that there is no noticeable change in the threshold level of
human capital.
It may be that the impact brought about by a change in general
productivity level does not differ between either mode of production, thus the unchanged
threshold level of human capital.
103
2.5
Production Share Parameters
Up to this point, our above analysis is based on the organizational component’s
production share being larger than that of the manual component. It would be of interest
to analyze the base case outcome by switching the relative production shares attributed to
each component (i.e. setting β=1/3 and keeping all other parameter values unchanged).
The results are shown in table 2.9.
The key observation in this case arising from the change in production shares is
the higher threshold level of human capital required before the Northern firm switches to
the fragmented mode of production. A higher production share of the manual component
would delay the need to pursue a differentiated cost strategy since the difference in
productivity between the manual and organizational component would not be sufficiently
large until higher levels of human capital are attained, following which the effect of a
higher wage cost relative to the cost of outsourcing the manual component sets in. Note
that upon the firm switching to the fragmented mode of production, the firm now
purchases a higher quality of the manual component from the supplier and this can be
attributed to the need to make up for the fall in contribution towards the quality of the
service good from the organizational component arising from its reduced productive
share. It is not cost optimal to retain the same level of per-unit employment compared to
the base case due to the low marginal increase in quality from employing an additional
worker to work on that unit of the good. Nevertheless, with the increasing cost of
obtaining a higher quality of the manual component from the supplier for a given level of
104
Table 2.9: Numerical results under both forms of production for different values of HN
with a change in the productive share of the organizational component (β=1/3)
Integrated production
HN
0.15
0.20
0.30
0.40
0.50
0.60
0.70
0.71
0.72
0.73
0.74
0.80
0.90
LNI
9.99795
8.10984
6.05233
4.92512
4.20086
3.69068
3.30904
3.27602
3.24379
3.21232
3.18158
3.01118
2.77124
VNI
1.44850
1.50765
1.59890
1.66954
1.72785
1.77787
1.82186
1.82599
1.83007
1.83411
1.83811
1.86127
1.89705
QNI
0.32259
0.33435
0.34905
0.35830
0.36487
0.36989
0.37390
0.37426
0.37461
0.37495
0.37529
0.37721
0.38002
PNI
1.02054
1.03467
1.05671
1.07370
1.08758
1.09934
1.10955
1.11051
1.11145
1.11238
1.11330
1.11860
1.12672
πNI
0.11069
0.12339
0.14163
0.15478
0.16508
0.17356
0.18076
0.18143
0.18208
0.18273
0.18336
0.18702
0.19257
QNI LNI
3.22527
2.71156
2.11256
1.76465
1.53277
1.36513
1.23724
1.22607
1.21515
1.20447
1.19403
1.13585
1.05312
PNI/ VNI
0.70455
0.68628
0.66090
0.64311
0.62944
0.61835
0.60902
0.60817
0.60732
0.60649
0.60567
0.60099
0.59393
Fragmented production
HN
LNO
VM
VNO
QNO
PNO
πNI
QNO LNO PNO/ VNO
0.15
4.55874
0.84921
1.18508
0.07337
1.09964
0.00465
0.33449
0.92790
0.20
3.37395
0.89891
1.22544
0.16921
1.04476
0.02567
0.57090
0.85256
0.30
2.25728
0.98249
1.30181
0.27166
0.99694
0.07062
0.61322
0.76582
0.40
1.72536
1.05249
1.37157
0.32560
0.98054
0.10698
0.56177
0.71490
0.50
1.41358
1.11321
1.43518
0.35884
0.97606
0.13578
0.50725
0.68010
0.60
1.20780
1.16700
1.49344
0.38137
0.97692
0.15915
0.46062
0.65414
0.70
1.06115
1.21534
1.54709
0.39766
0.98036
0.17862
0.42198
0.63368
0.71
1.04875
1.21992
1.55222
0.39904
0.98078
0.18039
0.41850
0.63186
0.72
1.03668
1.22445
1.55732
0.40039
0.98122
0.18213
0.41508
0.63007
0.73
1.02495
1.22894
1.56238
0.40170
0.98168
0.18385
0.41173
0.62832
0.74
1.01353
1.23340
1.56741
0.40298
0.98214
0.18555
0.40843
0.62660
0.80
0.95089
1.25928
1.59679
0.40999
0.98508
0.19518
0.38986
0.61691
0.90
0.86467
1.29958
1.64308
0.41967
0.99043
0.20953
0.36287
0.60279
(Note that numerical results in bold denote the lower and upper bound within which the threshold level of
human capital lies)
human capital, the firm is unable to make up fully for the lower quality from the
organizational component, thus accounting for the lower quality of the service good
under the fragmented mode of production. From the preference side, the loss in utility
from consuming a lower quality of the service good upon the Northern firm switching to
the fragmented mode of production is less than the utility gained from cost savings
gained through paying a lower price for the service good, which would explain for the
105
increase in quantity demanded, even though the price-to-quality ratio has increased under
this mode of production.
