Castella 2004 impact of FLA on landuse VN

14 545 0
Castella 2004 impact of FLA on landuse VN

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

Tác động của giao đất lâm nghiệp vào việc sử dụng đất ở một tỉnh miền núi của Việt NamIn the early 1990s following the decollectivization of agriculture, the Vietnamese government distributed forest land-use rights to individual households. The new forestland policy had three related objectives: (i) the introduction of a sedentary livelihood system for those populations who had traditionally relied on shifting cultivation and regular migration; (ii) the development of the village economy through tree plantations; and (iii) the protection of forest resources. In this paper, we discuss the changes in land use that resulted from the new forestland policy and the effectiveness of the policy in achieving each of its three objectives. r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160 Impact of forestland allocation on land use in a mountainous province of Vietnam Jean-Christophe Castella a,b,c,Ã , Stanislas Boissau a,c , Nguyen Hai Thanh c , Paul Novosad c a Institut de Recherche pour le De ´ veloppement (IRD), 213 rue Lafayette, 75480 Paris, Cedex 10, France b International Rice Research Institute (IRRI), DAPO 7777, Metro Manila, Philippines c Mountain Agrarian Systems (SAM) Program, Vietnam Agricultural Science Institute (VASI), Thanh Tri, Hanoi, Vietnam Received 19 January 2004; received in revised form 15 May 2004; accepted 28 July 2004 Abstract In the early 1990s following the decollectivization of agriculture, the Vietnamese government distributed forest land-use rights to individual households. The new forestland policy had three related objectives: (i) the introduction of a sedentary livelihood system for those populations who had traditionally relied on shifting cultivation and regular migration; (ii) the development of the village economy through tree plantations; and (iii) the protection of forest resources. In this paper, we discuss the changes in land use that resulted from the new forestland policy and the effectiveness of the policy in achieving each of its three objectives. r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Keywords: Land policy; Forestland allocation; Natural resource management; Livelihood systems; Mountain agriculture; Bac Kan; Vietnam Introduction The allocation of forestland to individual households was the final step in the changes in land-use rights that accompanied the doi moi (renovation) reforms in Vietnam. In a context of declining agricultural produc- tivity and food shortages, the cooperative system was undergoing a major crisis. A dual system of production had developed, with collectively managed work in paddyfields complemented by individually managed work on the hillsides (Sadoulet et al., 2002). Although the ‘‘people’’ (in other words, the State, Article 19 of the 1980 constitution) officially owned all land, sloping lands had not been integrated into the cooperatives. For this reason, sloping lands continued to be cultivated according to rules of free-access, 1 providing a supple- mentary income for many households. In times of shortage, farmers focused on the private economy, increasing the area cultivated on the slopes, which led to major deforestation in northern regions (De Koninck, 1999; Castella et al., 2002). On April 5, 1988, the Vietnamese Communist Party politburo adopted Resolution 10 to address the agri- cultural crisis in the country. Resolution 10 emphasized the importance of private property rights, as well as the need for each region to design a development model suited to its own natural, economic and social environ- ment. In recogni tion of the importance of the private agricultural economy, the new policy dismantled the failing cooperatives and beg an to restore ownership of means of production to individuals (Bergeret, 1995; Kerkvliet and Porter, 1995). In the mountainous areas of northern Vietnam, the restoration of the rights of the ARTICLE IN P RESS www.elsevier.com/locate/landusepol 0264-8377/$ - see front matter r 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.landusepol.2004.07.004 Ã Corresponding author. IRD, B.P. 64501, 34394 Montpellier, Cedex 5, France. Tel.: +33 4 67 63 69 80; fax: +33 4 67 63 87 78. E-mail address: j.castella@ird.fr (J C. Castella). 1 Traditional land access was free, with the absence of rules made feasible by the low population pressure on mountainous areas at this (footnote continued) period ( Mellac, 2000). The farmer who cleared a given upland field secured for him- or herself the right to use that field until it was fallowed for regeneration. individual to use paddyland in the early 1990s was intended to stimulate paddyfield intensification while reducing pressure on the surrounding upland areas (Donovan et al., 1997). The policy was successful in that it gave farmers an incentive to invest more in their own ricefields, and resulted in substantial productivity gains in the inter-mountain valleys (Sikor, 1999; Mellac, 2000; Sadoulet et al., 2002). However, the implementation of the national land allocation policy varied from region to region. Rather than distributing land as the policy suggested, the Black Thai villages of Son La Province left the village in control of the land, and periodically redistributed land among households ( Sikor, 1999). In contrast, in 1990 the Tay ethnic group in the Cao Bang Province began a movement to reclaim the lands of their ancestors, a movement that soon spread to neighbouring provinces. As Tay farmers repossessed the land that their forefathers had contributed to the agricultural coopera- tives, other groups were left without paddyfields, particularly households who had not owned paddyfields before the institution of the cooperatives, but who had nonetheless been contributing to the cooperatives in recent years. These groups (mostly Kinh from the delta region and Dao and H’mong who had emigrated from the uplands) were forced to turn to the uplands to meet their food needs. Despite the paddyland allocations, many farmers turned to extensive slash-and-burn systems in the uplands, which had not yet been allocated (Rambo et al., 1995; Jamieson et al., 1998). The State hoped to regulate the runaway exploitation of the uplands by applying the same solution that had worked in the lowland areas (Pillot, 1995; Fforde and de Vylder, 1996; De Koninck, 1999). The forestland, which encompassed all land that was or