Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 56 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
56
Dung lượng
266,58 KB
Nội dung
Bank Risk-Taking,Securitization,Supervision,andLowInterestRates:
Evidence fromLendingStandards
Angela Maddaloni and José-Luis Peydró
*
July 2009
Abstract
We analyze the root causes of the current crisis (Allen, 2009; Diamond and Rajan,
2009) by studying the determinants of banklendingstandards in the Euro Area. We
use the answers from the confidential BankLending Survey where national central
banks request banks quarterly information on their lending standards. We find robust
evidence that low short-term interest rates soften standards for both businesses and
households and – by exploiting cross-country variation of Taylor-rule implied rates –
we find that rates too low for too long soften standards even further. The softening is
over and above an improvement of the borrower’s collateral risk and outlook, thus
suggesting higher loan risk-taking by banks. In addition, we find that weaker banking
supervision standardsand higher securitization activity amplify the softening of
lending standards due to low short-term rates, even when we instrument securitization.
Finally, low short-term rates have a stronger impact than long-term rates on the
softening of standards. These results help shed light on the origins of the current crisis
and have important policy implications.
*
The authors are at the European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, D 60311 Frankfurt am Main,
Germany. Contact information: angela.maddaloni@ecb.europa.eu, and jose.peydro@gmail.com / jose-
luis.peydro-alcalde@ecb.europa.eu. We thank Lieven Baert and Francesca Fabbri for excellent research
assistance. Any views expressed are only those of the authors and should not be attributed to the
European Central Bank or the Eurosystem.
2
“One (error) was that monetary policy around the world was too loose too long. And that created this
just huge boom in asset prices, money chasing risk. People trying to get a higher return. That was just
overwhelmingly powerful We all bear a responsibility for that” … “The supervisory system was just
way behind the curve. You had huge pockets of risk built up outside the regulatory framework and not
enough effort to try to contain that. But even in the core of the system, banks got to be too big and
overleveraged. Now again, here’s an important contrast. Banks in the United States, even with
investment banks now banks, bank assets are about one times GDP of the United States. In many other
mature countries - in Europe, for example – they’re a multiple of that. So again, around the world,
banks got to just be too big, took on too much risk relative to the size of their economies.”
Timothy Geithner, United States Secretary of the Treasury, Charlie Rose’s PBS, May 2009
“I believe the causes cannot be found in any one market, such as the US. Nor are they limited to a
particular business, such as subprime mortgages. These triggered the crisis, but they did not cause it.
The causes are the same as in any previous financial crisis: excesses and losing the plot in an
extraordinarily favourable environment. Indeed, some fundamental realities of banking were forgotten:
cycles exist; lending cannot grow indefinitely; liquidity is not always abundant and cheap; financial
innovation involves risk that cannot be ignored”
Emilio Botín, Chairman of Bank Santander, Financial Times, October 2008
I. Introduction
The current financial crisis has had a dramatic impact on the banking sector of
most developed countries, it has severely impaired the functioning of interbank
markets, and it has triggered an economic crisis in these same countries.
What are the root causes of this crisis? Several commentators and academics
have suggested that the global financial crisis was originated by an excessive
softening of lending standards. Three key elements were mentioned as drivers: too
low levels of interest rates, high securitisation activity, and weak bank regulation
supervision standards.
2
Therefore, the crisis that started in the subprime mortgage
market in the US may have been the manifestation of deep rooted problems, which
were not peculiar to one financial instrument and/or country but were present
globally, albeit to different degrees (Allen, 2009, and Diamond and Rajan, 2009).
3
Moreover, these root causes may have also been interrelated and mutually amplifying
in affecting the risk-taking of financial institutions (Rajan, 2005). In this paper, we
empirically test these hypotheses.
2
See for example Allen (2009), Brunnemeier (2009), Calomiris (2008), Taylor (2007 and 2008), Engel
(2009), and numerous articles in The Financial Times, The Wall Street Journal, and The Economist.
Nominal rates were the lowest in almost four decades and below Taylor rates in many countries while
real rates were negative (Taylor, 2008; and Ahrend, Cournède and Price, 2008).
3
Allen (2009), Rajan (2009) and Diamond and Rajan (2009) distinguish between proximate versus
root causes of the current crisis.
