1. Trang chủ
  2. » Tài Chính - Ngân Hàng

Encyclopedia of Finance Part 20 potx

9 326 0

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU

Thông tin cơ bản

Định dạng
Số trang 9
Dung lượng 214,05 KB

Nội dung

Chapter 37 MARKET MAKERS 1 ROBERT A. SCHWARTZ, City University of New York, USA LIN PENG, City University of New York, USA Abstract The primary focus of this entry is on market maker services, revenues, and costs. A market maker’s basic function is to service the public’s demand to trade with immediacy by continuously standing ready to buy shares from customers who wish to sell, and to sell shares to customers who wish to buy. Additionally, the market maker helps to stabil- ize prices and to facilitate a reasonably accurate price discovery. Further, a special type of market maker – a stock exchange specialist – fulfills the role of an auctioneer. The bid–ask spread is the classic source of market maker profits, while the costs of market maker operations include: order- processing, risk-bearing (the cost of carrying an unbalanced portfolio), and adverse selection (the cost of trading with a better-informed participant). The paper further considers the competitive environ- ment that market makers operate within, and con- cludes with the thought that institutionalization, the advent of electronic trading, deregulation, and globalization of the equity markets have led to major changes in market maker operations in the recent past, and will continue to do so in the coming years. Keywords: adverse selection; bid–ask spread; competitive environment; electronic trading; ex- change specialist; immediacy; market maker; order-processing; price stabilization; price discov- ery; risk-bearing Market makers play a central role in many equity markets by buying and selling shares to service the public’s demand to trade immediately (the classic service provided by a dealer). Market makers are also responsible for stabilizing prices (making a market ‘‘fair and orderly’’) and facilitat- ing price determination. Some market makers, such as stock exchange specialists, also perform the role of auctioneer. Demsetz (1968) was one of the first to analyze the supply of immediacy. Buyers and sellers arrive sporadically at the market, and it is not a simple matter for them to find each other in time. The market maker provides a solution by continuously standing ready to trade from his or her own inven- tory of shares. The service is not free, however. The dealer sells to buyers at higher ask prices, and buys from sellers at lower bid prices. The bid–ask spread is the market maker’s compensation (sometimes referred to as ‘‘the dealer’s turn’’). Market makers are n ot necessary for immedi- acy to be provided t o a market. Public traders can post limit orders w ith c ommission brokers acting as middlemen. However, immediacy is not the only marke tabil ity service provide d by a market maker. The liquidity provided by market makers also helps to stabilize prices. Most participants in the securities markets prefer prices that, all else equal, are less volatile. They care about this as investors because they are generally assumed to be risk- averse. They care about this as traders because they are averse to transaction price uncertainty. Market maker intervention helps to stabilize price fluctuations in the short run. The U.S. exchange specialist in particular has an ‘‘affirmative obliga- tion’’ to make a fair and orderly market. Market makers also facilitate the determination of accurate prices. First, their own quotes directly set market prices. Second, their quotes are signals that public traders react to in writing their orders; therefore, market makers indirectly affect market prices by influencing the public order flow. Third, exchange specialists establish market-clearing prices at the opening of the trading day and at the resumption of trading after halts caused by the advent of news. Price stabilization and price discovery are both consistent with the provision of immediacy. This is because ‘‘immediacy’’ means not only the ability to trade promptly, but also the ability to trade in reasonable amounts at prices that properly reflect current market conditions. (Smidt, 1971 empha- sizes the supply of liquidity in depth, namely the ability of investors to trade quickly and in size, at the market maker’s quotes.) Consequently, trans- actional immediacy, price stability and accurate price discovery are all attributes of markets that are ‘‘fair and orderly.’’ As auctioneers in an agency market, market makers also organize and oversee trading. Stock exchange specialists do so by maintaining the limit order books and by assuring that trading rules are not violated. On some exchanges (such as the Tokyo Stock Exchange), market makers act only in the clerical bookkeeping and regulatory over- sight capacities, and are not allowed to trade the stocks assigned to them. Thebid–askspreadsetbythemarketmaker reflects the following componen ts: order-p rocess - ing costs, risk premium or inventory costs, ad- verse selection costs, and profit (Stoll, 1989). The order-processing costs compensate market makers for their time and effort, cost of paper- work, etc. Risk bearing is central to the dealership function (Amihud and Mendelson, 1980; Ho and Stoll, 1981). The market maker trades to make a market rather than for his or her own