should be covered in forest (as defined by the State), was allocated to individual households as stipulated in the 1993 land law. This final stage of the land allocation policy had three major objectives: (i) converting the populations of migratory cultivators to a sedentary livelihood system, (ii) increas- ing agricultural production in the uplands by giving farmers incentives to grow perennial plantations, and (iii) preserving the deteriorating forest resource base (Government of the Socialist Republic of Vietnam, 1994; Nguyen et al., 1995). In this paper, we examine the goals of the State in forestland allocation. Based on a case study undertaken in four villa ges in a mountainous region of northern Vietnam, we then analyse to what extent this land allocation achieved its stated goals and what impacts it had on the livelihood systems of farmers. Finally, we discuss possible trajectories of future production sys- tems, and their implications for development interven- tions. Methods The study draws on diverse sources of data including (i) a review of published literature, official statistics, legal and policy documents, (ii) monographic studies and analysis of land cover maps derived from aerial photographs, and (iii) qualitative data collected in interviews, oral histories and participatory observation. In four remote mountain villages within Na Ri District of Bac Kan Province, we investigated the process and effects of forestland allocation at the grassroots level. None of the four villages is accessible by road or motorized transportation. Unlike many other ethnic minority villages in Bac Kan province, these villages have not been the targets of the major government projects (i.e., infrastructure, education, production innovations) associated with the sedentar- ization policy . Fig. 1 shows the location of the four villages within Lang San and Luong Thuong communes of Na Ri District, along the Khuoi Sung and Ngan Son rivers. We selected these villages to cover a large range ARTICLE IN P RESS Khuoi Sap Nam Ca Na Hiu Khuoi Noc 5km District boundary Commune boundary Hamlet Village boundary River, stream Road Case study site in Na Ri District Bac Kan Province Vietnam, with province boundaries Fig. 1. Study site in Bac Kan Province. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160148 of diversity in ethnic composition, natural resource base, and livelihood systems. The objective of the case study was to analyse the way that the same land policies resulted in notably diff erent impacts on villages even in a limit ed geographic area, due to the initial diversity of village situations. Our fieldwork was performed over the course of several stays in the villages in 1999 and 2000. We combined informal interviews with direct observa- tion. In addition, we conducted an exhaustive survey of all village households (n ¼ 106), allowing us to system- atically complete the qualitative data collection. We analysed the impact of forestland allocation on farmers’ livelihood systems and trajectories of changes in land use by eliciting local people’s explanations of why they had changed agricultural practices, by examining forest tenure rights on the ground, and by investigating, and when possible, ruling out other causes of change in land-use practices. Some evidence on changes in land use/land cover at the village and district scales is reported in more detail in Castella et al. (2002). Allocation of forestland in the mountain areas of northern Vietnam The objectives of the allocation Fixed settlement of shifting cultivators: In the moun- tain areas of northern Vietnam, the predominant upland production system is swidden cultivation (Do, 1994). Swidden cultivation involves burning a section of forest and then growing crops (usually upland rice) in the rich soil that is left behind. The quality of the soil degenerates quickly, so after several years of cultivation the land is left fallow for a much longer period so that the forest can regenerate (Husson et al., 2001; Roder, 2001). The particulars of swidden cultivation differ from one group and from one region to another, but share the common principle of leaving the land to regenerate. In this paper, we distinguish rotational cultivation (fixed house, shifting fields) from migratory cultivation (shift- ing house, shifting fields), which complies with the need of swidden cultivators to search for mature forests to clear. The desire to settle mountainous populations in fixed areas is not new in Vietnam. Suc h policies first appeared in the colonial era, where settled populations were necessary for political control and taxation. Further, one of the objectives for the institution of the cooperatives in the mountainous areas was bringing nomadic populations down from the mountains, and encouraging them to participate in lowland ricefield cultivation ( Dang, 1991). Before the collectiv e period, certain ethnic groups were the predominant cultivators of lowland rice, while others engaged in swidden cultivation. During the collective period, they all engaged to some extent in swidden cultivation, the former in the form of rotational cultivation and the latter as migratory cultivation. Today, such a distinct ion is no longer possible—swidden cultivators are rather those who have been excluded from land allocation, regardless of ethnicity. Despite its diversity, until recently all swidden cultivation was considered to be similar and equally destructive (Do, 1994; Morrison and Dubois, 1998). The State views migratory cultivators as leading a precarious existence and harming forest resources (Dang, 1991). By settling these farmers on allocated pieces of land, the State hoped to end their slash-and-burn practices and encourage them to develop stable and fixed production systems (e.g., perennial plantations) that would allow them to prod uce more and consequently earn more. Protection of forest resources and the battle against deforestation: Forest cover in Vietnam has decreased dramatically in recent decades, from 45% of the country’s area in 1943 to only 28% in 1991 (of which only 10% was primary forest; Vo, 1998). These percentages correspond to a reduction in natural forest area by 350,000 ha/year over the last 25 years. Defor- estation has been accompanied by the appearance of severely eroded cleared lands, which according to some estimates covered up to 40% of the country in 1990 (Vo and Le, 1994). While the causes of deforestation include war, timber exploitation (Poffenberger