3
Low interest rates, weaker bank regulation supervision standardsand high
securitization activity may imply higher loan risk-taking by banks. Moral hazard
problems are severe in the banking industry due to e.g. deposit insurance, potential
bail-outs and very high levels of leverage; hence, high levels of liquidity increase
incentives for bank risk-taking (Allen and Gale, 2007).
4
Without bank agency
problems, excess of liquidity would be given back to shareholders or central banks,
but – due to bank moral hazard problems – banks may over-lend the extra-liquidity in
bad projects. Allen (2009) and Allen and Gale (2007 and 2004) connect too high
levels of liquidity with too low levels of short-term interest rates.
5
In fact, the level of
overnight rates is a key driver of liquidity for banks since banks increase their balance
sheets (leverage) when financing conditions through short-term debt are more
favourable (Shin, 2009; Adrian and Shin, 2009; and Brunnermeier et al., 2009).
Therefore, low short-term interest rates increase bank risk-taking through this channel
and, hence, stronger banking supervision standards – via reducing bank agency
problems – should reduce the higher risk-taking associated to low rates.
6
Finally, low
levels of both short and long-term rates may induce a search for yield from financial
intermediaries due to their moral hazard problems. Securitization of loans result in
assets yielding attractive returns for investors, but the social cost may be lower
screening and monitoring of securitized loans. Hence, the impact of low rates on the
softening on standards is stronger with higher securitization activity (Rajan, 2005).
4
For the link between liquidity and loan risk-taking by banks, see Chuck Prince, Citigroup Chairman,
when describing why his bank continued financing leveraged buyouts despite mounting risks, said:
“When the music stops, in terms of liquidity, things will be complicated. But, as long as the music is
playing, you’ve got to get up and dance. We’re still dancing.” (Financial Times, July 9, 2007).
5
Due to bank agency problems, short-term rates soften lendingstandards either by abating adverse
selection problems in credit markets thereby increasing bank competition (Dell’Ariccia and Marques,
2007), or by reducing the threat of deposit withdrawals (Diamond and Rajan, 2006).
6
There are other channels by which low levels of interest rates affect bank (loan) risk-taking. First,
lower risk-less rates increase the attractiveness of risky assets in a mean-variance portfolio framework.
Second, in habit formation models agents become more risk-averse during economic slowdowns
because their consumption decreases relative to their status-quo (Campbell and Cochrane, 1999), thus a
tightening in monetary policy by depressing real activity may increase investors’ risk aversion. Third,
low rates may decrease banks’ intermediation margins (profits), thus reducing banks’ charter value,
increasing in turn incentives for risk-taking (Keeley, 1990). Fourth, there could also be monetary
illusion with low levels of short-term rates which would make banks to desire riskier products to
increase returns (Shiller, 1997; and Akerlof and Shiller 2009). Fifth, an environment in which central
banks focus only on consumer goods price stability may make monetary policy rates too low, fostering
in turn asset price and credit bubbles (Borio 2003; Borio and Lowe, 2002). For Acharya and
Richardson (2009) the fundamental cause of the crisis was the credit boom and the housing bubble.
These were largely developed by too low levels of monetary policy rates (Taylor, 2007).
4
We empirically analyze the following questions: Do low levels of both short and
long-term interest rates soften banklending standards? Are the effects stronger with
higher securitization activity or weaker banking supervision standards? And, do
results differ across type of loans, i.e. across business, house purchase, and
households’ consumption loans?
There are four major challenges to identify the previous questions. First,
monetary policy rates are endogenous to the (local) economic conditions. Second,
banking supervision standards may be endogenous to monetary policy especially in
cases when the central bank is responsible for both. Third, securitization activity is
endogenous to monetary (bank liquidity) conditions, since these affect the ability of
banks to grant loans. Fourth, it is very difficult to obtain data on the pool of potential
borrowers approaching a bank, to know their quality, and then to know whether, why
and how banks change their lendingstandards to customers.
Our identification strategy relies upon the data we use, the Euro Area Bank
Lending Survey, which allows us to tackle the four previous identification
challenges.
7
First, we use data from the Euro Area countries, where monetary policy
rates are identical. However, there are significant cross-country differences in terms of
GDP growth and inflation, implying in turn significant exogenous cross-sectional
variation of Taylor-rule implied rates (Taylor, 2008). Second, banking supervision
standards in the Euro Area are responsibility of the national supervisory authorities
(often national central banks), whereas monetary policy is decided by the Governing
Council of the Eurosytem.
