Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 26 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
26
Dung lượng
311,14 KB
Nội dung
EconomicDevelopmentandthe Escape
from High Mortality
JAVIER A. BIRCHENALL
*
University of California, Santa Barbara, CA, USA
Summary. — This paper studies the characteristic features of theescapefromhighmortality as re-
corded fromthe historical experience of Northwestern Europe andfromthe current experience of
less developed countries. The paper documents stylized facts of mortality change and measures the
contribution of economic development, represented by income per capita, to themortality decline
during the second half of the 20th century. The paper argues that improvements in economic con-
ditions since the 18th century are an important factor behind the decline in death rates in developed
countries and in the subsequent reduction of death rates in less developed countries. We show that
economic development lowers mortality through differential effects in infectious disease mortality
and that quantitatively, income growth is able to account for between one-third and one-half of
the recent mortality decline.
Ó 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
JEL classification — I12, O11, O33
Key words — mortality, economic development, developed and less developed countries
1. INTRODUCTION
Death is inevitable and irreversible, but the
last three centuries have seen remarkable pro-
gress in the reduction of human mortality.
The mortality of pre-modern populations var-
ied considerably, but a simple comparison typ-
ically finds that the average life expectancy at
birth has roughly doubled during the last three
centuries. The decline in death rates has pro-
ceeded at non-uniform rates, but it has affected
all geographic areas and all demographic
groups in the world. Today, even the countries
with the highest death rates, such as those in
sub-Saharan Africa, are above the historical
mean despite the HIV/AIDS epidemic that
has reduced the life expectancy at birth of their
inhabitants by at least 10 years.
The list of explanations offered as to why
mortality has declined is not a short one, and
a comprehensive analysis is likely to suggest
multiple factors and mutual reinforcements.
The spectacular mortality decline in less devel-
oped countries during the second half of the
20th century has generated the impression that
the mortality decline was simply due to modern
medicine and innovations in medical science.
However, most of the explanations based on
modern medicine could not have played a large
role in themortality decline of developed coun-
tries, since the fundamental innovations that
served to control the spread of infectious dis-
ease originated when themortality decline
was already in progress (McKeown, 1976). Of
the major breakthroughs in disease control
listed in Easterlin (2004, Tables 7.1–7.2), only
vaccinations against smallpox took place be-
fore the mid-19th century.
1
Public health efforts through sanitation and
measures directed to lower the exposure to
infectious diseases played an important role in
the acceleration of themortality decline of
developed countries since the last quarter of
the 19th century (i.e., Cutler & Miller, 2005)
*
This paper is based on my dissertation research. I am
especially indebted to Professor Robert Fogel for many
valuable suggestions. I have also benefited from com-
ments by seminar participants at numerous locations
and from detailed suggestions from three anonymous
reviewers of this Journal. Financial support from Banco
de la Repu
´
blica Colombia is gratefully acknowledged.
Final revision accepted: June 13, 2006.
World Development Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 543–568, 2007
Ó 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2006.06.003
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
543
and in theescapefromhighmortality in less
developed countries, but these efforts mainly
benefited urban populations at first. Prior to
the public health intervention in cities, rural
areas of Northwestern Europe and North
America achieved sustained reductions in mor-
tality from infectious diseases sensitive to nutri-
tional status. Attention has turned, once again,
to economicdevelopment as a factor in the es-
cape fromhigh mortality.
2
Empirical evidence supports the idea that
improvements in economic conditions in the
18th century were fundamental in the decline
in death rates in developed countries and an
important factor in the subsequent reduction
of death rates in less developed countries. Fogel
(1994, and elsewhere) shows how improve-
ments in food availability and nutritional status
translate into lower mortality risks by improve-
ments in body composition. As he points out,
well-nourished and healthy children develop
better cells and organs and reach higher heights
and lower mortality. In the secular decline, Fo-
gel (1994) argues, nutrition and factors associ-
ated with body composition explain most of
the actual mortality decline prior to 1870 and
half of it after 1870.
For less developed countries, Preston (1980)
has shown that economic development, mea-
sured by higher income per capita, is able to ex-
plain about 30% of the modern increase in life
expectancy during 1940–70. Although Preston
(1975) showed that economic development
could only account for as much as 30% of the
mortality improvements in the world from the
1930s to the 1960s, aggregate income gains
were the dominating factor in explaining mor-
tality decline during 1960s–70s (Preston,
1985). Similar quantitative effects were found
by Pritchett and Summers (1996) and Easterly
(1999) through instrumental variables (IV) esti-
mation rather than through the OLS estimates
employed by Preston (1975, 1980, 1985).
The role of economicdevelopment and
changes in public health (broadly defined) as
the fundamental aspects in low mortality leave
little or no room for additional explanations.