et al., 1997), relative land scarcity due to increasing population and to regulations on access to resources, the State placed the blame for deforestation squarely on the backs of the migratory cultivators. The State has long perceived swidden cultivation (ra ˆ y in the Kinh language) as an ‘‘irrational’’ technique, a backward system that must eventually evolve into sedentary cultivation: ‘‘In Vietnam, since 1968, the Government has combined sedentarization and agricultural cooperation campaigns in search of a rational use of forest resources, to help mountain populations assist in mass agricultural production and put an end to their outdated raˆ y practices’’ (Dang, 1991, p. 26). It is worth noting that if a burned field is left fallow for enough time after cropping, then the soil and forest can regenerate sufficiently to provide for the next cycle of cultivation. Thus under the right conditions, particu- larly a combination of low population pressure and regular migration, swidden cultivation is sustainable (De Rouw and Van Oers, 1988; Mazoyer and Roudart, 1997). However, in the period following the coopera- tives, low population pressure was no longer a characteristic of northern Vietnam. Allocating the forestland an d obliging nomadic peoples to practice sedentary production would, the State hoped, result in an end to the deforestation process begun decades earlier. ARTICLE IN P RESS J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160 149 Increasing production through regional specialization: Resolution 10 aimed to transform the economy from a focus on self-sufficiency to a focus on the national market: ‘‘The renovation of economic management must meet the following needs: [y] transform our agriculture, still autarkic in many regions, into specialized goods production based on the natural, social and economic characteristics of each region, thus modernizing socialist agricultural production. [y]’’ (Resolution 10). For the agricultural sector, the State envisioned a system of regional specialization, with intensive rice production in the delta regions complemented by large-sca le sylvicul- ture and animal husbandry in the mountainous regions. These sedentary production systems would require sedentary populations to manage them. Fig. 2 summarizes the rationale behind the forestland allocation. The granting of individual property rights on sloping land put an end to the free access system. Free access has often been identified as the primary cause of the ov er-exploitation of forest resources that had taken place, as farmers can gain individual profits from the land, while the costs of such exploitation are shared collectively (Hardin, 1968). By granting renewable land- use rights, the State hoped to transfer responsibility to the individual, who would reap the benefits but a lso pay the costs associated with the exploitation of forestland. Individual responsibility would give farmers the needed incentive to make ‘‘rational’’ use of their land, leading to the protection of forestland (arrow 1 in Fig. 2). Private ownership would also encourage individuals to invest in their forestland and develop perennial plantations (2). Developing commercial perennial crops would lead to both an increase in tree cover and additional income for households, thus improving living conditions (3). Assuming that poverty is what motivates farmers to adopt short-term unsustainable survival strategies, the economic gains from perennial plantations would allow better protection of the forest (4). Further, the migration associated with shifting cultivation would no longer be necessary, tying improved living standards to policy on sedentary livelihood systems (5). Sedentary livelihood systems reinforce individual responsibility for resources and provide an incentive for the development of perennial plantations (6). The allocation process Forestland allocation began in 1992, and was still underway in 2002 in some remote communes. Resolu- tion 10 (April 1988) defined the main features of land allocation, with the 1993 land law and Decree 02-CP (January 15, 1994) supplying additional details. The allocation policy is also closely associated with the forest protection and de velopment code implemented in 1991. The 1993 land law (Article 43) defines forestland as ‘‘all land identified as being destined for sylviculture, natural forest regeneration, reforestation, timber, nur- series, forestry research and experimentation’’. Because forestland was defined according to planned future use rather than present use, the policy resulted in classifica- tion as ‘‘forests’’ of some lands that were currently being cultivated with annual crops and had been for dozens of years. This categorization included the majority of sloping land in the mountainous regions. Forests were classified into three distinct types:  Protected forest, for the preservation of water resources; the prevention of erosion, natural disasters, and climatic risks; and the overall protection of the environment.  Special-use forest, intended for the conservation of nature and of plant and animal species; scientific research; and the protection of historic, cultural and tourist sites.  Production forest, used primarily for timber and other forest products, and associated with the other types of forest to protect the environment. ARTICLE IN P RESS Fig. 2. Rationale for forestland allocation. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160150 The land-allocation process consisted of a series of meetings, beginning at the district People’s Committee and pro gressing down the administrativ e hierarchy to each individual village. The district developed an allocation plan, which delineated the areas to be classified as one of three types of forest (protection forest, production forest, special-use forest). The plan was then disseminated through the communes to the villages, where each household who wanted to receive a plot of forestland had to fill in a request form, which was sent on to the Forest Service. The Forest Service then measured and classified each individual plot. In many cases, the process only ratified the informal rights that already existed, the clear er’s rights, for households often requested the plots that they wer e currently developing or cultivating. The allocations thus legitimized tradi - tional land-use rights. That said, a number of conflicts also arose from the allocations, with households occasionally evicted from the process by a village