8
Third, there is significant cross-sectional variation in
securitization activity partly stemming from cross-country differences in the
regulation of the market for securitization. Fourth, we have access to the confidential
Bank Lending Survey database of the Eurosystem. National central banks request
quarterly information on the lendingstandards they apply to customers and on the
loan demand they receive. The rich information allows us to analyze whether banks
7 Banks are not only the key financial intermediaries that reduce the information problems which are
crucial for the real effects of monetary policy through credit markets (Bernanke and Gertler, 1995), but
banks are also the main providers of credit in most economies and, in particular, in the Euro Area (see
for example Hartmann, Maddaloni, Manganelli, 2003, and Allen, Chui and Maddaloni, 2004).
8 International guidelines like Basel are also very important for bank regulation, but there is rule for
discretion in supervision standards, in particular for banking capital see Laeven and Levine (2009) and
Barth, Caprio and Levine (2006).
5
change their lending standards, to whom (average or riskier borrowers), how (loan
spreads, size, collateral, maturity or covenants), and why (due to changes in borrower
risk, or in bank balance-sheet strength, or in bank competition).
The evidence we provide suggests that banks take on higher risk when overnight
rates are lower. This conclusion arises from the combination of the following robust
results: First, a softening of lendingstandards is associated to low overnight rates. The
association is highest for business loans.
9
Second, higher GDP growth also implies a
softening of standards, i.e. standards are pro-cyclical. Our findings are economically
relevant: taking into consideration the standard deviation of overnight rates and GDP
growth, the impact of a change in the overnight rate doubles a change in GDP growth
both for business and households’ consumption loans, but it is similar for loans for
house purchase. Third, by exploiting cross-country variation of Taylor-rule implied
rates, we find – especially for loans for house purchase – that a softening of lending
standards due to short-term rates too low for too long (measured as the number of
periods when short-term rates are lower than Taylor-rule implied rates). Fourth, low
overnight rates have a stronger impact than low long-term rates on the softening of
standards.
10
Fifth, all the lendingstandards are softened when short-term rates are low,
both for average and for riskier borrowers. The softening implies lower loan margins,
lower collateral requirements, longer loan maturity, less covenants and larger loan
size. Finally, and more importantly, there is a softening of standards even when
changes in standards are not associated to improvements in borrowers’ credit-
9
Jiménez, Ongena, Peydró and Saurina (2009) and Ioannidou, Ongena and Peydró (2009) are the first
to investigate the impact of short-term (monetary policy) rates on loan risk-taking by banks. They use
comprehensive credit registers for business loans from Spain and Bolivia respectively. They find that
low levels of overnight rates increase loan risk-taking by banks. Our results complement these papers
by analyzing not only business loans but also loans for house purchase and consumption, and also by
analyzing all Euro Area countries. In addition, we do not have the comprehensive credit register but we
have the potential pool of borrowers and we know whether, how and why banks change their lending
standards. For indirect evidence on short-term rates andrisk-taking, see Bernanke and Kuttner (2005),
Rigobon and Sack (2004), Manganelli and Wolswijk (2007), Axelson, Jenkinson, Strömberg and
Weisbach (2007), Den Haan, Sumner, and Yamashiro (2007), and Calomiris and Pornrojnangkool
(2006).
10
Due to the saving glut and the existence of current account “imbalances”, savers were looking for
investment opportunities abroad. However, they were seeking short-term assets (Gross, 2009) and, in
fact, Brender and Pisani (2009) reports that about one third of all foreign exchange reserves are in the
form of bank deposits. Little is known about the maturity composition of the remainder, most of which
is invested in interest-bearing securities. The scarce available data on the composition of USD foreign
exchange reserves that can be gleaned from the US Treasury International Capital data suggests that
over half of foreign official holdings of US securities had a maturity of less than three years (see Gross,
2009).
6
worthiness, but due to improvements in bank balance-sheet constraints (higher bank
liquidity or capital, or better bank access to market finance) and also due to higher
banking competition, especially from non-banks and market finance. Hence, the
softening of standards is over and above an improvement of the borrower’s collateral
risk/ value and outlook, thus suggesting higher loan risk-taking by banks when short-
term rates are low.