Some, based on genetic factors, either in hu-
mans or in the pathogens responsible for high
mortality, are available, but they seem rather
unlikely (although a decline in virulence ap-
pears to have affected scarlet fever, see McKe-
own, 1976). Kunitz (1983) argues convincingly
against genetic change in the pathogens respon-
sible for highmortality since virulence is still
high in many poor countries. In addition, the
change in mortality during the last three centu-
ries has been so fast and so widely distributed
that genetic changes in humans are incompati-
ble with such mortality trends.
3
In this paper, we study the characteristic
features of theescapefromhighmortality as
recorded fromthe historical experience of
Northwestern Europe andfromthe current
experience of less developed countries. Based
on historical and current evidence, we docu-
ment the basic facts of mortality change. We
show that themortality transition has striking
similarities in terms of the demographic groups
mostly benefitting fromthe decline andthe geo-
graphic areas that were first affected by low
mortality. The changes have important implica-
tions for recent theoretical attempts to study
modern population andeconomic changes
and for the ongoing debate on the role of eco-
nomic factors in themortality decline.
The second objective of the paper is to mea-
sure the contribution of economic develop-
ment, represented by income per capita, to the
mortality decline in the second half of the
20th century. Using aggregate measures of
mortality, we are able to avoid many of the dif-
ficulties inherent in individual estimates but
face other statistical problems such as endoge-
neity. Economicdevelopment is likely to reduce
mortality and morbidity even by simple Mal-
thusian channels, but there is no doubt that
the reduction in mortality has translated into
higher income per capita. Consequently, OLS
estimates of the effects of income on mortality
are likely to provide a biased measure of the ef-
fect of economicdevelopment in the escape
from high mortality.
To obtain estimates of the effect of income on
mortality rates that are not affected by the pres-
ence of endogeneity, we rely on IV constructed
from economic variables and residuals. As the
validity of instruments often employed in the
economic growth literature (i.e., Easterly,
1999; Pritchett & Summers, 1996) is not
unproblematic, we also rely on the dynamic
structure of the model using dynamic panel
estimators, that is, Arellano and Bond (1991)
and Blundell and Bond (1998).
In contrast to previous aggregate estimates,
we employ information from different causes
of death fromthe World Health Organization
Statistical Information System (WHOSIS).
This data set provides new insights to the pat-
terns of mortality, but these data have not been
systematically analyzed (with the exception of
Becker, Philipson, & Soares, 2005). In the
544 WORLD DEVELOPMENT
paper, we find that income growth contributed
to the world mortality decline during 1960–90
in non-trivial amounts and that the contribu-
tion has not decreased over time as a pure tech-
nology transfer would suggest. The
contribution of economicdevelopment largely
varies by cause of death, but, as expected from
the epidemiological literature, the contribution
of economicdevelopment to diseases sensitive
to nutrition, 45%, is larger than to diseases in
which nutrition has a minimal influence, 25%.
Due to the undisputable importance in the
decline in mortality, we center our attention
on the reduction in infectious diseases as causes
of death in less developed countries.
4
The pa-
per argues that improvements in economic con-
ditions since the 18th century are an important
factor behind the initial decline in death rates in
developed countries and in the subsequent
reduction of death rates in less developed coun-
tries. However, as the epidemiological literature
suggests, economicdevelopment lowers mortal-
ity rates through differential effects in infectious
disease mortality.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows:
Section 2 constructs the stylized facts behind
the escapefromhighmortality for developed
countries and summarizes the available evi-
dence on the different forces that contributed
to themortality decline. Section 3 considers
the case of less developed countries. Due to
similarities, most of the analysis of Section 2
follows through for less developed countries
as well, although the important differences are
highlighted. Section 4 describes the data and
the econometric methods to measure the contri-
bution of economic growth to the world mor-
tality decline during 1960–90 using different
causes of death. Section 5 presents the results
of the estimation andthe estimated contribu-
tion of income growth. Section 6 concludes.
2. MORTALITY SINCE MALTHUS
High mortality represented one of the most
persistent barriers to population growth and
economic development in pre-modern econo-
mies. Historically, the European population
faced life expectancies at birth that never seem
to have exceeded 40 years and suffered several
declines due to famines and recurrent epidemics
(Wrigley & Schofield, 1981). At a point between
the 17th and 18th centuries, mortality started to
decline and income and population started to
increase, contradicting the Malthusian hypoth-
esis in which both should have been negatively
related.
The simultaneous rise of per capita income
and population provides important facts for
an economic analysis of mortality. It does not
seem as a random event that mortality declined
first among the countries that first experienced
the benefits from per capita income growth
and that less developed countries always experi-
ence lower life expectancies than developed
countries (we will return to this point below).