head trying to privilege his own lineage. Such conflicts are reminiscent of those that arose with the allocation of irrigated ricefields at the end of the collective period and the ancestral reclamation movement (Nguyen and La, 1999). Once all conflicts had been cooperatively resol ved at the village level, the Forest Service integrated the information into a land map and gave certificates of land-use rights to households. Following the granting of land-use certificates, a meet- ing was held in each village to address the issue of forest protection. At this meeting, the Forest Service explained the policy and regulations concerning forest protection and development, and each household possessing forest- land had to sign an agreement to treat their land accordingly. Each village was then able to develop its own system of forest management, protection and development based on its own particular circumstances. However, the rules implemented by all villages were based on model regulations supplied by the Forest Service. The rule development system appeared to be par- ticipatory and flexible, but in reality it was a top-down procedure. Instructions were passed down from one hierarchical level to the next with minimal changes. It was not uncommon to find that the management rules of one village were nothing more than a photocopy of those of the ne igh- bouring village, with the names of the villa ge and its leaders changed. The top-down implementation of the system favoured neither local participation nor ownership. The effects of the forestland allocation We examined the effects of the forestland allocation through a case study of four villages in Bac Kan Province (Fig. 1 and Box 1). In Na Ri District as a whole, the allocation process began in 1992 and ended in 2000. Spe cifically, the allocation of land-use rights in Lang San and Luong Thuong communes took place from 1997 to 2000. The villages studied were all founded relatively recently, the oldest being Nam Ca, settled just 100 years ago. All of the villages with the exception of Na Hiu were settled for their abundant forest resources, 2 and even Na Hiu now relies on the forest more than ever, as two-thirds of its ricefields were repossessed during the Tay land reclamation movement. Although paddy rice has gained popularity as a means of subsistence, there is almost no remaining land in the region suitable for terracing for new paddyfields. The majority of households cannot produce enough paddyland rice to feed themselves, and have adopted production strategies based on rotational swidden cultivation. Effects on sedentary livelihood systems Clarification of individual and village land boundaries: The nature of the forestland allocation process necessi- tated the clear demarcation of each individual’s property rights. In doing this, the Forest Service implicitly defined all village and commune boundaries. ‘‘Under the old system, individuals of the neighbouring villages could clear lands in the territory of our village for swidden cultivation, and the village authorities were powerless to stop them. This often led farmers to blame neighbouring villages for forest deterioration’’. Under the new land allocation system, farmers are fully responsible for their own land, and should be satisfied that no household other than their own can harm this resource. What was designated as ‘‘village territory’’ now comprised the set of land plots allocated to the households of a village, together with plots placed under direct village owner- ship. Each village territory defined clear boundaries for agricultural and forestry activities. By definition, the existence of individual land-use rights excluded indivi- duals from use of land to which they did not have formal land-use rights. Thus, the new land policy abruptly ended the traditional free access rules that had existed before. Each village and household now possessed land that was protected from outsiders, but that same protection now also limited the scope of their actions. The end of free access was of critical importance to those groups with production systems based on ARTICLE IN P RESS 2 Although settlers chose the locations for these villages for their abundance of ‘‘primary’’ forest, the settlers did not realize that the forest was not more than 20 years old. Aerial photographs from 1954, 1977 and 1998 show that although the areas were densely forested in 1954, they had been cleared almost entirely at least once by 1977. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160 151 migratory cultivation, particularly the H’mong and Dao people in the study area. Under the new land policy, these groups could no longer migrate in search of mature forests to clear, as other individuals or villages now owned the right to use all forests. At first glance, one of the goals seemed to have been accom- plished: previously nomadic populations were settled permanently. How ever, it is necessary to distinguish between sedentary housing and sedentary production systems. Sedentary housing versus sedentary production systems: Effective transformation from a migratory to a seden- tary society has at least two different levels of indicators:  sedentary housing, indicated by kinds of homes and the materials used to construct them; and  sedentary production systems, indicated by an agri- cultural system that is ecologically and economically sustainable within a fixed territory (without requiring regular migration). ARTICLE IN P RESS Box 1 Main characteristics of the four villages under study. In 2000, Na Hiu village comprised 9 households spread out over a large area. The village population was made up of 62 inhabitants of diverse ethnic backgrounds, including Dao Cooc Mun, Red Dao and Nung. The villagers shared a history of coming to Na Hiu in search of cultivable land. The first arrived in 1985 and redeveloped a group of paddyfields that had been abandoned for more than 20 years. Most of these paddyfields have since been repossessed by the original owners. The remaining inhabitants (the later arrivals) were not able to acquire paddyfields and had to rely on the forested slopes. Although Na Hiu village was founded because of its abandoned ricefields, its inhabitants have increasingly turned to swidden cultivation and hunting and gathering as a mean of survival. Even the inhabitants who arrived in the hope of developing new paddyfields now depend on the forest for survival, as terracing requires considerable investment in