2.6
Modifying the Cost of Outsourcing
The above model assumes that the cost of outsourcing decreases, albeit in a
diminishing manner, as HN increases. In this section, we briefly mention and provide
some intuition behind the actions of the firm under the situation where the overall base
cost of outsourcing remains unchanged. Simply put, outsourcing cost is now specified as
ρ eV instead of ( ρ H N δ ) eV .21
M
M
For sufficiently high values of ρ , as HN increases, the firm will choose to
produce both components, thus remaining an integrated entity, since overall profits
through integration remain higher than that of fragmentation.22 To account for this, we
first observe that if the firm is under the outsourcing mode of production, it will reduce
the quality of the manual component that it purchases and per-unit employment. As
human capital increases, each worker is actually able to produce a higher quality of the
organizational component.
The exponential increase in the quality of the manual
component is likely to have resulted in the cost of increasing the quality of the manual
component purchased being more expensive than employing workers to raise the quality
of the organizational component instead. In fact, the observation of the firm reducing the
quality of the manual component purchased suggests that they would prefer to release
21
Numerical results for this case have not been included. These are available upon request.
Depending on the parameter values, if ρ is sufficiently low, we can theoretically have a situation where
the firm actually outsources the manual component at low values of HN and undertakes the integrated mode
of production beyond a threshold level of HN. This would be the opposite of Proposition 3.
22
106
less workers to produce a higher quality of the organizational component to make up for
the loss in the quality of the manual component.
On the whole, if the element of reliability is absent (i.e. outsourcing cost doesn’t
decrease as HN increases), then there is no avenue for the Northern firm to differentiate its
costs. The Northern firm would thus continue with the integrated mode of production.
2.7
General Discussion
Some interesting results have been obtained from the above comparative statics
analysis. We attempt to provide a general discussion on the implications of selected
outcomes and some possible policy implications by combining the various findings that
have been obtained through the above analyses.
In the above model, we find that increased competitive pressures arising from a
fall in the Southern firm’s service good can have a negative impact on the Northern
firm’s various decision variables as well as quantity demanded, overall employment and
profits. We have also noted the attempt by the firm to try to further differentiate its
product as a result of increased competition. The above studies of the effects of internal
factors on the various variables provide some useful implications on the policies that can
be formulated to deal with increased competition. Government measures targeted at
lowering the cost faced by the supplier can be translated into lower cost of outsourcing
faced by the Northern service good firm. This can then be translated into lower prices
107
and higher overall product quality, which reduces the competition level and thus raises
the extent of product differentiation.
In terms of policies that can be implemented to assist the firm directly, this may
come in the form of reducing the firm’s social security contributions or subsidizing wage
costs (by adjusting w). However, it is difficult to gauge the optimal level of assistance,
either to the firm or to the supplier as mentioned above, that should be rendered as such
assistance may result in deadweight losses that can potentially reduce the welfare of the
society as a whole, which we do not model here. A non-intervention approach should be
that the firm should strive to raise its productivity levels to cope with competition from
foreign firms.
This can come in the form of raising operational efficiency and
streamlining and restructuring their operations. In Singapore, the Port of Singapore
Authority and Singapore Airport Terminal Services have recently recorded improved
bottom-lines despite intense foreign competition after having undertaken measures,
sometimes painful ones in the form of retrenchments, to operate in a more efficient and
effective manner. Also playing an important role in fending off foreign competition
would be to upgrade the skills of workers in the firm continually to help workers working
in such firms to be able to produce higher quality of the service good whilst keeping the
price of its good competitive.