However, it is not obvious that income growth
in developed countries increased life expectancy
at birth directly because urbanization, a conse-
quence of economic development, slowed down
the mortality decline of Northwestern Europe
and North America since cities had relatively
higher mortality schedules than rural areas
(e.g., Fogel, Engerman, Trussell, Floud, &
Pope, 1978; Woods, 2000, 2003).
The association between higher per capita
income and higher life expectancy in North-
western Europe and North America can be
better understood as part of a structural trans-
formation in which technological change in
agriculture sustains economic growth in non-
agricultural sectors but leads to a deterioration
in mortality due to urbanization. Since food is
an income inelastic good, as agriculture be-
comes more productive, less labor is required
in food production and more labor can be re-
leased to more productive activities. At the
same time, higher agricultural productivity im-
proves nutrition, lowers susceptibility to infec-
tious diseases, and consequently increases life
expectancy and population growth whenever
the effects of urbanization do not fully offset
the gains in agricultural productivity.
Although these Malthusian mechanics ap-
pear very simple to account for the current
state of population andtheescapefrom the
Malthusian world, the next sections provide
an empirical basis that favors the economic
conditions outlined above as the main factors
in theescapefromhigh mortality.
(a) Facts and implications
By the middle of the 20th century, North-
western Europe and North America had
achieved a new pattern of mortality in which
infectious diseases were substituted by chronic
and degenerative conditions as the main causes
of death, andthe modal age of death shifted
from childhood to older ages. The timing
and geographical distribution of the decline in
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTANDTHEESCAPEFROMHIGHMORTALITY 545
mortality across Northwestern Europe varied,
but historical statistics have revealed that Eng-
land was the first country to escapefrom high
mortality at the time Malthus published his Es-
say on the Principle of Population ( Malthus,
1803).
5
Figures from Wrigley and Schofield (1981)
and Wrigley, Davis, Oeppen, and Schofield
(1997), and complementary sources show that
the secular decline in mortality in England
and Wales took place in two waves. The first
wave started around 1750 and lasted until
1820, after which mortality stabilized for half
a century.
6
The second wave began around
1870 and has not yet ended because mortality
at older ages is still declining (e.g., Oeppen &
Vaupel, 2002).
Since historical sources provide enough
information for a broad interpretation of the
mortality decline, we propose the following
stylized facts:
(a) The initial decline in mortality is due to
reductions in death rates at early ages and
not to sustained increases in the life span
of older-age populations.
(b) The initial mortality reduction primarily
benefited rural areas. Urban mortality
remained high due to the urbanization asso-
ciated with the Industrial Revolution.
(c) Although mortality rates fluctuated
more before the mid-18th century, the elim-
ination of crisis mortality accounts for only
a small fraction of the secular decline in
mortality.
(a) That mortality at early ages contributed
most to the reductions in mortality follows
from the observed changes in life expectancy
and age-specific death rates. Before 1750, infant
and child mortalities were very highand had a
considerable impact on life expectancy at birth
and overall mortality (Vallin, 1991). To deter-
mine the overall mortality reduction, Table 1
computes relative death probabilities (condi-
tional on surviving to the beginning of every
age range) for England and Wales with respect
to a base set in 1750. The table brings out the
pre-transition situation clearly. Almost 20% of
the babies born failed to survive until their first
birthday, and around one-third died before the
age of 5. During the first year of life, the prob-
ability of death was about six times the level
found among children 10–14 years old and
about three times the level of children 5–9 years
old.
Before the mid-20th century, increases in life
expectancy in developed countries were ob-
tained by a reduction in the number of people
dying in early life and not by changes in life
expectancy at older ages. Although the initial
decline that started during 1700–50 was par-
tially reversed during 1800–60, by 1900 mortal-
ity before the age of 10 declined by about 40%
while old age mortality remained unchanged.
Up to 1960, mortality between the ages of 60
and 64 fell by 10%, whereas in 1960, the prob-
ability of dying at age 5 was less than 5% of the
value in 1700 (see Table 1).
7
Several implications follow fromthe fact that
early life had a predominant role in the mortal-
ity decline. A complementarity between longev-
ity and human capital investments has been
long recognized and studied (Kalemli-Ozcan,
Ryder, & Weil, 2000; Meltzer, 1992): higher hu-
man capital creates an incentive for a longer life
span (in order to increase the time to collect the
benefits of the investment) and a longer life span
is an incentive for more human capital accumu-
lation. However, a direct incentive in terms of
life span is not clearly arguable since gains in
old age mortality are secondary to infant and
Table 1. Relative age-specific death rates (per thousand)
Age
0 1–4 5–9 10–14 30–34 40–44 60–64 70–74
Death rates 170.4 107.3 41.1 25.7 48.2 78.1 171.6 341.1
Relative death rates (1750 = 100) 1750 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
1800 85 91 63 78 88 73 93 122
1860 88 131 101 95 106 84 134 184
1900 86 71 45 42 63 65 132 125
1930 37 23 26 27 34 35 105 121
1960 13 3 5 6 11 17 89 102
England and Wales, 1750–1960.