labour. Many paddyfield terraces have been under construction for years and remain unfinished. Nam Ca village was founded over 100 years ago by a Tay, whose descendants now make up the 11 households and 57 inhabitants of the village. He chose a location favourable for the development of irrigated paddyfields, the basis of Tay production systems in northern Vietnam (Castella and Erout, 2002). However, the lowlands are now saturat ed, and no more paddyfields can be constructed. This has led the village to develop new inheritance rules forcing all but the eldest son in each family to emigrate. Households rely primarily on paddy-rice cultivation, with upland glutinous rice as a supplement. The forest is also used for free-grazing buffaloes in the winter season. In the spring of 2000, most households attempted a spring-season cycle of rice. The trials were not a complete failure, but produced mediocre yields due to cold weather. Khuoi Sap is the village farthest from the road, the administrative centre, and the marketplace (about an hour and a half away by foot). In 2000, Khuoi Sap comprised 17 households and 95 people, all Red Dao with the exception of one Tay family. The village encompasses four hamlets settled by two different family groups. The continuous spread of the village was motivated by the abundance of old-growth forestland that could be cleared and used for the production of upland rice. Village inhabitants initially opened swidden fields very close to their houses, but with time villagers cleared areas farther and farther from the settlements, now reaching distances of up to one or two hours on foot. The village production system is based on swidden cultivation, beginning with several years of upland rice follow ed by cassava and maize. This is complemented by hunting and gathering. Only two families own paddyfields, and these only cover a small area (1000 m 2 each). Khuoi Noc village occup ies the entire northern area of Luong Thuong Commune. The village is composed of 394 H’mong inhabi tants forming 70 households spread among six hamlets. When the first households (about 22) arrived from Cao Bang Province in 1983, the land was unoccupied. Founded because of the area’s abundant primary forests, the village now has an economy based on the swidden cultivation of upland rice and cassava, narrow fields of maize on the flat lands along the river, and hunting and gathering. Only 5 of the 70 families own irrigated ricefields, which they built themselves; the combined surface area is only 8100 m 2 . Some families engage in gold mining to complement their income. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160152 The Tay village of Nam Ca offers an example of sedentary housing. The people of the village have lived in the same location for over 100 years and have built houses on wooden stilts with tile roofs. Such houses require substantial investmen ts in both materials and labour. Migrating populations tend not to build such houses, but usually live instead in houses made from bamboo, built on the ground or on simple stilts. This type of house is mostly found in Dao and H’mong villages. For a family to build a wooden-stilt house with a tile roof is both a sign of relative wealth and an indicator that they intend to stay in one place for several years at least, even if such structures can occasionally be sold upon departure. The second, more fundamental change in the liveli- hood systems is the transition from a system based on swidden cultivation to a system based on irrigated ricefields, whether in flatlands or terraces on sloping land surrounded by intensive (long cultivation, short fallow period) upland fields. Almost all farmers in the study area had this transition as one of their goals, even before the new land policy. Even though the construc- tion of paddyfields or terraces is extre mely labour- intensive, farmers consider paddy rice cultivation to be easier than sloping-la nd cultivation. This is particularly the case when the swidden fields have to be cleared from degraded forests, requiring increased time investment in weeding for lower and highly uncertain yields (Husson et al., 2001 ; Roder, 2001). The village headman of Khuoi Sap stated that: ‘‘Everyone in the village would be ready to buy a paddyfield like I did, or expand the paddy area as I did, but we do not have any more suitable land for terracing’’. Although the majority of households have identified paddyfields as a major objective, few have achieved this objective. Reasons put forward by the farmers surveyed include inadequate access to flatlands, inadequate water sources for irrigating ter- races on sloping lands, and insufficient labour for the construction of paddyfields or terraces. The villages with economies based on irrigated rice (Nam Ca and part of Na Hiu) had both sedentary housing and sedentary production systems even before the forestland allocation. Consequently, transformation to a sedentary society was not an issue for them. The remaining villages (Khuoi Sap, Khuoi Noc and the rest of Na Hiu) have been converted to a sedentary existence only in terms of their housing. Even after the implementation of the new land policy, the majority of production systems in the studied Dao and H’mong villages continue to be based on swidden cultivation, a system that is sustainable only when accompanied by regular migration and under the condition of low demographic pressure (Mazoyer and Roudart, 1997). These populations now find themselves in a very delicate situation, with a production system that is poorly adapted to their institutional environment. At the same time, their sedentary housing reveals a de facto transformation to a sedentary lifestyle. This is not a true transformation of society based on a new livelihood system that no longer requires migration. Rather, it is merely a transitional stage induced by the loss of the possibility to migrate but not yet truly sustainable. Effects on forest protection Individual responsibility for forests: Farmers fre- quently mentioned the rapid decrease in old-growth forest that has taken place in recent years, and state that the over-exploitation of the forest could have serio us effects on their families. They stated that ‘‘four or five years ago farmers in Khuoi Noc reached the last forested areas suitable for swidden cultivation within their village boundaries’’. This statement was confirmed by our analysis of a chronological series of land-use maps (1954, 1977, 1998) that