investment motives. If buyers appear, a market ma ker must be willing to assume a short position; if sellers arrive, the market maker must be willing to as- sumealongposition.Asaresult,themarket maker generally acquires an unbalanced port- folio. The market maker is then subjec t to uncer- tainty c once rning the f uture price a nd the future transactions volume in the asse t. Not knowing when tr ans actions will be made, the market maker does not know for how long an unbalanced inventory position will h ave to be maintain ed. An unbalanced inven tory pos ition implies the exist- ence of diversifiable risk. Thus, the market maker requires a risk premium on the inventor y risk, which other i nvestors can eliminate by proper portfolio diversification (the expected return on a stock compensates all investors and market makers for accepting nondiversifiable risk). Market makers also prot ect themselves agai nst adverse selection. Public orders to purchase or to sell securities are motivated by either idiosyn- cratic liquidity reasons or informational change. The market maker typi cally does not know whether an order has ori ginated from an informed trader or from a liquidity trader. If a public trader rec eives news and transmits t he order before the mar ket maker has learned of the informational change, the public trader profits at the market maker’ s expense (Bag ehot, 1971; Copeland and Galai, 1983; Glosten and Milgrom, 1985). The market maker responds to the cost of ignorance by increasing the ask quote and lowering the bid so that the expected loss to the informed traders is compensated by the expected gain from the l iquidity traders. The market maker cannot a chieve total p rotection, however, by sufficiently widening the spread. Regardless of how much the offer is raised and=or or the bid is lowered, any informationally moti- vated trade would be at the market maker’s expense. And the defensive maneuver is not costless. The market maker profits from liquidity trades, and in the process of widening the spread to guard against MARKET MAKERS 635 informed traders, increases the cost of transacting and so loses an increasing number of liquidity traders. Yet, there must be investors who trade for noninformational reasons. Without the liquid- ity traders, the dealer market would collapse (Grossman and Stiglitz, 1980). The competitive environment of a market maker firm differs depending on whether it operates in an agency=auction environment or in a dealer market. In an agency=auction market, limit order traders and floor traders provide competition for the sin- gle market maker (stock exchange specialist). In contrast, a dealer market is competitive only if the order flow for a security is directed to more than one dealer firm. This competition for market- ability services fragments the informational con- tent of the order flow, however. In other words, each dealer firm knows what buy and sell orders it receives, but does not observe the flow of orders to competing dealer firms. However, in a screen- based system, each dealer firm does see the quotes posted by others. In addition, information is trans- ferred by transaction price reporting and via inter- dealer trading. The online reporting of large transactions, how- ever, can signal information about a dealer’s in- ventory position to its competitors. And, when the order flow is dominated by institutional investors, as on the London Stock Exchange, other problems can arise (see Neuberger and Schwartz, 1990). These include fair-weather market making (taking the privileges but failing to meet the obligations of market making), preferencing (the diversion of order flow to a market maker firm that is not necessarily posting the best quotes, but that has guaranteed best-price execution nonetheless), handling a lumpy order flow (few trades but of large size), and coping with one-way markets (buyers only or sellers only). All told, market mak- ing is a complex, multifaceted operation. Institutionalization, the advent of electronic trading, deregulation, and globalization of the equity markets are having a profound impact on securities trading and price determination. These forces have led to major changes in market maker operations in the recent past, and will continue to do so in the coming years. NOTE 1. This material is modified from an equivalent entry from The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, by Newman, Peter. Reprinted with permis- sion of Palgrave Macmillan. Copyright ß Newman, Peter. REFERENCES Amihud, Y., Ho, T., and Schwartz, R.A. (eds.) (1985). Market Making and the Changing Structure of the Securities Industry. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. Amihud, Y. and Mendelson, H. (1980). ‘‘Dealership market: market making with inventory.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 8: 31–53. Bagehot, W. (1971). ‘‘The only game in town.’’ Finan- cial Analysts Journal, 27: 12–14, 22. Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R.A., and Whitcomb, D. (1979). ‘‘Market makers and the market spread: a review of recent literature.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14: 813–835. Copeland, T. and Galai, D. (1983). ‘‘Information effects on the bid-ask spread.’’ Journal of Finance, 38: 1457– 1469. Demsetz, H. (1968). ‘‘The cost of transacting.’’ Quar- terly Journal of Economics, 82: 33–53. Garman, M . (1976). ‘‘Market microstructure.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 257–275. Glosten, L. and Milgrom, P. (1985). ‘‘Bid, ask, and transaction prices in a specialist market with hetero- geneously informed traders.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 14: 71–100. Grossman, S.J. and Stiglitz, J. (1980). ‘‘On the impos- sibility of informationally efficient markets.’’ Ameri- can Economic Review, 70: 393–408. Ho, T. and Stoll, H. (1981). ‘‘Optimal dealer pricing under transaction and return uncertainty.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 9: 47–73. Ho, T. and Stoll, H. (1983). ‘‘The dynamics of dealer markets under competition.’’ Journal of Finance, 38: 1053–1074. Neuberger, A. a nd Schwartz, R.A. ( 1990). ‘‘Current devel- opments in the London equity market.’’ Finanzmarkt und Portfolio Management, 3: 281–301. 636 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE O’Hara, M. and Oldfield, G.S. (1986). ‘‘The microeco- nomics of market making.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 21: 361–376. Schwartz, R.A. and Francioni, R. (2004). Equity Markets in Action: The Fundamentals of Market Structure and Trading. New York: John Wiley. Smidt, S. (1971). ‘‘Which road to an efficient stock market: free competition or regulated monopoly?’’ Financial Analysts Journal, 27: 18–20, 64–69. Stoll, H. (1985). ‘‘Alternate views of market making,’’ in Amihud, Ho and Schwartz (eds.) Market Making and the Changing Structure of the Securities Industry. Lexington Books, pp.67–92. Stoll, H. (1989). ‘‘Inferring the components of the bid- ask spread: theory and empirical tests.’’ Journal of Finance, 44: 115–134. Tinic, S.M. and West, R. (1972). ‘‘Competition and the pricing of dealer services in the over-the-counter stock market.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 7: 1707–1727. MARKET MAKERS 637 Chapter 38 STRUCTURE OF SECURITIES MARKETS 1 ROBERT A. SCHWARTZ, City University of New York, USA LIN PENG, City University of New York, USA Abstract The entry reviews essential elements of market structure – the systems, procedures, and protocols that determine how orders are handled, translated into trades, and transaction prices determined. There are various contrasting alternatives, such as order- driven and quote-driven markets; consolidated vs fragmented markets; human intervention vs elec- tronic trading; and continuous markets vs periodic call auctions. A major objective of market design noted in the discussion is to enhance the accuracy with which prices are discovered in a dynamic, un- certain environment. Lastly, the entry points out that market structures are rapidly changing, and that much remains to be learned about how best to structure a technologically sophisticated, hybrid market that efficiently services the varied needs of diverse participants. Keywords: call auctions; consolidated markets; continuous markets; electronic trading; fragmen- ted markets; hybrid market; market structure; order-driven markets; price discovery; quote- driven markets The structure of a securities market refers to the systems, procedures, and protocols that determine how orders are handled, translated into trades, and transaction prices determined. To date, theoretical security valuation models have generally not con- sidered the effect of a market’s structure on asset prices. Formulations such as the Capital Asset Pricing Model and the Arbitrage Pricing Theory, for example, address the risk and return dimen- sions of a security, but ignore considerations such as liquidity, trading costs, information costs, and transaction uncertainty. When these realities are taken into account, it is apparent that market structure matters, that it does affect the price and size of trades. Market structures differ significantly among major international equity market centers (see Schwartz and Francioni, 2004). The New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) and other U.S. stock ex- changes are agency=auction markets where the market maker (specialist) acts as both dealer and broker’s broker. Examples of a dealer market in- clude the Nasdaq market in the United States and the London Stock Exchange (LSE) before they introduced their electronic order-driven trading systems (Supermontage for Nasdaq and SETS for the LSE). The Tokyo Stock Exchange (TSE) is an agency=auction market where the market maker (saitori) handles the orders but does not take a dealership position. Markets also differ in the way in which orders are consolidated or fragmen- ted, in the way in which information is dissemin- ated, and in the degree to which trading is computerized. Whether investors trade through an intermedi- ary, as in a dealer market, or directly with each other, as in an agency=auction market, is one of the most important distinctions in market struc- ture. In a dealer market, the market maker initiates trades by posting bid and ask quotations that are publicly disseminated. The bid is the price at which public traders can sell to a dealer, and the ask is the price at which they can buy from a dealer. The bid– ask spread is the dealer’s compensation for provid- ing marketability services. To achieve a trade in a dealer market, a customer (usually via a broker) contacts a dealer by telephone or electronically and accepts his or her quotation. In an agency=auction market, public partici- pants trade with each other, and floor profes- sionals in an agency market such as the NYSE act in a brokerage (agency) capacity. When trading is active in a stock, floor traders gather in a ‘‘crowd,’’ and trading truly takes place in an auc- tion environment. In the U.S. exchanges, orders are consolidated at the posts of specialists, who are market professionals who function as both principals and as agents. Specialists have an af- firmative obligation to buy and to sell shares so as to make ‘‘a fair and orderly market’’ when counterpart orders do not provide sufficient liquid- ity. They also have a negative obligation: when a public order and a specialist’s quote are at the same price, the specialist must step aside and let the public order execute first. Two types of orders are commonly used in an agency=auction market: limit orders and market orders. A limit order states the maximum price at which a public investor is willing to buy, or the minimum price at which the public investor is will- ing to sell, a specified number of shares. A market order is unpriced; it states the number of shares the investor wishes to trade ‘‘at market,’’ namely the price prevailing when the order is received by the market center. To execute a market order, limit orders must exist; for limit orders to exist, there must be a facility for maintaining public orders in a file (limit order book). This file charac- terizes agency=auction exchanges. Handa and Schwartz (1996) have examined the costs and re- turns to placing limit orders. Trades may also be negotiated if they are diffi- cult to handle because of their size. In an agen- cy=auction environment such as the NYSE, a buyer or seller may give a not held (NH) order to a floor trader who uses his or her discretion to negotiate with other floor traders or to expose the order to the limit order book. The floor trader is ‘‘not held to the price’’ if the order executes at a price inferior to that which existed at the time of its arrival. Large orders are also negotiated in the ‘‘upstairs market,’’ a network of trading desks of securities dealers and institutional investors who bring buyers and sellers together at mutually ac- ceptable prices. Trades may also be negotiated with a dealer and=or electronically through a facility such as Liquidnet or Pipeline. Institu- tional investors commonly negotiate with the mar- ket makers to obtain larger sizes than the market makers are quoting and=or prices that are within the bid–ask spread. Large orders are also com- monly broken up (sliced and diced) and brought to the market in smaller tranches for execution over an extended period of time. A major function of a market center is to find the prices at which shares are traded. This process is known as ‘‘price discovery.’’ The accuracy of price discovery depends on the systems used for handling orders, disseminating information, and making trades. If an issue is traded in more than one market center, intermarket linkages including information systems and arbitrage operations must be implemented to ensure both adequate price pro- tection for investors and price consistency across markets. Intermarket linkages also connect equity markets and derivative product markets (for ex- ample, the futures and options markets for stock indices in Chicago and the cash market for shares in New York). Another feature of market structure is the means by which information concerning current market conditions (floor information) is trans- ferred among participants. The informational sig- nal transmitted by a quote differs significantly from that transmitted by a transaction price. A quote reflects an individual’s willingness to trade; it is firm only up to its stated size and may be improved on in terms of price and=or quantity. Quotes may also reflect trading strategy and STRUCTURE OF SECURITIES MARKETS 639 gaming by market participants. A transaction price has actually been accepted by both counterparties to a trade, but relates to the past and does not necessarily represent the price at which one can trade in the present. Nonetheless, latest transaction prices do reflect current market conditions when transactions occur frequently. For this reason, transaction price reporting has been introduced in both the U.S. and London dealer markets (see Seguin, 1991). The extent to which orders are fragmented or consolidated in trading also defines a market’s structure (see Cohen et al., 1986). A competitive dealer market is naturally fragmented in the sense that orders are routed to one of several dealer firms. This may be desirable because of the com- petition for marketability services that fragmenta- tion implies. Most apparent is that bid–ask spreads are tightened in a competitive dealer environment compared to a monopoly dealer environment (see Ho and Stoll, 1983). However, given the frag- mented nature of a dealer market, dealers may not be as closely regulated as the specialists in the agency=auction market. This may create incentives for dealers to collude (see Christie and Schultz, 1994a,b). In 1996, the justice department settled with the Nasdaq dealers on accusations of spread collusion. Another problem of the dealer market is that fragmenting the order flow across different dealer firms can obscure information and impair the accu- racy of price determination (see