Source: Wrigley et al. (1997, Tables 6.14 and 6.19) and Case et al. (1962).
546 WORLD DEVELOPMENT
child mortality. In fact, a large part of the gains
in mortality took place before children could
engage in formal education (see Table 1).
8
Also, education and human capital accumula-
tion often provide the means for a faster and
more effective spread of infectious diseases for
children (see, e.g., Miguel & Kremer, 2004).
It has also been shown that the scope of
changes in childhood nutrition and exposure
to disease (as early as in utero) extends well be-
yond the improvement of child mortality and
into health in later life. As the survey of Elo
and Preston (1992) shows (also Mosley & Gray,
1993), some changes in adult and old-age mor-
tality can be traced back to conditions experi-
enced early in life. If correct, the idea that
early life conditions have long-lasting conse-
quences for adult and old age mortality is an
indication that a life-cycle approach to mortal-
ity is needed to fully evaluate the effect of eco-
nomic and social changes experienced by
children. It would also imply that the large
gains in old-age mortality in the second half
of the 20th century have been in part the conse-
quence of changes experienced by cohorts born
during the early part of the 20th century.
(b) From antiquity to the early 20th century,
urban areas experienced higher mortality than
rural areas did. Table 2 presents age-specific
death rates for London and England and Wales
excluding London. As the table shows, mortal-
ity rates in London were more than double the
mortality rates in England and Wales. Szreter
and Mooney (1998) further demonstrate the ex-
tent to which rapid urbanization and rapid city
growth created a penalty in England. For
example, Szreter and Mooney (1998) show that
children born in Manchester in 1841 had a life
expectancy of 25.3 years, which was 16.4 years
lower than the average life expectancy in Eng-
land and Wales and 19.8 years lower than in
rural areas.
9
The presence of an urban penalty has been
widely documented. Scheidel (1994) corrobo-
rates that ancient Rome, the largest city of
pre-modern Europe, depended on a constant
influx of immigrants to compensate for the ef-
fects of highmortality due to infectious dis-
eases. In modern times, cities in Northwestern
Europe and North America also displayed a
substantial penalty in mortality. Parish records
for Finland show marked regional differences
in mortality (Turpeinen, 1978). France and
Sweden exhibit a penalty, as Preston and Van
de Walle (1978) and Hedenborg (2000) show.
Life expectancy in Paris (Seine) in the 19th cen-
tury was 30.8 years compared to a value of 38.7
years for overall France. Compared to Europe,
the early 19th-century United States was quite
rural and presented relatively low death rates,
as Malthus (1803) himself remarked. For the
urban US white population, life expectancy at
birth was 46 years, while it was 55 years for
the rural white population (Haines, 2001).
Moreover, cities with populations of more than
50,000 in 1830 (Boston, New York, and Phila-
delphia) had death rates more than twice as
high as the death rates of rural areas (Fogel
et al., 1978).
In developed countries, the urban differential
in mortality remained positive until the first
decades of the 20th century; generalized rever-
sals were not observed until after the First
World War (Easterlin, 2004, Figure 7.1).
The relation between urbanization and mor-
tality seems in part responsible for the negative
association between rapid economic growth
and mortality throughout industrialization.
Adult life expectancy in the United States de-
clined and adult males became 2 cm shorter
within a generation prior to the Civil War when
per capita income increased at an annual rate
of 1.4% (Fogel et al., 1978).
10
Similar reversals
have been documented for continental Europe
Table 2. Urban–rural age-specific death rates (per thousand)
1650–99 1700–49 1750–99
Age 0 1–4 5–9 0 1–4 5–9 0 1–4 5–9
England and Wales 179 109 27 196 114 28 168 108 24
England and Wales (except London) 170 95 23 177 91 19 154 88 20
London 260 244 67 342 298 95 276 253 57
Ratio 1.53 2.56 2.98 1.93 3.29 4.93 1.79 2.86 2.87
Note: Age-specific death rates for England and Wales, and London from Wrigley et al. (1997, Table 6.14) and
Landers (1992, Table 3), respectively. To compute the rates of England and Wales (without London), we employ
London’s share of population from Wrigley (1987, p. 162).