revealed the rapid decrease in forest cover between 1977 and 1998 in the study area (see land-use maps of Luong Thuong and Lang San communes in the digital atlas in Castella et al., 2003). Deforestation was associated with a sharp increase in upland crop areas and shrub land, whi ch is typical of the rapid expansion of swidden cultivation that occurred everywhere in Bac Kan Province before the allocation of forestland (Castella et al., 2002). As a consequence, forest wildlife, another important component of peo- ple’s livelihood, has also rapidly disappeared. The populations of the study villages wer e mostly satisfied with the individual land allocations (Table 1), though not necessarily for the same reasons. Most farmers received the land that they requested, that which would have been theirs by traditional rights. Some were happy to own land near their home, as this either reduced the walking time to swidden fields or allowed for the continual surveillanc e required for the develop- ment of perennial plantations. Others were happy with the quality of the land (generally when old-growth forest was involved). The reasons for individual satisfaction tended to reflect people’s planned use of the forestland. Consequently, many were less enthusiastic about the accompanying forest protection policy as an outright ban on forest exploi tation would jeopardize their food security. Farmers in the study area are particularly conscious of the need for forest protection, as their livelihoods depend on the survival of this resource base. The announcement of the forest protection policy, particularly the ban on the clearing and burning of forestland, was met with apprehension by a large number of farmers who had no short-term alternative ways to feed their families. Given their reliance on the forest, farmers are eager to learn about initiatives to protect it. New circumstances will inevitably force them to develop new production systems to compensate for the ban on swidden production. ARTICLE IN P RESS J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160 153 The end of swidden cultivation: Farmers are experien- cing declining yields from swidden fields and increasing labour requirements for weeding. Fig. 3 shows that the number of newly opened swidden fields has decreased over the last 2 years. Our field survey indicates that a large number of households have continued to cultivate swidden fields opened in previous years. Farmers explained that this change is a direct consequence of the forestland allocation and forest protection policy as it is no longer possible to open new fields. The cultivation of old swidden fields is parti cularly striking in Khuoi Noc, where some swidden fields have been cultivated continuously since 1990, while in Na Hiu and Khuoi Sap the oldest fields date from 1994 and 1995, respectively. In addition, the yields of newly cleared swidden fields (defined as the rice harvest in proportion to the quantity of seed sown) have been declining in Khuoi Noc. For the village head of Khuoi Noc ‘‘the low and still diminishing yields in my village are the result of a forest that is becoming thinner and thinner while the population of swidden cultivators, swollen by immigration, continues to rise’’. The surprising (and alarming) result is that fields in their first year of cultivation produce yields that are even lower than fields that have been cultivated for 7 years (Fig. 4). We checked with the farmer that this result was not imputable to an exceptional bad climatic season or unfavourable field topography but to the ‘‘repeated use of the same pieces of land, which exhausts the soil’’ as an older farmer in Khuoi Sap explained. The average surface area of swidden fields 3 opened 3 years earlier has not changed substantially (Fig. 5). Taken with declining yields, this is a clear sign that, confined to fixed terr itories under the new land policy , production systems based on swidden agriculture are slowly failing. ARTICLE IN P RESS Table 1 Farmers’ satisfaction with forest land allocations (expressed answers only) Village Na Hiu Nam Ca Khuoi Sap Khuoi Noc Total Expressed satisfaction Very satisfied 2 6 8 16 32 Fairly satisfied 3 3 3 31 40 Not satisfied 1 0 1 13 15 Reason for satisfaction Proximity 5 1 5 23 34 Land quality 0 5 5 16 26 Other 1 3 1 6 11 Fig. 3. Number of upland fields under cultivation in 2000, plotted against year of opening. * Swidden fields opened in 2000 under cultivation in 2001. Fig. 4. Yield of upland rice crops cultivated in 2000, plotted against year of opening. * Yields are expressed as multiples of the quantity of seeds sown. For example, if a farmer sowed 10 kg/ha and harvested 150 kg/ha, then the yield would be 15 (150/10=15). 3 Because it is difficult to measure actual plot sizes on sloping lands, we estimated the surface area of swidden fields by the kilograms of seeds sown per plot, using a conversion factor of 10 kg seed sown per hactare. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160154 Effects on agricultural production and economic development The new land policy was intended to result in both intensification of paddyland production and the use of the uplands for perennial plantations and livestock development. Both outcomes were intended to increase the income and thus the quality of life of farmers. In reality, the new system exacerbated the problems of swidden cultivation without providing farmers with an adequate alternative source of income. Migratory cultivators facing crisis: The reduction in upland rice yields implies a reduction in the living standards of the populations who rely on swidden cultivation. In 1999, in two out of the three villages that formerly practiced migratory cultivation, the average rice yield was under the 250 kg/person self-sufficiency threshold (Table 2). Indeed, a substantial number of households faced rice deficits in 1999 (Table 3). This does not necessarily mean that they went hungry, but instead purchased rice, or relied on non-rice staples. However, as most of these complementary sources of food are traditionally harvested from the forest ecosys- tem, their quantity and quality were deeply affected by deforestation and access to these resources was affected by the forestland allocation to individuals. The Dao (which means ‘‘people of the forest’’) people recognize that ‘‘beyond the negative impact of the imposed sedentary life on their traditional cropping systems the new land policy has transformed other key activities