Neuberger and Schwartz, 1990). However, in a screen-based system such as the US Nasdaq market, each dealer firm does see the quotes posted by the others. A dealer market with fragmented orders may also reduce the oppor- tunity for the interaction of all buying and selling interest in that security and thus reduce price com- petition. In 1997, the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission enacted the Order-Handling Rules (OHRs), which required that public limit orders be exposed in the national best bid and offer (NBBO). The rules set in motion the transition of the Nasdaq market from a predominantly quote-driven, dealer market towards an order-driven, agency market. Order flow in an agency=auction environment is by its nature more consolidated than in a com- petitive dealer market. Consolidation is desirable because it allows orders to be matched against each other with a minimum of broker–dealer inter- vention. Furthermore, the consolidation of orders facilitates the enforcement of order exposure and trading priority rules. The primary priority rule is price; highest-priced bids and lowest-priced asks have precedence. A secondary priority rule speci- fies the sequence in which orders at the same price execute; usually, the first order entered at the price is the first to execute (time priority). However, too much consolidation may lead to monopoly power for a single market center, which may lead it to lose its incentive to reduce transaction costs and to innovate. An agency=auction market is fragmented when shares are listed on more than one exchange, traded in-house by a brokerage firm, on an Alter- native Trading System (ATS) and=or on an Elec- tronic Communications Network (ECN) . This fragmentation may be desirable if it truly repre- sents competition between market centers. It is not desirable if one market center free-rides on the prices discovered by another market center. For example, a satellite market may guarantee trades at the best price quoted in a major market center and charge lower commissions for the service. Order consolidation facilitates the consolidation and transference of floor information. For ex- ample, NYSE specialists are in a unique position from which to observe the order flow and to set prices that are reasonable given the current de- mand for shares. But, like the saitori in Tokyo, specialists are not permitted to receive orders dir- ectly from customers, which restricts their access to information. In contrast, both dealers can receive orders directly from customers, including institu- tional traders. This contact enables them to obtain further information about market conditions. In addition to being spatially (geographically) consolidated, orders can be consolidated temporally (over time). Orders are temporally consolidated when they are bunched together in call auction 640 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE trading. In continuous trading, orders are executed whenever they cross during trading hours and, in a continuous market, trades are generally bilateral. In contrast, in call auction trading, orders are stored for simultaneous execution in multilateral trades at predetermined times when the market is ‘‘called.’’ Call market trading has certain advantages (see Schwartz and Francioni, 2004). In particular, de- pendence on the intermediation of dealers and brokers is lessened and trading costs are reduced. Since everyone trades at the same price, at the same time and under the same conditions, call market trading is fairer, and the procedure can produce prices that are more accurate and less volatile. But, traditional call market trading has had its limitations. Accessibility to the market was restricted and the dissemination of floor infor- mation poor in the old call markets of Europe. These limitations can be overcome with the use of computer technology. Pagano and Schwartz (2003) have found that the introduction of electronic call auctions at market closings on the Paris Bourse (now Euronext Paris) reduced transaction costs and improved price discovery. One of the more striking changes in market struc- ture that occurred as the twentieth century drew to a close was the advent of electronic trading. At its inception, electronic systems tended to mimic existing systems; now they are more commonly developing their own distinctive functionality. The first electronic exchange, the Computer Assisted Trading System (CATS), was introduced by the Toronto Stock Exchange in 1977. CATS is based on the principle of continuous trading in an agen- cy=auction environment. The success of CATS has led to the implementation of similar systems in Tokyo (1982), Paris (1986), and elsewhere. Small order execution systems were also introduced in the U.S. and London dealer markets in the 1980s. Now most national equity markets around the globe provide floorless, electronic trading plat- forms. The major exceptions, the New York Stock Exchange in the U.S., is in the process of converting to a hybrid structure that integrates an electronic platform (Directþ) with its trading floor. Electronic technology has strong advantages: it gives participants direct access to markets and control over their orders regardless of geographic location; it provides direct access to information concerning current market conditions; it provides anonymity; it enables the investors to trade with- out a broker and thus reduce transaction costs; and, as systems become increasingly sophisticated, the computational power of the computer facili- tates the handling of institutional-sized orders and the negotiation of trades. Investors in the 1990s have witnessed a proliferation of fourth-market organizations. Electronic facilities such as Instinet and Archipelago allow members to post orders and to match that of other traders in the system. Crossing systems such as Posit and Instinet’s Crossing Network allow investors to trade portfo- lios directly without a bid–ask spread. Liquidnet and Pipeline allow participants to find each other on their screen and negotiate their trades electronically. Electronic technology solves the major problems associated with call market trading: restricted accessibility to a market and inadequate dissem- ination of floor information (see Pagano and Schwartz, 2003). Reciprocally, a call market en- vironment may be more suitable than the continu- ous market for the use of electronic technology. In particular, the submission and handling of in- stitutional-sized orders can be accommodated in an electronic call (see Schwartz and Francioni, 2004). Because of strong vested interests, technological inertia, and the ability of an established market center to retain order flow, the superiority of a new system may not ensure its acceptance. Market structure has evolved slowly in the United States since trading moved from coffee houses and curbs into exchanges (the American Stock Exchange did not move indoors until 1921). The pace of change accelerated in the mid-1970s with the passage of the U.S. Securities Acts Amendments of 1975, which precluded fixed commissions and mandated the development of a national market system. London’s Big Bang in 1986 also precluded fixed STRUCTURE OF SECURITIES MARKETS 641 commissions, broadened competition between dealers and brokers, and further spurred the glob- alization of trading. More recently, the NYSE and Nasdaq have completed a conversion from frac- tional to decimal prices under the pressure of the SEC. Technological developments, inter-market competition, and regulation will no doubt continue to reshape securities markets around the world. However, achieving meaningful change in market structure is not an easy task; much remains to be learned about how best to structure a technologic- ally sophisticated, hybrid market that efficiently services the varied needs of diverse participants. NOTE 1. This material is modified from an equivalent entry from: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, by Peter Newman. Reprinted with permis- sion of Palgrave Macmillan. Copyright S Newman, Peter. REFERENCES Amihud, Y., Ho, T. and Schwartz, R.A. (eds.) (1985). Market Making and the Changing Structure of the Se- curities Industry. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R.A., and Whitcomb, D. (1979). ‘‘Market makers and the market spread: a review of recent literature.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Ana1ysis, 14: 813–835. Cohen, K., Maier, S., Schwartz, R.A., and Whitcomb, D. (1986). The Microstructure of Securities Markets. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall. Christie, W.G. and Schultz, P.H. (1994a). ‘‘Why do NASDAQ market makers avoid odd-eighth quotes?’’ Journal of Finance, 49: 1813–1840. Christie, W.G., Harris, J., and Schultz, P.H. (1994b). ‘‘Why did NASDAQ market makers stop avoiding odd-eighth quotes?’’ Journal of Finance, 49: 1841– 1860. Handa, P. and Schwartz, R.A. (1996).‘‘Limit order trading.’’ Journal of Finance, 51: 1835–1861. Ho, T. and Stoll, H. (1983). ‘‘The dynamics of dealer markets under competition.’’ Journal of Finance, 38: 1053–1074. Neuberger, A. and Schwartz, R.A. (1990). ‘‘Current developments in the London equity market.’’ Finanz- markt und Portfolio Management, 3: 281–301. Pagano, M. and Schwartz, R.A. (2003). ‘‘A closing call’s impact on market quality at Euronext Paris.’’ Journal of Financial Economics, 68: 439–484. Schwartz, R.A. and Francioni, R. (2004). Equity Mar- kets in Action: The Fundamentals of Market Structure and Trading. New Jersey: John Wiley. Seguin, P. (1991). ‘‘Transactions reporting, liquidity and volatility: an empirical investigation of national market system listing.’’ Paper given at Western Finance Association Meetings, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, June. US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) (2000). NYSE Rulemaking: Notice of filing of proposed rule change to rescind exchange rule 390; Commission request for comment on issues related to market fragmentation. Release No. SR-NYSE-99–48. 642 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE . special type of market maker – a stock exchange specialist – fulfills the role of an auctioneer. The bid–ask spread is the classic source of market maker profits, while the costs of market maker. Finanzmarkt und Portfolio Management, 3: 281–301. 636 ENCYCLOPEDIA OF FINANCE O’Hara, M. and Oldfield, G.S. (1986). ‘‘The microeco- nomics of market making.’’ Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,. needs of diverse participants. NOTE 1. This material is modified from an equivalent entry from: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, by Peter Newman. Reprinted with permis- sion of

Ngày đăng: 06/07/2014, 08:20