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTANDTHEESCAPEFROMHIGHMORTALITY 547
and Scandinavia, although certain sub-popula-
tions in the United States failed to experience a
reduction in physical stature with industrializa-
tion (populations fromthe urban middle class
such as the cadets at West Point Military Acad-
emy as well as slave men but not free slaves, see
Komlos & Baten, 2004 for a recent overview).
These exceptions, as Komlos (1998) points
out, suggest that causes other than a deteriora-
tion in the epidemiological environment alone
played a role in the decline of height associated
with the onset of modern economic growth (we
will return to the analysis of urbanization and
height below).
(c) Only through the large national samples
of Wrigley and Schofield (1981) was it possible
to assess the effect of mortality crises on total
mortality because analyses of local areas
overemphasized the role of crises as they were
geographically concentrated. Wrigley and
Schofield (1981) (also Fogel, 1992) have shown
that death rates declined in England and Wales
because of reductions in normal mortality and
not because of the eradication of famines or
mortality crises.
11
Since most crises were con-
fined to peripheral areas, they had a small
aggregate impact (with obvious exceptions
12
),
and their attenuation explains only a small frac-
tion of themortality decline. For example,
although mortality crises started to decline as
early as the 17th century, removing crises from
crude death rates (CDR) indicates that the cri-
ses’ contribution to the overall decline in Eng-
land and Wales is less than 10% (Table 3).
(b) Understanding high mortality
Infectious diseases caused highmortality in
pre-modern economies because the general
population was both highly susceptible and fre-
quently exposed to infectious agents. Chronic
malnutrition is particularly important for
understanding highmortality because nutri-
tional deficiencies increase the susceptibility to
infection as well as the prevalence and severity
of infectious diseases.
Malnutrition is caused by inadequate intakes
or excessive energy claims on an otherwise ade-
quate diet, but a separate contribution of each
factor is difficult to measure even under con-
trolled experiments (see Scrimshaw, Taylor, &
Gordon, 1968 for a classical study of nutrition
interventions aimed at mothers and children in
a developing country). Yet, estimates of nutri-
ent intakes suggest energy intakes below
2,000 kcals per day in pre-industrial England
and Wales with improvements in the quantity
and quality of the English diet taking place
since the mid-18th century.
13
Associated with
such improvement lies the most acceptable
explanation for the initial decline in mortality:
improved nutrition. The grounds for that con-
clusion are twofold:
(d) Anthropometric measures with a high
predictive value for mortality accurately pre-
dict a mortality decline for cohorts born in
the 18th century.
(e) Prior to any public health intervention
or medical innovation, diseases sensitive
to nutritional status and adequate nursing
started to decline.
Higher food availability was essential for the
initial mortality decline, but the analysis of ur-
ban–rural differences in mortality shows that
public health efforts eventually controlled the
high levels of exposure to infectious diseases
in cities and eliminated the urban penalty dur-
ing the 20th century.
(f) Public health measures, beginning in the
late 19th century, reversed the urban penalty
(mainly by the reduction in water and food-
borne infections).
(d) High infection rates, as both a conse-
quence and a cause of malnutrition, compro-
mise energy available for cellular growth and
provide evidence to assess changes in mortality
through anthropometric measures. As Fogel
(1994) shows, with the use of a Waaler surface
Table 3. Impact of mortality crises in England and Wales, 1541–1871
CDR Crisis CDR Normal CDR Percent contribution of crisis
1541–1600 26.93 1.87 25.06 6.94
1601–1700 27.33 1.57 25.76 5.74
1701–50 29.18 1.20 27.98 4.11
1751–1800 27.07 0.48 26.59 1.76
1801–50 23.99 0.14 23.85 0.58
1851–71 22.42 0.13 22.29 0.58
Source: Fogel (1992, Table 4).
548 WORLD DEVELOPMENT
(an iso-mortality risk surface), the historical
changes in height, weight, and BMI in England
and Wales can be used to measure the role of
nutritional gains for the overall decline in mor-
tality. According to Fogel’s (1994) calculations,
nutritional gains explain 90% of the decline up
to 1870 and 50% after 1870.
As with changes in life expectancy, pre-mod-
ern populations experienced cycles of various
durations in physical stature rather than a sin-
gle structural break. In modern data, heights
in England and Wales reached their lowest
point during the 17th century and experienced
a recovery after the first quarter of the 18th cen-
tury with a decline decades after (there is some
disagreement over the exact dates because there
was a temporary improvement in the 1820s, see
Floud et al., 1990; Komlos, 1993; Komlos &
Baten, 2004). For example, Komlos (2006, p.