such as animal husbandry, hunting, gathering, and collection of timber and firewood’’. The multiplicity of land uses and local rules over natural resource management that overlap on the same forestland creates a very complex situation in the relationships between people and their environment. Considerable variability was observed between locations with respect to specific village regulations over individual and or collective manage- ment of forest resources (Pandey and Dang, 1998; Castella and Dang, 2002). In sum, a general feature of the villages predomi- nantly populated by swidden cultivators is a high percentage of households facing food deficits, which is indicative of a production system in crisis, a system that is no longer adapted to its environment. We will now discuss how farmers have adapted their production systems in response to the crisis, and more generally how they have adapted their systems to the new land policy. Intensification of lowland production: The ban on opening new upland fields was intende d to encourage households to focus their energies on the lowlands. Lowland rice production can be increased either by creating new pa ddyfields; or intensifying production in existing paddyfields (e.g., by introducing a spring-season rice crop); or both. New paddyfields have recently been constructed in Na Hiu (eight households) and Khuoi Noc (six households), while two households from Khuoi Sap purchased paddyfields. However, most of this increase happened between 1987 and 1993, before the new forestland policy was implemented. Our interview s ARTICLE IN P RESS Fig. 5. Surface area of upland ricefields cultivated in 2000 plotted against year of opening. * Plot size is expressed in kilograms of seeds sown per plot (the sowing density commonly used as a reference is 10 kg seeds/ha). Table 2 Indices of upland rice production in 1999, by village Index of upland rice production Village Khuoi Sap Na Hiu Khuoi Noc ‘A’=quantity seed sown/person (kg) 16 12 13 ‘B’=average yield 18 18 14 ‘A Â B’=average production/person (kg) 288 216 182 N.B. Yields are expressed as multiples of the quantity of seeds sown. Table 3 Indices of rice deficit in 1999, by village Index of rice deficit Village Khuoi Sap Nam Ca Na Hiu Khuoi Noc Percentage of households experiencing deficit (food requirements exceeded rice production) 59% 20% 87% 67% Average length of the deficit (months) 2253 J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160 155 indicated that the decreasing availability of old-growth forest was already encouraging individuals to move to the lowlands; land allocations were only an added incentive. As we mentioned earlier, the paddyland within the study area is already almost saturated; little flatland remains that could still be developed. In spite of a growing population and the progressive subdivision of fields (because of inheritance), no new ricefields have been created in Nam Ca since 1971. With the lowlands already saturated with ricefields, the only possibility for increased production in Nam Ca is to find ways to intensify rice production in existing ricefields. In the spring of 2000 Nam Ca farmers began to experiment with increasing production by adding a second, spring - season rice crop. Farmers in Nam Ca justified this intensification of paddy-rice production as a conse- quence of the increased demographic pressure within the village co mbined with the restrictions imposed by the village authorities on clearing new lands on the hillsides. This illustrates the interdependence of paddylands and sloping lands, demonstrated by Castella and Ero ut (2002). Perennial plantations: State policy suggests a future of uplands brimming with fruit tree plantations, bringing wealth or at least self-sufficiency even to farmers who lack paddyfields. With swidden cultivation no longer feasible, upland rice production will decline or cease, and perennial plantations are expected to fill the gap. Plantations are indeed being developed in the study area, but they are far from an all-purpose solution to the difficulties faced by farmers. Cinnamon and anise plantations account for 70% and 15%, respectively, of the trees planted in the study area, while fruit trees (e.g. plum, orange, apricot) make up the remaining 15% (Fig. 6). For most farmers, tree-crop production is still experimental, as revealed by the fact that the majority of plantations are very small—the trees are located in the vegetable garden or very near to swidden fields, and the harvest is mostly consumed by the household. ‘‘Planta- tions represent a highly uncertain source of income because of village remoteness and market uncertainty’’ mentioned the few household heads who engaged in large scale cinnamon plantations in Na Hui with the help of the World Food Programme thanks to their proximity to the main road as compared to the three other villages. The new land policy successfully destabilized migra- tory cultivation, but perennial plantations and lowland intensification have not been sufficient to meet the needs of swidden farmers. Struggling to feed their families, they are rapidly experimenting with new possibilities, from aquaculture and animal husbandry (mainly poultry, pigs, and cattle) to the testing of any cropping innovation that shows promise. Another option is to move to a new location in search of better environ- mental conditions for agriculture or opportunities for non-agricultural income. New kinds of migration: Migrating to new communes or districts within the province is no longer possible because all the land has already been allocated to villagers. However, households without opportunities in their current locations can move their houses closer to forestland they own within a village. In Khuoi Sap and Khuoi Noc, some households have created new hamlets, and others have moved their houses to their more remote upland plots to develop irrigated paddyfields or fishponds. A few other families have moved closer to the road to engage in non-farming activities such as small- scale commerce (e.g., selling consumer goods or agricultural inputs) or motorcycle taxi services, as well as to give their children better access to schools. The most dramatic option is migration to southern Vietnam, where New Economic Zones are being developed. Supported by State subsidi es, families can relocate to work in the new industrial plantations (mostly coffee and rubber) in these zones, located in the Central Highlands region or in the south of