11
Using time-varying measures of banking supervision standards for bank capital,
we find that the impact of low short-term rates on the softening of lendingstandards
over and above improvements in borrower’s credit-worthiness is larger when
supervision standards are weaker, both for loans for house purchase and for
consumption. However, the level effect of supervision standards is not as significant
as the direct effect of rates on lending standards. The lack of strong significance of the
direct effect of banking supervision on lendingstandards may be consistent with the
arguments made by Allen (2009) and Rajan (2009) concerning the need for “good”
supervision regulation, which does not necessarily mean more stringent supervision.
12
Finally, in contrast with short-term rates, we don’t find that the impact of low long-
term rates on the softening of standards depends on banking supervision standards.
Finally, we analyze securitization activity.
13
We find that the impact of low short-
term rates on the softening of standards for all type of loans is larger when
securitization activity is higher. However, if we consider the tightening of standards
only related to bank balance-sheet’s constraints, securitization activity in conjunction
with overnight rates has a significant impact only for loans for house purchase and
consumer credit. Moreover, we find significant effects for short-term rates but not for
long-term rates. Finally, instrumenting securitization activity by the regulation of the
market for securitization in each country does not significantly modify the results,
where the instrument has a t-stat higher than 8 in the first-stage regression and, hence,
11
That is, the effect of low rates on the softening of standards is over and above the firm balance sheet
channel of monetary policy (Bernanke and Gertler, 1995). Because of imperfect information,
incomplete contracts and imperfect bank competition, expansive monetary policy increases banks’ loan
supply (Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist, 1996; Bernanke, 2007; Kashyap and Stein, 2000; Diamond
and Rajan, 2006; Stiglitz, 2001; and Stiglitz and Greenwald, 2003).
12
See also Barth, Caprio and Levine (2006).
13
For evidence of excessive softening of lendingstandards due to securitization, see Keys et al. (2008),
Mian and Sufi (2009), and Dell'Ariccia, Laeven and Igan (2008).
7
it does not suffer from weak instrument concerns (Staiger and Stock, 1997). In
consequence, the previous set of results suggests higher loan risk-taking by banks
when securitization activity is high and short-term rates are low.
The analysis of conditions and terms of the loans suggest that when short-term
rates are lowand securitization activity is high margins on loans to riskier firms are
not affected while margins on riskier households – either for house purchase or for
consumption – are softened. In addition, collateral requirements, covenants, maturity
and loan-to-value ratio restrictions are softened.
When analyzing at the factors by which banks change the standards, in a situation
with low short-term rates and high securitization activity, the results we find
highlight: (i) the importance of the “shadow banking system” in setting of the
softening of banklendingstandards (both stemming from higher competition from
non-banks andfrom market finance, which both have a different level of regulation
and supervision than banks), (ii) the importance of bank balance-sheet liquidity in the
softening of standards, and (iii) the risk transfer effects linked to securitization in the
sense that the collateral risk and value may matter less for banks when granting loans
if banks can transfer these risks off.
All in all we find that low short-term rates soften lending standards. The
softening is over and above improvements in borrower’s collateral risk/ value and
outlook, and all the relevant standards are softened. Hence, our results suggest that
banks take on higher loan risk when overnight rates are low. In addition, the impact of
low short-term rates on the softening of standards is stronger when securitization is
high or banking supervision standards are weak, thus suggesting that low levels of
short-term rates may create excessive bank risk-taking (Allen and Gale, 2007; Rajan,
2005).
14
Finally, low short-term rates matter statistically and economically more than
14
From Allen and Gale (2007) for example, low short-term interest rates create high risk-taking by
banks because of moral hazard problems in banks. Hence, since we find that softer banking supervision
standards make stronger the impact of low rates on higher risk-taking, the evidence suggests excessive
risk-taking due to low short-term rates.
In addition, since – as explained earlier – the higher impact of low rates on the softening of standards
due to high securitization, that we find, may also be due to moral hazard problems (Rajan, 2005); our
evidence, therefore, suggests excessive risk-taking when short-term rates are low as compared to a
situation with low agency problems in the banking sector (i.e., banks grant more loans when short-term
8
low long-term rates on the softening of standards, both directly and indirectly via
softer bank supervision standardsand higher securitization levels. These results help
shed light on the root causes of the current global crisis (Allen, 2009; Rajan, 2009;
and Diamond and Rajan, 2009) and have important policy implications for monetary
policy, banking regulation andsupervision,and for financial stability.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section II describes the data,
introduces the variables employed in the empirical specifications, and reviews the
empirical strategy. Section III discusses the results and Section IV concludes.
II. Data and Empirical Strategy
A. The BankLending Survey (BLS) dataset
The main dataset used in the paper are the answers from the Euro Area BLS. The
national central banks of the Eurosystem request information on banklending
standards since 2002 through the Euro Area BLS, a quarterly survey on banks' lending
practices based on the answers of a representative sample of banks in each country.
The questions asked were chosen on the basis of theoretical considerations related to
the monetary policy transmission channels and on the experiences of other central
banks running similar surveys, in particular in the US and in Japan. The main set of
questions did not change since the start of the survey in 2002:Q4.
15
The survey contains 18 specific questions on past and expected credit market
developments. Past developments refer to credit conditions over the past three
months, while expected developments focus on the next three months. There are two
main borrower sectors that are the focus of the survey: enterprises and households.
Loans to households are further disentangled in loans for house purchase and for
consumer credit, consistently with the classification of loans in the official statistics
for the Euro Area.
rates are lowand may care less about the standards they set if they can securitize the loans thereby
transferring the risk off).
15
Berg, van Rixtel, Ferrando, de Bondt and Scopel (2005) describe in detail the setup of the survey.
Sauer (2009) provides an update of the most recent developments and the few changes to the survey
(request of additional information via ad-hoc questions).
9
The backward-looking questions cover the period from the last quarter of 2002 to
the first quarter of 2009. In order to use a balanced panel, the analysis is restricted to
the 12 countries which comprised the Euro Area in 2002:Q4. Over this period we
consistently have data for 12 Euro Area countries (Austria, Belgium, France, Finland,
Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain). The
sample of banks is representative of the banking sector in each country. Therefore it
comprises banks of different size, although national guidelines on the formation of the
sample expressed a preference to include the largest banks in each country.
The questions imply only qualitative answers and no figures are required. The
survey is carried out by the national central banks of the Euro Area countries.
Typically the questionnaire is sent to senior loan officers, like for example the
chairperson of the bank’s credit committee. The response rate has been virtually 100%
all the time.
The questionnaire covers both supply and demand factors. Concerning the supply
factors, which are addressed in ten different questions, attention is given to changes in
lending standards, to the factors responsible for these changes and to the credit
conditions and terms applied to customers.
Lending standards are defined as the internal guidelines or criteria that guide a
bank's loan policy and are addressed in two questions, each referring to a different
borrower (enterprises and households, further disentangled in loans for house
purchase and consumer loans).
16
The question asked is: “Over the past three months,
how have your bank’s lendingstandards as applied to the approval of loans (to
enterprises or to households) changed?” Banks can chose their answers among five
choices, ranging from “eased considerably” to “tightened considerably.” (See
Appendix for a detailed description of the questions used in the paper).
17
The successive set of questions gives respondents the opportunity to assess how
specific factors affected lendingstandards as applied to the approval of loans to both
16
In cases when foreign banks are part of the sample, the lendingstandards refer to the loans' policy in
the domestic market which may differ from guidelines established for the headquarter bank.
17
See http://www.ecb.int/stats/money/lend/html/index.en.html for all the information related to the
BLS.
10
enterprises and households. In particular whether the changes in standards were due to
changes in bank balance-sheet strength (either bank liquidity, capital, or access to
market finance), to changes in competitive pressures (either from other banks or from
non-banks), to changes in expected general economic conditions or changes in
borrower risk (borrower’s collateral risk/ value or borrower’s outlook). We will use
this information to assess whether the changes of standards are just due to changes in
borrower credit-worthiness to assess bank risk-taking and also to understand the
channels by which low rates, high securitization and weak supervision affect loan
risk-taking by banks.
Finally, we have information on the changes in the terms and conditions of a
loan. These are the contractual obligations agreed upon by the lender and the
borrower, such as the interest rate (both for average and for riskier borrowers), the
loan collateral, size, maturity and covenants. We use this information to assess
whether the different standards are adjusted for the risk taken.
Concerning demand factors, which are the topic of seven questions, various
factors related to financing needs and the use of alternative finance are mentioned.
Three questions look at borrowing demand from enterprises and four at demand from
households. Finally, the survey also allows participating banks to give free-formatted
comments in response to an open-ended question.