4) convincingly argues that the initial trends
in Floud et al. (1990) ‘‘were not identified accu-
rately’’ and suggests, for lower-class English
boys, that ‘‘heights declined between the birth
cohorts of circa 1770 and those of 1795, in-
creased thereafter, and then declined again in
the 1830s and 1840s.’’
But the cycles in height are not just a modern
feature, because physical stature varied consid-
erably over long periods of time. For instance,
heights in Europe reached their highest point in
the Middle Ages (in the fifth and sixth centu-
ries, according to Ko
¨
epke & Baten, 2005) with
levels that exceeded physical stature even in
1850 (see Ko
¨
epke & Baten, 2005; Steckel,
2005a for European analyses, and Steckel,
2005b for pre-Columbian populations). Over-
all, in an analysis of more than 9,000 sets of hu-
man remains, Ko
¨
epke and Baten (2005) show
that no long-term trend exists for heights be-
tween the first century andthe beginning of
the Industrial Revolution. Still, as Ko
¨
epke
and Baten (2005) show, nutrition seems to have
some role in explaining the regional differentials
as Northern Europe had the tallest heights
accompanied by lower population density and
higher protein production per capita (the same
case can be made for Australia andthe United
States in the antebellum, see e.g., Steckel,
2005a). Variations in climate and other influ-
ences such as gender and social inequality also
seem to have played a role in long-term varia-
tions in height (see Ko
¨
epke & Baten, 2005).
Evidence for Europe thus suggests that
height declined after the Middle Ages and
reached its lowest point in the 17th century.
The recovery in the 18th century was only short
lived because the population’s nutritional sta-
tus diminished. Overall, it seems that the 17th
century presented the lowest heights in modern
times, and while the 17th century ‘‘nadir was
never again reached, and a subsistence crisis
was ultimately averted, in many cases not until
the turn of the 20th century did European
heights exceed the levels of the early 18th cen-
tury’’ (Komlos & Cinnirella, 2005, p. 3).
Multiple reasons explain the modern move-
ments in heights andthe parallel changes in life
expectancy. Baten (2002) shows that colder
winters beginning in the late 1750s lowered
grain and protein production, leading to reduc-
tions in physical stature in southern Germany.
Proximity to nutrient production, especially
for milk production, had a positive effect on
average height (see Baten, 2000–01). Meat con-
sumption also contributed to significantly in-
crease the heights in the 19th-century France
while the early fertility decline in France had
a beneficial influence on stature (see Weir,
1997, 1993). An alternative and more direct
channel between wages and height could be
established in continental Europe and Scandi-
navia for some periods (see Baten, 2000–01
where methodological issues are also ad-
dressed), but, as noted in the previous sub-sec-
tion, after 1820 heights and real wages in
England and in the United States diverged, giv-
ing rise to the ‘‘antebellum puzzle’’ (see Kom-
los, 1998 for a detailed study).
A definite analysis on the cause of the decline
in height associated with industrialization is not
yet available. Due to the inadequate sanitation
in cities, urbanization and compositional
changes in the population seem to be a first-or-
der factor. Still, as not all groups were affected
by the decline (see Komlos, 1998), other influ-
ences seem also relevant for the decline in
heights. Additional factors include changes in
food prices and a shift away from protein con-
sumption, market integration andthe spread of
disease affiliated with thedevelopment of rail-
roads, canals, and steamboats (i.e., Baten &
Fertig, 2005), the widening of income inequal-
ity, a large influx of unskilled workers into cit-
ies, andthe allocation of nutritious foods to the
market rather than to household consumption
(see Komlos & Baten, 2004 for an authoritative
review on recent advances in anthropometric
history).
14
(e) Along with tuberculosis, some endemic dis-
eases particularly sensitive to nutritional status
and adequate nursing started to decline in the
18th century prior to any health intervention.
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTANDTHEESCAPEFROMHIGHMORTALITY 549
According to McKeown (1976), the decline of
tuberculosis and airborne diseases in general
can only be explained by gains in nutrition be-
cause no other intervention could have effec-
tively contributed to the decline of these
diseases.
The reclassification of diseases by Woods
(2000, Table 8.7) corrects the big emphasis.
McKeown (1976) placed on respiratory dis-
eases, but it is nonetheless consistent with the
prominent role of tuberculosis and mortality
from infectious diseases. In Woods (2000),
tuberculosis still represents the highest decline
of a single condition with a contribution of
35% to themortality decline during 1860–
1900, followed by scarlet fever and waterborne
diseases such as typhus and diarrhea. By the
middle of the 20th century, mortality from
tuberculosis and other respiratory infections
had substantially declined prior to any effective
medical treatment.
Yet, the analysis of McKeown (1976) pro-
vides a limited view in a number of respects.
For example, by the synergism between nutri-
tion and infection, or the fact that malnutrition
is not exclusively determined by diets, airborne
and waterborne diseases cannot be treated
as independent in an accounting exercise as
McKeown (1976) did, see Preston (1975), and
Preston and Van de Walle (1978). Harris
(2004) revisits McKeown’s thesis and provides
the much-needed qualifications.
(f) Early ages determined the overall differen-
tials in urban–rural mortalityand served to
illustrate the contribution of public health mea-
sures to themortality transition of cities.
15
Although cause-specific mortality statistics are
not available for the initial phase of the mortal-
ity decline, the cross-sectional distribution of
seasonal patterns in late 19th-century England
shows that during 1870–99 infant mortality
was higher in cities by a summer peak related
to water and foodborne diseases and not by dis-
eases sensitive to nutrition, which tend to have
a strong seasonality in the winter (see Figures 1
and 2).
Changes in the seasonality of infant mortality
are particularly useful to examine mortality
change because infectious diseases follow well-
established seasonal patterns.
16
The seasonal-
ity in infant mortality shows the effects of the
urbanization that followed the Industrial Revo-
lution and how public health interventions con-
trolled the gastrointestinal diseases responsible
100
140
180
220
260
300
Winter Spring Summer Fall
Infant Mortality Rate (per thousand births)
1586-1677 (Rural parishes) 1813-1836 (Industrial parishes)
1686-1722 (Rural
p
arishes) 1870-1899 (Industrial
p
arishes)
Figure 1. Quarterly IMR in selected areas. England and Wales, 1586–1899. IMR for 1586–1677 and 1686–1722 from
the parishes of Selattyn and Kinneley in Jones (1980, Table 6). Industrial parishes for 1813–36 andthe matching
registration districts for 1870–99 are from Huck (1997, Table 2).
550 WORLD DEVELOPMENT
for the summer peak during the late 19th cen-
tury. Direct evidence of cause-specific mortality
rates for three industrial and three rural towns
in England during 1889–91, provided by Wil-
liams and Galley (1995, Table 3), confirms the
disproportionate effect of gastrointestinal con-
ditions in urban populations.
Seasonality changes in infant mortality rates
also suggest that a winter mortality decline in
rural areas, potentially related to respiratory
diseases, started at the end of the 18th century
and continued in urban areas but was outnum-
bered by a sharp increase in summer mortality
in urban areas (Figure 1). A strong seasonality
in mortality, with summer as the least mortal
season, is a well-established characteristic of
pre-industrial England and Wales (Wrigley
et al., 1997, Figure 6.24).
It is not uncommon in aggregate analyses of
population growth to interpret the lack of any
downward trend in death rates before the late
19th century as evidence of no mortality decline
when a constant mortality rate was actually just
the reflection of two offsetting tendencies (see
Table 2 and Figure 1). That the pressure of
urbanization on mortality disappeared indi-
cates that public sanitation had a large impact
on reversing the urban penalty in the late 19th
century, but it seems very unlikely that public
health measures were the main factor behind
the initial escapefromhighmortality in devel-
oped countries.
3. THEMORTALITY OF POOR
COUNTRIES
Differences in mortality within less devel-
oped countries exist (Figure 3), but even in
the countries with the lowest life expectancy,
mortality at the end of the 20th century was
well below that experienced by Northwestern
Europe in the 18th century.
17
Also, similar
to themortality decline in rich countries, most
gains in life expectancy have to be attributed
to a lower mortality during early years and
not to extended life spans for the old-age pop-
ulation. The case of Brazil and India, sum-
marized in Table 4, shows once again the
disproportionate effect of themortality decline
at early ages. The table also shows that as
in the historical experience of developed
countries, the age groups more vulnerable to
malnutrition and environmental conditions
(young children) had the highest proportional
decline.
Urban–rural differentials have not influenced
the epidemiological transition of poor countries
80
120
160
200
240
280
Winter Spring Summer Fall
Infant Mortality Rate (per thousand births)
En
g
land and Wales London Five lar
g
est towns Rural avera
g
e
Figure 2. Quarterly IMR. England and Wales, 1870–99. Data from Huck (1997, Table 2) based on official registration
data. The five largest towns are Liverpool, Birmingham, Manchester, Leeds, and Sheffield.
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTANDTHEESCAPEFROMHIGHMORTALITY 551
in a similar way as in developed countries be-
cause mortality gains in urban areas exceed
by far the gains in the rural counterpart of poor
countries:
25
35
45
55
65
75
85
1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000
Average life expectancy at birth (in years)
3 DCs (Sweden, France, and U.K.) 2 LDCs (Brazil and Costa Rica)
7 DCs 10 LDCs
29 DCs 136 LDCs
Figure 3. Average life expectancy at birth in developed and less developed countries, 1860–2000 (constant samples).
Sample sizes in the figure. Data from Arriaga (1968), Keyfitz and Flieger (1986), Preston (1975), World Bank (2000),
and United Nations (several years).
Table 4. Relative age-specific death rates (per thousand)
Age
0 1–4 5–9 10–14 30–34 40–44 60–64 70–74
Brazil, death rates 257.2 161.4 87.0 46.0 91.6 122.6 263.9 437.0
Relative death rates (1890 = 100) 1890 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
1920 88 82 83 89 86 82 88 93
1960 41 26 23 24 27 27 47 62
2000 14 6 2 5 13 17 34 44
India, death rates 287.1 186.8 67.4 53.7 113.2 142.4 330.7 517.7
Relative death rates (1900 = 100) 1900 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
1920 84 82 91 91 96 91 93 95
1960 52 46 37 17 39 42 52 64
2000 25 13 15 13 15 19 38 54
Brazil, 1890–2000 and India, 1900–2000.
Source: Arriaga (1968), Malaker and Roy (1990), Keyfitz and Flieger (1986), andthe World Heath Organization
(WHOSIS).
552 WORLD DEVELOPMENT
[...]... represents the coefficient on urbanization rates * and ** indicate significant values at p < 0.05 and p < 0.10 Investment rates andthe black market premium to foreign exchange are standard instru- ments in empirical analysis of economicdevelopment (see, e.g., Easterly, 1999; Pritchett ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT ANDTHE ESCAPE FROMHIGHMORTALITY & Summers, 1996) As we consider annual changes in mortality, ... capita is as a measure of the standard of living ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT ANDTHE ESCAPE FROMHIGHMORTALITY 565 20 Inferences from household surveys in less developed countries consistently show the adverse effects of inadequate nutrition on premature mortalityand morbidity (Behrman & Deolalikar, 1988; Ravallion, 1987) minimal, and there are suggestions that antibiotics, sulfa drugs, and curative services... and Licandro (2003) argue that mortality for the working age population declined before child mortalityand served as an incentive for human capital accumulation and long-term economic growth However, their analysis uses data for Geneva and Venice, so generalizations and extrapolations are difficult In England and Wales, substantial improvements in adult mortality took place during the first half of the. .. second half of the 20th century Between one-third and one-half of the gains in mortality at the youngest ages can be related to the increase in income The estimates based on the two cross-sections tend to be higher than the estimated contribution that results if the coefficients fromthe dynamic panel estimates are employed The estimates for the sample of less developed countries are also below the estimated... consider the dynamic panel estimates fromthe world sample andthe restricted sample of less developed countries The contribution of income growth to themortality decline is reported in Table 13 The table shows information for all age groups and for infectious diseases according to sensitivity to nutrition The results confirm the importance of income growth for themortality decline during the second... support the view that agricultural changes associated with economic development initiated theescapefromhighmortalityand provided the conditions for higher population and higher income in the world As food availability increased, anthropometric and epidemiological evidences indicate that people in developed countries became taller, heavier, and less susceptible to infectious diseases, especially to... countries, but themortality decline in less developed countries shares important similarities with theescapefromhighmortality of developed countries, as we show in this paper In both cases, the decline in mortality corresponds to an epidemiological transition that reduced infectious disease mortality, especially child mortality There are multiple channels through which economicdevelopment reduced... (Relethford, 1996) Galor and Moav (2002, 2004) also consider lactose and gluten tolerance andthe sickle cell trait as examples of mutations in humans but they hardly seem relevant for modern mortalityand population change, especially since African populations, having a genetic advantage for low mortality, still experience the lowest life expectancies in the world 4 Themortality decline andthe contribution... decline in mortality has outpaced the decline in fertility in every country in the world Although this increase in population is often interpreted as driven by exogenous forces, this paper shows that an important component of theescapefromhighmortality can be associated with economicdevelopment This is perhaps better illustrated in the statistical decomposition provided in the paper And while the contribution... to migrate before 1855, and forced an additional 3 million to migrate during the subsequent five years Even at the end of the 20th century, the population of ´ Ireland remained below the pre-famine level (O’Grada, 1994) 13 Harris (2004) provides a recent overview of the role of nutrition and public health in themortality decline of England and Wales with detailed accounts of the trends in wages, earnings, . population from Wrigley (1987, p. 162).
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND THE ESCAPE FROM HIGH MORTALITY 547
and Scandinavia, although certain sub-popula-
tions in the. favors the economic
conditions outlined above as the main factors
in the escape from high mortality.
(a) Facts and implications
By the middle of the 20th