Vietnam. The New Economic Zones hold a particular appeal for highland peoples; the prospect of having sufficient land to grow commercial crops that can be readily sold leads many to dream of a better future. Ten households from Khuoi Sap have already made the long journey. Between 1991 and 1996 nearly 1.5 million people migrated to the Central Highlands (Vo et al., 1999). The journey south is costly; farmers interviewed estimated that such an undertaking would cost at least ten milli on dong. Migration is thus only possible for households who have been able to accumulate capital, but who nonetheless find themselves in sufficiently difficult circumstances to justify leaving everything behind for the great unknown. Households who have difficulty meeting their most basic needs are more likely to consider small-scale migration (often within a village) to improve their situation. ARTICLE IN P RESS Fig. 6. Plantation composition per village. J C. Castella et al. / Land Use Policy 23 (2006) 147–160156 [...]... potato, etc.) Biophysical conditions of the plot (irrigation, micro-climate, etc.) Mechanization Extension of existing paddies or construction of new ones Hill-sides Plantation of perennial crops: fruit trees, etc Stabilization of rotational cropping systems on the existing agricultural land on the slopes: improved fallow management, mulching, direct seeding on cover crops, etc (Husson et al., 2001) Terracing... allocation policy was concomitant with a general trend towards paddyland intensification (introduction of a spring season rice crop, Castella and Erout, 2002) and forest regeneration (Castella et al., 2002) However, the causal relationship had not been not fully demonstrated In some cases, the trend to paddyland intensification and forest protection preceded the implementation of the land allocation ARTICLE... Dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, USA Sikor, T., 2001 The allocation of forestry land in Vietnam: did it cause the expansion of forests in the northwest? Forest Policy and Economics 2, 1–11 Tachibana, T., Nguyen, T., Otsuka, K., 2001 Agricultural intensification versus extensification: a case study of deforestation in the northern-hill region of Vietnam Journal of Environmental Economics... have only been implemented on a very small scale, if at all Meanwhile, swidden cultivation continues, in a Malthusian spiral of impoverishment associated with environmental degradation Finally, depending on local circumstances and on the history of population settlement, the same policy can have completely opposite effects and lead to a Malthusian situation of resource depletion as well as a Boserupian... From Plan to Market: Economic Transition in Vietnam 1979–1994 Westview Press, Boulder Government of the Socialist Republic of Vietnam, 1994 Allocation of Forest Land to Organizations, Households, and Individuals for Stable and Long-term Use for Forestry Purposes Decree No 02CP, 15.1.1994 Of cial Gazette, Hanoi Hardin, G., 1968 The tragedy of the commons Science 162, 1243–1248 Husson, O., Ha Dinh T., Lienhard,... Sustainable livelihoods in Upland Vietnam: land allocation and beyond Forestry and Land Use Series 14, International Institute for Environment and Development (IIED), London Nguyen, V.H., La C.Y., 1999 Cac Quan He Dat Dai va Nhung Mau Thuan Ruong Dat o Vung Nong Thon Mien Nui Mien Bac Hien Nay (Land Relations and Conflicts in Rural Mountain Areas of Northern Vietnam) Uy Ban Dan Toc va Mien Nui, Hanoi... Our study of four remote mountain villages in northern Vietnam revealed many of the consequences of individual forestland allocations The biggest distinction in effects is between two kinds of farmers: those who have their food needs met by paddyland rice, and those who do not The allocation of forestland and the associated protection policy did not endanger the land-use systems of farmers belonging to... demarcation of individual land-use rights in the uplands, which prevented migration and thus increased the population pressure on the land owned by these individuals on the hillsides The implicitly enforced sedentarization has made swidden cultivation unsustainable The upland cultivation that is currently continuing is characterized by decreasing yields and deteriorating forest and soil quality—the signs of. .. belonging to the first group The focus of their production continues to be paddylands With irrigated rice forming the basis of their household consumption, these families, often with houses and fields established decades earlier, had already ceased to rely on sloping lands to feed themselves They still clear sloping lands on the edges of ricefields both to allow more sunshine on the ricefields in the narrow valley... paddies, would allow considerable expansion of paddies Access to cultivars and inputs Market for product Limited so far because of the lack of capital Only farms with large paddies and limited labour force are concerned (Sadoulet et al., 2002) Suitable land very limited; this option is becoming marginal because of the historical settlement of the lowlands Access to market, transportation infrastructure, . concerned (Sadoulet et al., 2002). Extension of existing paddies or construction of new ones Suitable land very limited; this option is becoming marginal because of the historical settlement of. provide for the next cycle of cultivation. Thus under the right conditions, particu- larly a combination of low population pressure and regular migration, swidden cultivation is sustainable (De Rouw. the overall protection of the environment.  Special-use forest, intended for the conservation of nature and of plant and animal species; scientific research; and the protection of historic, cultural

Ngày đăng: 25/03/2014, 13:47

Mục lục

  • Impact of forestland allocation on land use in a mountainous province of Vietnam

    • Introduction

    • Methods

    • Allocation of forestland in the mountain areas of northern Vietnam

      • The objectives of the allocation

      • The allocation process

      • The effects of the forestland allocation

        • Effects on sedentary livelihood systems

        • Effects on forest protection

        • Effects on agricultural production and economic development

        • Discussion

          • Land allocation and trajectories of change in land use

          • Lessons for development interventions/policy implications

          • Conclusions

          • References

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan