Economies of Conflict Private Sector Activity in Armed Conflict phần 4 pps

10 175 0
Economies of Conflict Private Sector Activity in Armed Conflict phần 4 pps

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Thông tin tài liệu

29 might be used for tracking purposes. Even the legitimate diamond industry has been shrouded in secrecy for generations. Half the world’s production or more is mined in countries with unstable or se- cretive governments, an almost foolproof recipe for expanded and deepened crim- inality. The value of rough diamond production was approximately US$7.5 billion in 2000. This was converted into $57.6 billion in diamond jewellery sales, of which the diamond content was approximately $13.7 billion. At least 20 per cent of the rough diamonds that are sold each year are, in one way or another, ‘illicit’, provid- ing a ready-made cover for the ‘conflict diamonds’ that are the subject of current international interest. Efforts to Curb the Problem The effort to halt conflict diamonds began in 1998, with a UN Security Council resolution on Angola. UN Security Council embargoes have been proven an effec- tive means of alerting importing countries to the problem of conflict diamonds: the current ban on Liberian diamonds has effectively stopped the laundering conflict and illicit diamonds via Liberia. It has not, however, stopped the flow of conflict diamonds from Sierra Leone. Sanctions on Angola have also not stopped the flow of diamonds. The diamond industry, NGOs, politicians, individual governments and the United Nations have become engaged in a large and concerted effort to deal with the issue. For diamond producing countries, many of them developing countries, the resource is crucial for economic development. For the diamond industry the challenge has been twofold. First, it has a moral obligation to make sure that its product is not tainted. Second, there has been a public relations problem, fanned by a growing number of churches and NGOs, which have threatened the reputation of the industry and its product. Diamond bourses around the world began developing codes of conduct in 2000. However, while several companies have been named in UN Security Council Reports, little has been done, in part because the absence of laws in importing countries outlaw- ing illicit or conflict diamonds means that any industry measures against diamen- taires could be actionable in a court of law. The Kimberly Process, which has sought to reach agreement on how to deal with conflict diamonds, has faced two unspoken obstacles. One is the potential cost and complexity of putting an effective system in place. The second has to do with sta- tistics and international inspection. For some countries diamonds are a ‘strategic mineral’ and as such could not be subject to international inspection. For NGO participants, however, self-regulation is a non-starter. By the end of 2001, after ten meetings, the Kimberly Process had yet to reach an agreement on the precise na- 30 ture of an international certification system. However, the months of negotiation had resulted in the some consensus on the ‘essential elements’ of a global certifica- tion system: • Provisions for a certificate of origin; • Provisions for internal controls in producing, trading and processing countries; • The creation of a common statistical data base on the trade in rough diamonds; • A statement on verification of national compliance. In addition, the World Diamond Council had spelled out its understanding of what an industry-managed “chain of warranties’ could look like, and had agreed to ex- ternal verification of such a system. Key outstanding issues at the time of writing included credible and effective monitoring and co-ordination, and the creation of a consistent and reliable data base on rough diamond production and trade. In addition, there were uncertainties about how and whether the system would con- form to WTO regulations. Conclusions, Lessons and Recommendations The study focuses on the connection between one primary export commodity and conflict. Diamonds did not cause the wars in Angola, Sierra Leone or the DRC. Diamonds entered the story, in all three cases, after the conflicts had begun. Griev- ance, however well or badly justified, was the motivator, and power was the goal. But diamonds became important as a source of financing which helped sustain the wars, and as a contributing factor to the intensity and scope of the fighting. There are no internationally agreed mechanisms to monitor the movement of this highly portable, accessible and valuable commodity. That is what the Kimberley Process has sought to develop. The Kimberley Process was initiated on the premise that only a comprehensive international certification system could be expected to have any serious impact on the phenomenon. Such a system would include better control in diamond mining countries, clarity in procedures for shipping diamonds, and controls in trading and processing countries. These controls would have to be backed by an independent international monitoring system and an international database on trade and pro- duction. An effective international certification system would also help to end the other illicit uses to which diamonds are put, including money laundering. To be effective, attempts to sever the link between rough diamonds and armed con- flict will require the following: 31 • The Kimberley Process should result in a strong mechanism for monitoring national compliance with minimum standards. Consumer confidence cannot be based on trust or on haphazard, minimal-review mechanisms. Credible mon- itoring for compliance should be viewed as compulsory and desirable by any country wanting to demonstrate that its industry is conflict free. • The Kimberley Process should come to grips with the issue of, and the need for, global production and trade statistics on rough diamonds. • The issue of WTO compatibility should be settled, and it should be settled soon. Neither the WTO, nor the GATT, condone or permit theft, war, human rights violations and the other abuses that stem from conflict diamonds. • The certification system should have more authority than can be derived from a voluntary arrangement or from a UN General Assembly resolution. The rele- vance of conflict diamonds for international peace and security are now well understood. Once a system has been finalized and debated by the General As- sembly, it should be forwarded to the UN Security Council for endorsement and global application. The experience of attempting to regulate conflict diamonds via the Kimberly Proc- ess suggests a number of key lessons for those working to regulate commodities which fuel armed conflict. On the supply side, the key element is the accessibility of diamonds – a func- tion of security failures, corruption, and state collapse. UN embargoes, new national legislation and industry efforts to stop conflict diamonds have had little impact, except to change the routing and covers under which conflict and illicit diamonds travel. On the demand side, industry secrecy, an absence of reliable trade and com- mercial data, and lack of governmental oversight are important factors in generat- ing and nourishing the opportunity that has sustained armed conflict. The fact that 20 per cent of the diamond industry is essentially crooked means that channels for the disposal of conflict diamonds had been established by illicit diamonds prior to the conflicts. Armed conflict and criminality converged, creating a more ready op- portunity for the emergence of conflict diamonds than might be the case in other commodities. Effective regulation must address the supply and demand sides of the prob- lem in tandem, addressing both the accessibility of rough diamonds and lack of trans- parency and accountability that enable them to be marketed. The strength of the Kimberley Process was that it was inclusive. NGOs and senior industry executives attended all meetings, and were encouraged to participate as fully as government representatives. There was no North-South divide: there were as many governments from developing countries as there were from the North. And there was a champion for the issue: the Government of South Africa. Shortcomings in 32 the Kimberley Process may become more obvious with time and distance. Certain- ly, as this paper was being completed in January 2002, the outcome of the process remained unclear. Multilateral processes to discuss the regulation of conflict goods should be as inclusive as possible, integrating the interests of industry, producing and consum- ing states and NGOs. 33 Fuelling Conflict Phillip Swanson This report examines how oil and gas industry activities in developing countries may contribute to or help perpetuate such conflicts. It emphasises the dynamics that can occur even when oil companies may be attempting to be good “corporate citizens”. Oil, States and Armed Conflict Some 70% of world oil production currently takes place outside OECD countries, and over 40% outside either the OECD or the Middle East. Investments by major oil companies can contribute significantly to the GDP and government revenues of oil-rich developing countries. However, large investments in natural resource exploitation and export also tend to give rise to a number of negative dynamics in the economy, government and society of the host country. Even if unintended, these dynamics can be very powerful, with consequences for social stability. Governments typically receive oil wealth via several different routes, including bonuses, royalty payments and income tax. In many cases, a combination of these payment methods is used. Together they can be used to obscure the direction and volume of oil revenue flows. Taxes and other payments related to resource extrac- tion and export by international oil companies often account for well over half of government revenues in oil-rich developing countries. Access to large and relative- ly easy petroleum revenues can give host governments a false sense of economic security that undermines the need for responsible economic and fiscal management. A large influx of easy oil revenue into a non-transparent system invites corrup- tion, in turn creating incentives to further limit transparency and accountability. Under such conditions, much oil wealth apparently has disappeared into off-budg- et accounts. Such “looting” of a country’s natural resources by its governing elites can provide the incentive and means to remain in power. Given a regime’s dependence upon oil revenues for its power, any threat to such revenues is likely to be met with significant resistance. In the short term, host gov- ernments will be concerned about any cut in the flow of oil, which effectively rep- resents a cut in government revenue. In the longer term, oil-dependent governments are concerned about the willingness of international oil companies to remain in the country. In some cases, the desire to maintain security for oil extraction may lead to the brutal treatment of those opposed to such operations. Whether or not the dynamics suggested are fully or even partly responsible for gov- ernment violence towards its population in a particular case, large oil revenues at 34 least provide the means for a government disposed toward violence to carry out such activities with relative impunity. A government’s willingness to resort to the use of force to protect its continued access to oil revenues is likely to be reinforced by an increasing estrangement between the government and its citizens. In fact, oil wealth tends to reduce a government’s dependence upon its citizens – corporate or indi- vidual – for tax revenues. When a government depends less on its own citizens for its revenue, it may become less accountable and may depend less upon them for its legitimacy. Oil company operations can create or exacerbate tensions between the central government and oil-producing regions, especially if a disproportionate share of benefits is seen to accrue to the former and a disproportionate share of costs to the latter. Tensions can also arise if the region feels that the central government’s share of oil revenue is “unfairly” large. Armed Conflict and the Company Most international oil companies have taken a “neutral” stance on the nature of host- country regimes, noting that companies should not get involved in politics. A number of NGOs have pointed out that large economic investments provide eco- nomic and political comfort to host countries, including de facto “recognition” of rogue regimes. Violence associated with oil company operations most often results from the use of force by government security forces against local protesters who opposed oil in- dustry operations. A number of NGOs, as well as missions by the UN and various oil company “home” country governments have reported numerous allegations of violent human rights abuses committed by government forces in and around oil producing regions in a number of countries. However, the secrecy surrounding se- curity arrangements that many international oil companies have concluded with host governments makes it difficult to assess company complicity in such activity. There are also documented cases of human rights abuses by oil company secu- rity forces or by the private forces hired by the oil companies. However, such cases usually are more clear-cut regarding oil company blame. Hopefully, they will also be the easiest abuses to avoid in future, since the oil companies presumably have more control over their own forces. A number of oil companies have been accused of providing logistical assistance to government military campaigns against political or ethnic oppositions. Common accusations are that companies have allowed militaries to use airstrips, helicopters, roads and other oil company infrastructure for offensive military purposes. In some cases host governments even appear to be using oil company security as a cover for waging military campaigns against political or ethnic enemies. Some of the most 35 serious accusations levelled against international oil companies have involved direct or indirect assistance in procuring weapons for host country governments, and in some cases even for rebel groups. For the oil companies, the direct effects of armed conflict are similar to those on other industries, e.g., threats to personnel, installations and supply lines, with the related costs of protecting each of these aspects of the business. However, once conflict erupts in a particular region, it usually will be significantly more expensive for oil companies to abandon their activities than it will be for most other inves- tors. This is due to the large and long-term nature of oil company investments, as well as the location-specific nature of natural resources. Oil companies may assume that their operations will be relatively shielded from civil conflict, in some cases by all parties to the conflict. Due to the large potential revenues that their oil extraction represents, it is not in the parties’ interest to per- mit armed conflict to devastate oil company investments. For a company already heavily invested, a cost-benefit analysis may indicate that the profit from oil extrac- tion could out-weigh the economic costs of doing business in a conflict zone. For some companies, armed conflict may be almost a cost of doing business. One of the most important negative effects of conflict on an oil company now takes place in the product and capital markets of the developed world. The threat to company reputation can have negative impacts on profits, share prices and the ability to raise capital. Oil companies with easily identifiable brand names at the service station pump are ultimately vulnerable to the sort of boycott campaigns that already have threatened companies in some other industries. Companies also may be increasingly susceptible to shareholder activism, especially by large institutional investors such as pension funds, many of which have adopted codes of conduct. Policy Options and Instruments Because oil companies often provide a large portion of host country budgets, they are among the few entities with potential leverage over such governments. This is why some observers see oil companies as potential agents for positive change. How- ever, oil companies face a possible loss of competitive advantage in the event that a host government decides to punish a company for taking a stand on human rights issues by rewarding one of its industry competitors. It is conceivable that a coali- tion of companies could form a “united front” for policy reform. However, in such a case these companies still could face non-cooperation from the growing number of technically proficient oil companies from developing countries that currently are not under the same Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) pressures from NGOs, customers and shareholders. 36 Transparency One of the main enabling factors for corruption and diversion of funds to off-budget military expenditures in host countries is lack of financial transparency. A key find- ing of this study is that a major area for policy focus should be on increasing the transparency of payments by oil companies to host governments. This would make it easier for host country citizenry to achieve a better understanding of the amount of money actually received from the development of their natural resources and to hold their governments accountable on this basis. Oil companies should be required to make a full public accounting of their payments to individual host countries. In many cases of alleged violence by government security troops, the foreign oil companies involved have either denied knowledge of abuses or insisted that the actions were not approved by the company. However, it is often impossible to as- sess company complicity, or to say whether governments have acted outside securi- ty agreements, since such agreements usually are secret. Companies should commit themselves to making public their security agreements with host countries. Given the impact of local violence on the security of oil company staff and op- erations, it would seem to be in companies’ best interests to pay more attention to such issues. It seems highly unlikely that companies are not already performing various risk assessments and assessments of the political or security situation. Com- panies should publicly commit themselves to performing systematic risk assessments based on those suggested in the Voluntary Principles on Security and Human Rights. Policy Instruments Companies would seem to have a significant market incentive to respond to or avoid NGO criticism, because negative publicity can damage their image with consum- ers and shareholders. A major drawback with NGO pressure, however, is that it does not seem to be applied evenly to all companies. NGOs have targeted those compa- nies they perceive to be most likely to respond to their criticism. The absences or ineffectiveness of pressure by NGOs is especially evident when it comes to the large, technically proficient non-OECD oil companies that are offering increasingly cred- ible competition to the majors in developing countries. Many of these currently face comparatively little pressure from their customers and shareholders to address CSR issues, thus giving NGOs little leverage to affect them commercially. Voluntary codes of conduct have become an important tool for companies to demonstrate support for particular social principles. However, experience from other industries indicates that codes developed by companies or industry associations in isolation often lack legitimacy vis-à-vis outside observers. Governments could play a role in bringing together industry actors and NGOs to work out codes that various 37 parties find acceptable (e.g. the negotiations to establish the “Voluntary Principles on Security and Human Rights”). Collective action by oil companies may also benefit from the “sponsorship” of a respected international body, such as the UN or the World Bank. Governments and the oil industry should recognise the value of multilateral institutions such as the United Nations or the World Bank in helping to manage collective action problems and reputational risk. Government and private sector partnerships with multilater- al institutions must reflect the international norms and law that these institutions embody. One approach to stimulate companies to provide more information or to im- plement other desired policies would be to make these provisions or policies a re- quirement for receiving certain services provided by or regulated by government. There has been discussion in some countries about expanding criteria for environ- mental conditionality, already in place in some OECD countries, to include strict- er requirements regarding transparency and accountability of payments. There has already been some work to co-ordinate action in this area among OECD govern- ments. As an issue for multilateral negotiation, the transparency of payments by international oil companies to foreign governments may lend itself to the existing negotiating framework, along the lines of the OECD anti-bribery convention. Sim- ilarly, stock market listings are in many cases regulated by states, giving governments scope for imposing conditions in this area. A major criticism of conditions on stock market listings is that they could inadvertently punish the financial centres that impose them. However, this collective action problem could be solved by co-ordi- nated action to introduce harmonised legislation in the world’s major financial centres. Governments should consider the development of mechanisms of positive conditionality in support of stricter requirements regarding transparency and ac- countability of payments. 38 Illicit Finance and Global Conflict Jonathan Winer In recent years, with every substantial national, regional, or global failure of gov- ernance, a financial scandal has been found in close attendance. Accompanying each financial scandal has been the systemic use of banking and financial secrecy to hide criminal activity. Over the past decade, this pattern has played out repeatedly in jurisdictions all over the world. Repeatedly, political conflict and major political destabilizing activity, including grand corruption, narcotics trafficking, arms smug- gling, and civil war have been facilitated and sustained by illicit finance networks embedded in the world’s licit financial services infrastructure. Structural Consequences of the Globalization of Money In Latin America, Mexico lost a quarter century of economic growth when the peso collapsed in 1994, amid evidence of drug money laundering and massive high-lev- el corruption. Similar financial catastrophes in which billions went missing attend- ed the collapse of governments in Ecuador, Peru, and most recently, in late 2001 and early 2002, Argentina 10 . Fraudulent pyramid schemes decapitalized nations in transition in Albania, Bulgaria, and Latvia. Kleptocrats stole and then sequestered the national wealth of the Congo/Zaire, Indonesia, Nigeria, and Russia using the same infrastructure of globalized financial services to hide their money. The use of the offshore sector to mask large financial losses facilitated the industrial-corporate- governmental corruption that has burdened the economies of Japan, South Korea and Taiwan. The same global financial infrastructure and major global banks han- dled political slush funds laundered for former German Chancellor Helmut Kohl and similar monies for illicit arms trafficking by the son of the late French Presi- dent Francois Mitterand 11 . Major international banks in Europe, the Americas and the Middle East processed the funds moved from the Persian Gulf by Al Qaeda and 10 See e.g. The Guardian, "In Argentina Today, the police raid foreign banks, January 18, 2002. "Police in Buenos Aires made dawn raids on foreign banks yesterday as part of an investigation into allega- tions that billions of dollars was smuggled out of Argentina in the days before its financial collapse last month. The investigation into reports that the regime of the former president, Fernando de la Rua, allowed $10bn to disappear offshore came as the slide into economic chaos continued with the resignation of the central bank governor, a sharp drop in the stock market and a further decline in the value of the peso." 11 See e.g. Newsweek, July, 2000, online international edition, "The Kohl Case: Oh, What a Tangled Web: The tale of how Germany's CDU nurtured a system of corrupt finance." . possible, integrating the interests of industry, producing and consum- ing states and NGOs. 33 Fuelling Conflict Phillip Swanson This report examines how oil and gas industry activities in developing. effects of armed conflict are similar to those on other industries, e.g., threats to personnel, installations and supply lines, with the related costs of protecting each of these aspects of the business source of financing which helped sustain the wars, and as a contributing factor to the intensity and scope of the fighting. There are no internationally agreed mechanisms to monitor the movement of

Ngày đăng: 14/08/2014, 16:20

Từ khóa liên quan

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

Tài liệu liên quan