18
The Euro Area results of the survey (which are a weighted average of the results
obtained for each Euro Area country) are published every quarter on the website of
the ECB. In few countries, the answers from the Survey at the national level are
published by the respective national central banks. However, the overall sample
including all the answers at the country andbank level is confidential.
For the purpose of this paper we concentrate only on few questions from the BLS
that we describe in detail in Appendix I. The questions are related either to the
previous three months or to the expected change in lendingstandards for the next
three months. We find very similar results using either of the two set of questions and
18
For the purpose of this paper we do not use the answers to questions related to the demand; however,
in non-reported regressions we control for demand answers. The results are qualitatively similar.
[...]... Maddaloni and Peydró, 2009) 23 national central banks request from banks quarterly information on the lendingstandards they apply to customers and on the loan demand they observe We find robust evidence that low short-term interest rates soften standards for loans to both business and households, and the softening is over and above an improvement of the borrower’s collateral risk/ value and outlook,... change in lendingstandards due to changes in banks’ balance sheet constraints, i.e changes in standards not associated to borrowers’ quality (it corresponds to Question 2 and 9 of BLS, see Appendix) From column 7 to 12 we see that low overnight rates softens lendingstandards because of improvements in banks’ balance sheet position In this case lendingstandards are softened because of “pure” bank- supply... results highlight: (i) the importance of the “shadow banking system” in setting of the softening of banklendingstandards (both stemming from higher competition from non-banks andfrom market finance, which both have a different level of regulation and supervision than banks), (ii) the importance of bank balance-sheet liquidity in the softening of standards, and (iii) the risk transfer effects linked to... As explained earlier, national central banks request from banks quarterly information on the lendingstandards they apply to customers and on the loan demand they receive The survey started in 2002:Q4 and it collects the answers from a representative sample of around 90 banks This rich information allow us to analyze not only whether banks change the lendingstandards for the pool of borrowers they... shortterm rates are low and securitization activity is high 36 Bank risk problems may transmit through the system through interbank contagion and other mechanisms, see Iyer and Peydró (2009) and Bandt, Hartmann and Peydró (2009) Once the banking system is in trouble, a credit crunch stemming fromlowbank capital and liquidity has a high likelihood to happen (see Jiménez, Ongena, Peydró and Saurina, 2009b)... consider changes in lendingstandards due to bank balance-sheet constraints We find that higher securitization activity makes stronger the impact of low short-term rates on the softening of lendingstandards both for loans for house purchase and for consumption This implies that there is softening of standards over and above improvements of borrower risk due low short-term rates and high securitization... Area, and also in banking supervision standards All in all, the dynamics of the lending standards, of the securitization activity, supervision and of the business cycles show significant heterogeneity across Euro Area countries from 2002 to 2009 C Empirical strategy We want to empirically address the impact on the softening of lendingstandards of both short and long-term rates, of securitization and. .. the impact of low short-term rates on the softening of standards is stronger when securitization is high or banking supervision standards are weak It suggests excessive risk-taking as compared to a situation with zero or lowbank agency problems: From Allen and Gale (2007) for example, low short-term interest rates create high risk-taking by banks 22 because of moral hazard problems in banks Hence,... short-term rates are low, as compared to a situation with low agency problems in the banking sector.35 All in all, we find that low short-term interest rates, high securitization,and weaker banking regulation directly and in conjunction soften the lendingstandards This softening is over and above improvements in the borrowers’ credit-worthiness, thus indicating higher loan risk-taking by banks Moreover,... growth, inflation, securitization andbank regulation We use the answers from the confidential BankLending Survey where 35 As explained earlier, banks grant more loans when short-term rates are low and banks may care less about the lendingstandards they set if they can securitize the loans thereby transferring the risk outside In addition, the competition from the non-banking sector may intensify this . Bank Risk-Taking, Securitization, Supervision, and Low Interest Rates: Evidence from Lending Standards Angela Maddaloni and José-Luis Peydró * . banks request banks quarterly information on their lending standards. We find robust evidence that low short-term interest rates soften standards for both businesses and households and – by exploiting. whether, how and why banks change their lending standards. For indirect evidence on short-term rates and risk-taking, see Bernanke and Kuttner (2005), Rigobon and Sack (2004), Manganelli and Wolswijk