Our study above also analysed the impact of an increase in product quality of the
Southern firm on the Northern firm. Depending on the nature of the service good, the
Southern firm may want to reduce the quality of its service good so as to further
differentiate its product or, in other instances, to raise the quality of its service good so as
108
to compete with the Northern firm. It may be more likely that firms would try to raise
service quality and yet try, at the very minimum, to keep price increases low. A richer
model where the Southern firm’s decision-making process is endogenized will certainly
provide a more comprehensive analysis of North-South competition in the service-link
industry.
2.8
Conclusion and Future Research
In this study, we have considered a simple two-country model with competition in
the provision of service links. Our motivation arises from the fact that certain industries
face limitations in terms of the locational aspect of outsourcing the lower-end tasks in
that such firms can only either produce all the components of their product or outsource
those components to a supplier located domestically. We have also studied the role of
human capital in determining whether the integrated or fragmented mode of production
would be adopted. Our findings indicate the existence of a threshold level of human
capital where the integrated mode of production is adopted for human capital levels
below the threshold level, with the fragmented mode of production implemented upon
crossing that threshold. An interesting consequence pertaining to the transition from the
integrated to outsourcing mode of production would be the jump in the extent of product
differentiation, with the firm ceasing to serve her fringe customers as a result.
Comparative statics analysis was carried out to determine the impact of external and
internal factors on various variables associated with the Northern firm such as product
quality and price, per unit employment, required quality of the outsourced component,
profits, quantity demanded and overall employment. Table 2.10 provides a summary of
109
the various comparative statics analyses as well as the changes that occur upon transition
from the integrated to the fragmented mode of production. Some implications regarding
suitable initiatives to deal with competitive pressures were discussed.
Whilst the above study provides some useful results on two-country competition
in sectors where there are limitations on the location where components can be
outsourced to, we note that there can be other factors that determine the consumer’s
preference on where to acquire such services associated with these sectors.
One
interesting addition would be to study the role of distance and transport or
communication costs required. In this model, we would expect that the consumer’s
distance and such costs incurred would be inversely related to the quantity demanded.
The Northern firm’s pricing decision would then have to be varied accordingly depending
on such costs. Another improvement, as mentioned in the preceding section, would be to
allow the various variables associated with the Southern firm to be endogenous. This
would allow for a richer study of how changes in various factors can have an impact on
both the Northern and Southern firm. Such a study will be more realistic as changes in
the cost conditions faced by either firm will realistically have an impact on the pricing
and quality decisions and thus profits on both firms. This can be further augmented by
having the price variable faced by the supplier to be endogenous. Such improvements
can be implemented in future studies on this area of research on domestic outsourcing
and foreign competition.
110
Table 2.10: Summary of outcomes of comparative statics exercise of an increase in
respective parameters in section 4 under the relevant production mode
(b) Integrated mode (for a given level of human capital in Northern economy)
Total CurrPNI /
Parameter
LNI
VNI
QNI
PNI
Empent
VNI
loyed Profit
Price of service good
PS
+
+
+
of Southern firm
Quality of service
VS
+
+
good of Southern firm
Base cost of
ρ
Not applicable under integrated mode
outsourcing
Outsourcing cost
δ
Not applicable under integrated mode
parameter associated
with h
Base wage rate
w
+
General per-unit
λ
+
+
+
+
+
productivity
(b) Fragmented mode (for a given level of human capital in Northern economy)
Parameter
LNO
VNO
VM
QNO
PNO
PNO /
VNO
Total
Employed
Threshold
h*
Current
Profit
-
-
-
-
Price of service
good of Southern
firm
PS
+
+
+
-
+
(h*)
Quality of service
good of Southern
firm
VS
+
+
+
-
+
-
-
-
-
Base cost of
outsourcing
ρ
-
+
+
-
-
+
-
+
δ
-
+
+
-
-
+
-
+
w
-
+
-
-
+
-
Outsourcing cost
parameter
associated with h
Base wage rate
+ (for
h*)
-
no
General per-unit
λ
+
+
+
+
+
chanproductivity
ge
Note: “h*” denote respectively very low and very high levels of human capital that are much
lower and much higher than the threshold level of human capital.
(c) Changes in variables upon switch from integrated to fragmented mode upon instant of
crossing threshold h*
From LNI to
LNO
From VNI to
VNO
FromQNI to
QNO
From PNI to
PNO
Price to
quality ratio
Total
Employed
Current
Profit
-
+
-
+
-
-
+
111
Another interesting modification would be to consider a continuum of manual
components where the firm gradually outsources each variety and concentrate
increasingly on the organizational component.
Under such a model, the so-called
“threshold” level of human capital would then be considered to be a juncture where the
firm then fully concentrates on the organizational component.
112
References
Abraham, Katherine G. and Susan K. Taylor (1996), Firms’ Use of Outside Contractors:
Theory and Evidence, Journal of Labor Economics, 14 (3), 394-424
Acemoglu, Daron (1997a), “Technology, Unemployment and Efficiency”, European
Economic Review, 41, 525-533
Acemoglu, Daron (1997b), “Training and Innovation in an Imperfect Labour Market”,
Review of Economic Studies, 64, 445-464
Acemoglu, Daron and Fabrizio Zilibotti (2001), “Productivity Differences”, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 116, 563-606
Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion and Fabrizio Zilibotti (2003), Vertical Integration
and Distance to Frontier, NBER Working Paper, w9191
Aghion, Philippe and Peter Howitt (1994), “Growth and Unemployment”, Review of
Economic Studies, 61, 477-494
Antràs, Pol and Elhanan Helpman (2004), Global Sourcing, Journal of Political Economy,
112 (3), 552-580
Bartoloni, Eleonora and Maurizio Baussola (2001), “The Determinants of Technology
Adoption in Italian Manufacturing Industries”, Review of Industrial Organization, 19,
305-328
Basu, Susanto and David N. Weil (1998), “Appropriate Technology and Growth”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 1025-1054
Berman, Eli, John Bound and Stephen Machin (1998), “Implications of Skill-Biased
Technological Change: International Evidence”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113,
1245-1279
Besley, Timothy and Anne Case, “Modelling Technology Adoption in Developing
Countries”, American Economic Review, 83, 396-402
Brander, James A. and Barbara J. Spencer (1985), Export Subsidies and International
Market Share Rivalry, Journal of International Trade, 18 (1), 83-100
Burda, Michael C. and Barbara Dluhosch (2002), Cost Competition, Fragmentation and
Globalization, Review of International Economics, 10 (3), 424-441
Canton, Erik J. F., Henri L. F. de Groot and Richard Nahuis, “Vested Interests,
Population Ageing and Technology Adoption”, European Journal of Political Economy,
18, 631-652
113
Chan, William and Wing Suen (2003), “The Long-Term Effectiveness of the Hong Kong
Employees Retraining Programme”, Pacific Economic Review, 8 (1), 79-98
Chander, Parkash and Shandre M. Thangavelu (2004), “Technology Adoption, Education
and Immigration Policy”, Journal of Development Economics, 75 (1), 79-94
Cheng, Leonard K., Larry D. Qiu and Guofu Tan (2001), Foreign Direct Investment and
International Fragmentation of Production, in Arndt, Sven W. and Henryk Kierzkowski
(eds.), Fragmentation: New Production Patterns in the World Economy, Oxford
University Press, Oxford, 2001, 165-186.
Danninger, Stephan and Jacob Mincer (2000), “Technology, Unemployment and
Inflation”, NBER Working Paper 7817
Davis, Donald and Trevor Reeve (2002), “Human Capital, Unemployment and Relative
Wages in a Global Economy”, in: Greenaway, David, Richard Upward and Katharine
Wakelin, eds., Trade, Investment, Migration and Labour Market Adjustment (Palgrave
Macmillan, New York), 7-27
Eaton, J. and S. Kortum (1996), “Trade in Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in the
OECD”, Journal of International Economics, 40, 251-278
Feenstra, Robert C. (1998), “Integration of Trade and Disintegration of Production in the
Global Economy, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12 (4), 31-50
Feenstra, Robert C. and Gordon H. Hanson (1996), Foreign Investment, Outsourcing and
Relative Wages, in Feenstra, Robert C., Gene M. Grossman and Douglas A. Irwin (eds.),
The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, MIT
Press, Cambridge, Mass.
Grossman, Gene and Elhanan Helpman (2002), Inegration Versus Outsourcing in
Industry Equilibrium, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (1), 85-120
Grossman, Gene and Elhanan Helpman (2005), Outsourcing in a Global Economy,
Review of Economic Studies, 72 (1), 135-159
Harris, Richard G. (2001), A Communication-Based Model of Global Production
Fragmentation, in Arndt, Sven W. and Henryk Kierzkowski (eds.), Fragmentation: New
Production Patterns in the World Economy, Oxford University Press, New York
Haskel, Jonathan and Christopher Martin (1993), “Do Skill Shortages Reduce
Productivity? Theory and Evidence from the United Kingdom”, Economic Journal, 103
(417), 386-394
Ho, Kong Weng and Hian Teck Hoon (2003), Service Links and Wage Inequality,
Department of Economics, National University of Singapore, working paper wp0301
114
Ho, Kong Weng and Randy Chih Wei Tan (2005), “Non-Monotonic Relationship between
Human Capital and Unemployment: An Exploratory Study with Empirical Evidence on
Singapore”, NUS mimeo
Hollanders, Hugo and Bas ter Weel (2002), “Technology, Knowledge Spillovers and
Changes in Employment Structure: Evidence from Six OECD Countries”, Labour
Economics, 9, 579-599
Hoon, Hian Teck (1993), “Efficiency Wages and Economic Growth”, Economics Letters,
42, 201-208
Howitt, Peter and David Mayer-Foulkes (2002), “R&D, Implementation and Stagnation:
A Schumpeterian Theory of Convergence Clubs”, NBER Working Paper 9104
Jones, Ronald W. and Henryk Kierzkowski (1990), The Role of Services in Production
and International Trade: A Theoretical Framework, in Jones, Ronald W. and Anne O.
Krueger (eds.), The Political Economy of International Trade: Essays in Honor of Robert
E. Baldwin, Basil Blackwell, Cambridge
Lindbeck, Assar and Dennis J. Snower (1996), “Reorganization of Firms and LabourMarket Inequality”, American Economic Review, 86, 315-321
Lloyd-Ellis, Huw and Joanne Roberts (2002), Twin Engines of Growth: Skills and
Technology as Equal Partners in Balanced Growth”, Journal of Economic Growth, 7, 87115
Machin, Stephen and John van Reenen (1998), “Technology and Changes in Skill
Structure: Evidence from Seven OECD Countries”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113,
1215-1244
Morrison Paul, Catherine J. and Donald S. Siegel (2001), “The Impacts of Technology,
Trade and Outsourcing on Employment and Labour Composition”, Scandinavian Journal
of Economics, 103, 241-264
Motta, Massimo (1993), Endogenous Quality Choice: Price vs Quantity Competition,
Journal of Industrial Organization, 41 (2), 113-131
Mussa, Michael and Sherwin Rosen (1978), Monopoly and Product Quality, Journal of
Economic Theory, 18 (2), 301-317
Nakanishi, Yasuo (2002), “Employment and IT Capital in Japan”, Applied Economics
Letters, 9, 865-867
Nahuis, Richard and Jeoren van de Ven (1999), “Endogenous Growth in a Small Open
Economy”, De Economist, 147, 353-360
115
Nelson, Richard R. and Edmund S. Phelps (1966), “Investment in Humans,
Technological Diffusion and Economic Growth”, American Economic Review, 56, 69-75
Nickell, Stephen (1979), “Education and Lifetime Patterns of Unemployment”, Journal
of Political Economy, 87 (5) Pt. 2, S117-S131
Papageorgiou, Chris (2003), “Distinguishing between the Effects of Primary and Postprimary Education on Economic Growth”, Review of Development Economics, 7, 622635
Pissarides, Christopher A. (2000), Equilibrium Unemployment Theory (2nd Edition), MIT
Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts
Postel-Vinay, Fabian (2002), “The Dynamics of Technological Unemployment”,
International Economic Review, 43, 737-760
Richardson, Katarina and Gerard J. van der Berg (2001), “The Effect of Vocational
Employment Training on the Individual Transition Rate from Unemployment to Work”,
Swedish Economic Policy Review, 8, 175-213
Shaked, Avner and John Sutton (1982), Relaxing Price Competition through Product
Differentiation, Review of Economic Studies, 49 (1), 3-13
Tirole, Jean (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass
Tuijnman, Albert, (1999), “Lifelong Learning Policies in a New Technological Era”, in
Mitter, Swasti, and Maria-Ines Bastos (eds.), Europe and Developing Countries in the
Globalised Information Economy: Employment and Distance Education, Routledge, New
York
Yashiv, Eran (2000), “Hiring as Investment Behavior”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 3,
486-522
116
[...]... non-monotonic relationship between technology adoption and employment under the onslaught of increasing levels of human capital Using appropriate parameters for our numerical simulation, we find that while increases in human capital encourage adoption of higher levels of technology and raises the sum of future discounted profits of an additional worker, wages and interview rate, such increases can only... additional workers over and above the optimal level of employment will result in future losses in terms of lower total future discounted profits from having these surplus workers, which will thus necessitate the laying off or reduction in the optimal level of employment amongst the firms Hence, we have this non-monotonic relationship between unemployment and technology adoption and also unemployment and. .. Empirical findings by Papageorgiou (2003) based on World Bank data revealed that post-primary education contributes significantly towards technology innovation and adoption whilst primary education contributes towards final output production Hollanders and Weel (2002) found a positive relationship between skill upgrading and R&D intensity in manufacturing based on an empirical study of six OECD countries... human capital is carried out in section 1.3 We consider changes in other parameters in section 1.4 Section 1.5 provides a general discussion of the implications of the outcomes obtained Section 1.6 concludes this chapter 1.2 The Model The economy consists of a collection of identical firms indexed from 0 to 1 that are producing the final good The population consists of economically active agents that can... may no longer require a cameraman to accompany them in news reporting should future technological developments result in improved versions of the videophone Thus, technological progress could potentially have destructive effects on employment, with serious repercussions on job creation within the economy as well The above discussion leads to the following question: does improved skill profile amongst... leading nations Eaton and Kortum (1996) did an empirical study to assess the proportion of a nation’s growth that can be attributed 2 to its own research efforts and found that such efforts within major economies, namely United States, Japan and Germany, form a significant proportion of their growth Nahuis and van de Ven (1999) further postulated that efforts that concentrate on the adaptation of technology... small nations based on the empirical outcomes from Eaton and Kortum (1996) Computations by Howitt and Mayer-Foulkes (2002) revealed that 80% of the global R&D expenditure can be attributed to 5 countries, this figure rising to 95% with the inclusion of another 6 countries, thus suggesting that most other nations are embarking on technology adoption rather than being at the forefront of the global technological. .. relationship between IT capital and labour and further indicated that the impact has increased during recent times Other writers have also studied the relationship between human capital and unemployment An increase in education capital is found to reduce unemployment by Davis and Reeve (2003), regardless of whether the economy is closed or open Empirical studies by Richardson and van der Berg (2001) and. .. proportion of skilled workers within the workforce and would also lead to a reduction in unemployment The findings here seem to imply that increase in human capital is driven by technology adoption and that unemployment falls as a consequence His finding differs significantly from ours in that we view the presence of human capital to be the driving force behind technology 9 adoption and that unemployment. .. technology adoption decisions of Italian manufacturing firms have revealed that the human capital level of a firm’s employees does play an important role towards the firm’s decision on whether to adopt a certain technology.3 2 Empirical evidence on the skill-biased nature of technological innovations can be found in Berman, Bound and Machin (1998), Machin and van Reenen (1998) and Morrison Paul and Siegel ... or reduction in the optimal level of employment amongst the firms Hence, we have this non-monotonic relationship between unemployment and technology adoption and also unemployment and human capital... presentation I conducted and the summer meeting of the North American Economics and Finance Association held at the 80th Western Economics Association conference I would also like to thank Mdm Foo and. .. graph consisting of the above demarcation curves in Figures and corresponding to situations and A brief explanation of the above observations will be given in the next sub-section The simulation