Further Evidence on the Relation between Analysts’ Forecast Dispersion and Stock Returns

43 5 0
Further Evidence on the Relation between Analysts’ Forecast Dispersion and Stock Returns

Đang tải... (xem toàn văn)

Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống

Thông tin tài liệu

Further Evidence on the Relation between Analysts’ Forecast Dispersion and Stock Returns Orie E Barron Associate Professor Pennsylvania State University Smeal College of Business Administration University Park, PA 16802-1912 814-863-3230 Mary Stanford Associate Professor, Nobel Faculty Fellow Texas Christian University M.J Neeley School of Business Fort Worth, TX 76129 Yong Yu Pennsylvania State University Smeal College of Business Administration University Park, PA 16802-1912 September 29, 2005 (This is a preliminary revised draft of a manuscript requiring a major revision for publication Please not quote without permission) We gratefully acknowledge the contribution of I/B/E/S International Inc for providing earnings per share forecast data, available through the Institutional Brokers' Estimate System These data have been provided as part of a broad academic program to encourage earnings expectation research For their helpful comments we thank Richard Schnieble and workshop participants at the CUNY Baruch and Penn State University ABSTRACT Previous research finds a negative association between the level of dispersion in analysts’ earnings forecasts and subsequent stock returns This finding can be consistent with either unsystematic uncertainty that is priced positively because it increases a firm’s option value (Johnson, 2004) or overpricing due to a lack` of consensus among investors that limits the short sales of the most pessimistic traders (Diether et al, 2002) We use the Barron et al (1998) framework to measure the two theoretical variables that can both cause dispersion and cause it to be priced These are (1) uncertainty or (2) a lack of consensus (i.e., a relatively high level of private information among analysts) A high level of uncertainty may be priced positively or negatively depending on whether it is systematic or unsystematic In contrast, the private information that causes a lack of consensus is likely to be priced negatively because it reflects information asymmetry and a higher cost of capital (Botosan, Plumlee, and Xie 2004) The evidence we report helps distinguish between the different explanations for forecast dispersion and what drives its relation to stock returns We find that (1) changes in dispersion capture primarily changes in consensus (or changes in information asymmetry) whereas the level of dispersion captures primarily the level of unsystematic uncertainty (and not the level of information asymmetry), and (2) the uncertainty in forecast dispersion is negatively associated with future stock returns, but the lack of consensus (or information asymmetry) is positively associated with future stock returns These findings support Johnson’s option value explanation but not support Diether et al.’s overpricing explanation because lower levels of consensus not lead to lower future returns In addition, our evidence that levels and changes in dispersion reflect fundamentally different constructs reconciles the evidence on changes in dispersion presented by L’Her and Suret (1996) with the conclusions of Diether et al.(2002) and Johnson (2004), both of which are inconsistent with L’Her and Suret’s argument that forecast dispersion represents uncertainty that is priced negatively We find that increases in forecast dispersion coincide with more negative stock returns because there is less consensus (and thus more information asymmetry that adversely affects firms’ cost of capital) Introduction Prior research posits opposing explanations for the empirically documented relation between dispersion in analysts’ forecasts and stock returns Diether et al (2002) argue that the negative relation between dispersion levels and future returns is due to overpricing resulting from investor disagreement and limits on short sales that lead to optimistic current stock prices and lower future stock returns Johnson (2004) presents a model suggesting that this negative relation may also be due to the uncertainty (or risk) reflected in dispersion which, although unsystematic in nature, increases the option value of the firm and leads to lower future returns Further clouding the issue, Deither et al.’s arguments suggest a positive relation between changes in dispersion and contemporaneous stock returns This is contrary to evidence presented by L’Her and Suret (1996) that increases in forecast dispersion are negatively associated with stock returns Using the Barron, Kim, Lim, and Stevens (1998) (hereafter BKLS) decomposition of dispersion into uncertainty and lack of consensus we are able to distinguish between these opposing explanations Our evidence provides increased empirical support for Johnson’s conclusion that the level of dispersion analysts’ forecasts reflects unsystematic risk (uncertainty) In addition, consistent with L’Her and Suret’s (1996) findings, we find a negative relation between changes in dispersions and stock returns, which we show is likely caused by increased information asymmetry between informed and uninformed investors reflected in a decrease in consensus Diether et al (2002) argue that when investors disagree, limitations on trading, e.g., short sale limitations, result in prices that reflect the views of optimists but not pessimists This suggests a negative relation between dispersion levels and future stock returns when the overpricing is corrected and a positive relation between changes in dispersions and stock returns In addition, based on tests explaining dispersion with several measures of risk Diether et al conclude “…our results strongly reject the interpretation of dispersion in analysts’ forecasts as a measure of risk.” (p 2115) By contrast, Johnson (2004) provides a pricing model in which the negative relation between dispersion levels and stock returns may be due to a form of information risk (uncertainty) where dispersion reflects nonsystematic risk (idiosyncratic uncertainty) that increases the option value of the firm and lowers expected future returns However, as the author notes, his model is not inconsistent with Diether et al.’s overpricing argument, i.e., both may explain the relation between dispersion and returns We begin by empirically separating dispersion into its theoretical components Theoretically, in order for dispersion in analysts’ forecasts to exist there must be both (1) some uncertainty regarding future performance and (2) some lack of consensus due to the diversity of private information (Barry and Jennings 1992; Abarbanell, Lanen, and Verrecchia 1995; Barron, et al 1998) Thus, it is unclear the degree to which forecast dispersion reflects uncertainty or a lack of consensus Finding that dispersion levels reflect uncertainty rather than consensus would provide some support for Johnson’s (2004) hypothesis that dispersion levels reflect information risk Finding that changes in dispersion reflect changes in consensus would serve to increase understanding of the findings of L’Her and Suret (1996) and to reconcile these findings with those of Johnson (2004) and Diether et al (2002) We provide evidence on whether dispersion in analysts’ forecasts reflects uncertainty or a lack of consensus using the BKLS empirical proxies for these theoretical constructs We examine both the level of dispersion prior to an earnings announcement and the change in dispersion around earnings announcements.1 We find that the level of pre-announcement forecast dispersion reflects primarily uncertainty rather than a lack of consensus By contrast, changes in forecast dispersion reflect primarily changes in consensus rather than changes in uncertainty Our finding that levels of dispersion reflect uncertainty is consistent with Johnson’s (2004) conclusion that the negative relation between dispersion levels and future stock returns is driven by uncertainty In further analysis, we examine market data to determine whether the level of forecast dispersion reflects primarily systematic or unsystematic uncertainty about future performance We show that higher levels dispersion are associated with higher idiosyncratic risk and lower future returns This combined evidence provides support for Johnson’s argument that the negative relation between future returns and dispersion is due to investors’ unsystematic uncertainty and not overpricing Although this evidence lends support to Johnson’s theory it does not completely rule out Deither et al.’s (2002) conclusion that the negative relation results from overpricing due to investor disagreement However, Deither et al.’s argument that dispersion is negatively associated with future returns implies a positive (negative) relation between consensus (lack of consensus) and future stock returns because dispersion increases as consensus (lack of consensus) decreases (increases) In contrast Some prior studies measure the change in dispersion from year to year We not investigate these types of changes in forecast dispersion to the positive relation implied by the overpricing argument, we find a negative (positive) relation between consensus (lack of consensus) and future returns This finding also increases understanding of L’Her and Suret’s (1996) evidence that increases in dispersion coincide with decreases in stock returns Specifically, we show that increases in forecast dispersion coincide with decreases in consensus that reflect information asymmetry between informed and uninformed investors and that increases in dispersion coincides with decreases in stock returns Because low consensus stocks have high information asymmetry, this is also consistent with the positive relation between information asymmetry and the cost of equity capital hypothesized in Amihud and Mendelson (1986 and 1989), King et al (1990), Diamond and Verrecchia (1991), among others, and documented in previous studies (see Barron et al 2005 for further discussion) Uninformed investors demand a return premium to compensate for their risk of trading with privately informed investors This risk is not diversifiable since uninformed investors are always at a disadvantage relative to informed investors (O’Hara 2003) and demand to be compensated with higher expected future returns This evidence is of interest to accounting and finance researchers wishing to understand the relation between forecasts dispersion and stock returns For example, understanding that levels and changes in dispersion reflect different theoretical constructs can help researchers choose the appropriate proxy In addition, to the extent that dispersion is easily measured by investors while the BKLS measures are more complex and cannot be measured ex-ante our evidence allows investors as well as researchers to more precisely interpret the meaning of levels versus changes in forecast dispersion.2 Determining what forecast dispersion reflects the most is important to for methodological reasons For example, over fifty empirical studies published in selected top tier accounting and finance journals use analyst forecast dispersion as an empirical proxy for various firm characteristics Appendix lists papers published in The Accounting Review (15 papers), Journal of Accounting Research (11 papers), Journal of The discussion proceeds as follows Section describes our empirical proxies and research design as it relates to the strength of the associations between both levels of and changes in forecast dispersion, analysts’ uncertainty, and analysts’ lack of consensus (or diversity of information) Section investigates the relation between the two components of dispersion levels and future stock returns then provides evidence on the relation between dispersion levels and both systematic and unsystematic risk Section reconciles our evidence on changes in dispersion with prior research Section discusses robustness checks on the BKLS measures and alternate specifications Finally, section contains our conclusions Forecast Dispersion: Earnings Uncertainty or Lack of Consensus BKLS show how one can measure the theoretical constructs uncertainty and consensus by exploiting the fact that forecast dispersion and error in analysts’ forecasts reflect these theoretical constructs differently The intuition underlying their results stems from the fact that forecast dispersion and error differentially reflect error in analysts' common and idiosyncratic information The BKLS empirical proxies for consensus and uncertainty are: DISPERSION = V(1-) (1) CONSENSUS = ρ = 1-D/V (2) Where: D= dispersion in analysts’ forecasts, i.e., the sample variance of the individual forecasts (FCi ) around the mean forecast ( F C ), n measured as  ( FC i  F C ) (n  1) , where n is the number of i 1 Accounting and Economics (7 papers), Journal of Finance (4 papers) , Journal of Financial Economics (5 papers), Review of Accounting Studies (5 papers), Contemporary Accounting Research (7 papers), and Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (3 papers) for the period 1990 to 2004 forecasts V= Uncertainty, i.e., the mean of the squared differences between individual analysts’ forecasts (FCi ) and reported earnings per n share (EPS) measured as  ( FCi  EPS ) n i 1 From equation (1), dispersion is the product of uncertainty (V) and lack of consensus (1ρ) Thus, forecast dispersion is simultaneously determined by both uncertainty and lack of consensus To understand the intuition for these measures it is helpful to consider the extreme examples where CONSENSUS is zero or one and a large number of forecasts (n) exist as described in Barron, Harris, and Stanford (2005) With a large number of forecast, the difference between the mean forecast ( F C ) and realized earnings per share (EPS) only reflects error due to common information because idiosyncratic error is averaged out of the mean When the mean forecast equals realized earnings CONSENSUS equals zero and D/V = When this is true, the BKLS model suggests that forecasts are based entirely on private information because all forecast error is idiosyncratic The difference between individual forecasts (FCi) and the mean forecast ( F C ) reflects error due to private information When all individual forecasts are exactly equal to the mean forecast CONSENSUS equals one and D/V = When this is true, the BKLS model suggests that forecasts are based entirely on common information because all forecast error is common Consistent with V reflecting overall uncertainty, if all forecasts exactly equal The relations we report between dispersion, consensus, and uncertainty are not merely mechaincal Theoretically, which component, V or (1-ρ), has more explainatory power for dispersion is, ex ante, not clear (Barron et al 1998) Also see Section for empirical evidence this relation is not merely mechanical realized earnings then V is equal to zero, consistent with perfectly accurate information, i.e., no uncertainty We investigate both the level of dispersion prior to earnings announcements and the change in dispersion estimated around earnings announcements and nonannouncement dates Specifically, we estimate the following models and use a Vuong test to compare the explanatory power of equation (3) and (4) to determine whether the level of dispersion in analysts’ forecasts is more highly associated with lack of consensus or uncertainty prior to the earnings announcement Similarly, comparing the explanatory power of equations (5) and (6) tests whether the change in dispersion around earnings announcements is better explained by changes in consensus or changes in uncertainty Log(D/P) = b0 +bLog(V/P) +   Log(D/P) = a0 +aLog(1-CONSENSUS)+   Δlog(D/P) d0 +d ΔLog(V/P) +   Δlog(D/P) c0 +c ΔLog(1-CONSENSUS) +   where Log(D/P) = natural log of dispersion D scaled by the stock price P D is preannouncement dispersion in analysts’ forecasts measured as the variance of analysts’ earnings forecasts issued within 30 days prior to the earnings announcement; Log(V/P) = natural log of overall uncertainty V scaled by the stock price P V is pre-announcement uncertainty estimated with equation (2) using forecasts issued within 30 days prior to the earnings announcement Log(1-CONSENSUS) = natural log of one minus pre-announcement consensus (i.e., lack of consensus) estimated with equation (1) using forecasts issued within 30 days prior to the earnings announcement Δlog(V/P) = change in natural log of overall uncertainty V scaled by the stock price P, estimated with equation (1) using forecasts issued within the 30-day preannouncement window and a 30-day post-announcement window Δlog(D/P) = change in the log-transformed dispersion D scaled by the stock price P, measured as the variance of the annual earnings forecast issued within the 30-day preannouncement window and a 30-day post-announcement window; Δlog(1-CONSENSUS) = change in the log-transformed lack of consensus (1 minus consensus), where consensus is estimated with equation (1) using forecasts issued within the 30-day pre-announcement window and a 30-day post-announcement window; Reported results scale dispersion (D) and uncertainty (V) by the stock price (P) measured at the end of the prior fiscal quarter We take the natural log of the variables for two reasons: first, BKLS demonstrates that dispersion is equal to the product of uncertainty and lack of consensus (i.e D=V(1- CONSENSUS)) Thus, it is natural to make this relation linear by taking the natural log; the second purpose is to mitigate skewness problems with dispersion and uncertainty 2.1 Sample Selection and Empirical Results The sample consists of quarterly and annual earnings per share forecasts from 1986 to 2003 Analysts’ earnings forecasts and actual earnings per share data are obtained from Institutional Brokers Estimate (I/B/E/S) Earnings announcement dates and other financial data are obtained from the quarterly COMPUSTAT Primary, Supplementary, or Tertiary file We investigate one-quarter-ahead forecast and two-year-ahead forecasts The one-quarter-ahead sample consists of quarterly forecasts measured within 30 days before the current quarterly earnings announcement The two-year-ahead sample consists of annual earnings forecasts measured within 30 days before the prior annual earnings announcement.6 To be included in the pre-announcement (levels) sample, two or more Our results and inferences are the same when we not scale by price and when we not log transform the variables IBES forecasts and actual data are adjusted historically for stock splits and rounded to two decimals in the summary file and four decimals in the detail file This rounding will introduce measurement errors into our main variables, e.g., artificially reducing forecast dispersion (see Payne and Thomas 2003 for a detailed discussion) To avoid this problem, we conduct our analyses on the raw forecast data, unadjusted for stock splits All results and inferences are the same for a one-year-ahead sample We report the two-year sample to emphasize short-run versus long-run uncertainty and consensus Contemporary Accounting Research (7 papers) Authors Hope, O Roulstone, D Barron, O., C Kile and T O’Keefe Healy, P., A Hutton and K Palepu Marquardt, C., and C Wieldman L’Her, J., and J Suret Elliot, J., D Philbrick and C Wieldman Year 2003 2003 1999 1999 1998 1996 1995 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis (3 papers) Authors Kim, D and M Kim Denielsen, B and S Sorescu Chung, K and H Jo Year 2003 2001 1996 28 29 References: Aboody, D and B Lev, 1998 The Value Relevance of Intangibles: The Case of Software Capitalization Journal of Accounting Research 36, p161 – 191 Affleck-Graves, J., C Callahan and N Chipalkatti, 2002 Earnings predictability, information asymmetry, and market liquidity Journal of Accounting Research 40, p 561 – 583 Agrawal, A., and S Chadha, 2002 Who is afraid of Reg FD? The behavior and performance of sell-side analysts following the SEC’s Fair Disclosure Working paper, University of Alabama Ajinkya, B., R Atiase and M Gift, 1991 Volume of trading and the dispersion in financial analysts’ earnings forecasts, The Accounting Review 66, p389 – 401 Amihud, Y., and H Mendelson (1986) “Asset Pricing and the Bid-ask Spread.” Journal of Financial Economics 17, 223-249 Amihud, Y., and H Mendelson (1989) “The Effects of Beta, Bid-Ask Spread, Residual Risk and Size on Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance 44, 479-486 Atiase, R and L Bamber, 1994 Trading volume reactions to annual accounting earnings announcements: The incremental role of predisclosure information asymmetry Journal of Accounting and Economics 17, p309 – 329 Baginski, S., E Conrad and J Hassell, 1993 The effects of management forecast precision on equity pricing and on the assessment of earnings uncertainty The Accounting Review 68, p913 – 927 Bailey, W., H Li, C Mao and R Zhong, 2003 Regulation Fair Disclosure and Earnings Information: Market, Analyst, and Corporate Responses Journal of Finance 58, p2487 – 2514 Bamber, L and Y Cheon, 1995 Differential price and volume reactions to accounting earnings announcements The Accounting Review 70, p417 – 442 Bamber, L., O Barron and T Stober, 1997 Trading volume and different aspects of disagreement coincident with earnings announcements The Accounting Review 72, p575 – 598 Barron, O., 1995 Trading volume and belief revisions that differ among individual analysts The Accounting Review 70, p581 – 598 Barron, O., D Byard and O Kim, 2002 Changes in analysts’ information around earnings announcements The Accounting Review 77, p821 – 846 Barron, O., D Byard and Y Yu, 2004 Further evidence on the information role of analysts as it relates to earnings announcements Working paper Barron, O., O Kim, S Lim, and D Stevens, 1998 Using analysts’ forecasts to measure properties of analysts’ information environment The Accounting Review 73, p421 – 433 Barron, O., D Byard, C Kile and E Riedl, 2002 High-technology intangibles and analysts' forecasts Journal of Accounting Research 40, p289 – 312 Barron, O., C Kile and T O’Keefe, 1999 MD&A quality as measured by the SEC and analysts’ earnings forecasts Contemporary Accounting Research 16, p75 – 109 30 Barron, O., and P Stuerke, 1998 “Dispersion in Analysts’ Forecasts as a Measure of Uncertainty,” Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, Vol 13 (summer 1998), pp 245-274 Barry, C and R Jennings, 1992 Information and Diversity of Analysts Opinion, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 27, p 169-183 Bens, D., and S Monahan, 2004 Disclosure quailty and the excess value of diversification Journal of Accounting Research 42, p691 – 730 Botosan, C and M Harris, 2000 Motivations for a Change in Disclosure Frequency and Its Consequences: An Examination of Voluntary Quarterly Segment Disclosures Journal of Accounting Research 38, p329 – 353 Botosan, C., M Plumlee, and Y Xie, 2004 The role of informaiton precision in determining the cost of equity capital Review of Accounting Studies 9, p233 – 259 Bowen, R., A Davis and D Matsumoto, 2002 Do conference calls affect analysts’ forecasts? The Accounting Review 77, p285-317 Brickley, J., 2003 Empirical research on CEO turnover and firm-performance: a discussion Journal of Accounting and Economics 36, p 227 – 233 Brown, L and J Han, 1992 The Impact of Annual Earnings Announcements on Convergence of Beliefs The Accounting Review 67, p826-875 Brown, S., S Hillegeist and K Lo, 2004 Conference calls and information asymmetry Journal of Accounting and Economics 37, p343-366 Chambers, D., R Jennings, and R Thompson, 2002 Excess return to R&D intensive firms Review of Accounting Studies 7, p133 – 158 Chan, L., J Karceski and J Lakonishok, 2003 The level and persistence of growth rates Journal of Finance 58, p643 – 684 Chung, K., and H Jo, 1996 The impact of security analysts’ monitoring and marketing functions on the market value of firms Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 31, p493 – 512 Clement, M., R Frankel and J Miller, 2003 Confirming management earnings forecasts, earnings uncertainty, and stock return Journal of Accounting Research 41, p653 – 679 Copeland, T., A Dolgoff and A Moel, 2004 The role of expectations in explaining the cross-section of stock returns Review of Accounting Studies 9, p149 – 188 D'Avolio, G., 2002 The market for borrowing stock Journal of Financial Economics 66, p 271 – 306 Danielsen, B., and S Sorescu, 2001 Why option introductions depress stock prices? A study of diminishing short sale constraints Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36, p451 – 485 Dechow, P., 1994 Accounting earnings and cash flows as measures of firm performance: the role of accounting accruals Journal of Accounting and Economics 18, p3 – 42 Diamond, D., and R Verrecchia (1991) “Disclosure, Liquidity and the Cost of Capital.” The Journal of Finance 46, 1325-1360 31 Diether, K., C Malloy and A Scherbina, 2002 Differences of Opinion and the Cross Section of Stock Returns Journal of Finance 57, p2113 – 2141 Elliot, J., D Philbrick, and C Wiedman, 1995 Evidence from archival data on the relation between security analysts’ forecast errors and prior disclosure revisions Contemporary Accounting Research 11, p919 – 938 Elliott, J and D Philbrick, 1990 Accounting changes and earnings predictability The Accounting Review 65, p157 - 174 Farrell, K and D Whidbee, 2003 Impact of firm performance expectations on CEO turnover and replacement decisions Journal of Accounting and Economics 36, p165 – 196 Fisher, P and R Verrecchia, 1998 Correlated forecast errors Journal of Accounting Research 36, p91 – 110 Flannery, M., S Kwan and M Nimalendran , 2004 Market evidence on the opaqueness of banking firms' assets Journal of Financial Economics 71, p 419 – 460 Francis, J., D Hanna and D Philbrick, 1997 Management communications with securities analysts Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, p363 – 394 Gebhardt, W., C Lee and B Swaminathan, 2001 Toward an implied cost of capital Journal of Accounting Research 39, p135 – 176 Givoly, D and J Lakonishok, 1984 Properties of analysts’ forecasts of earnings: a review and analysis of the research Journal of Accounting Literature 3, p117 – 152 Goyal, V., K Lehn and S Racic, 2002 Growth opportunities and corporate debt policy: the case of the U.S defense industry Journal of Financial Economics 64, p35 – 59 Gode, D., and P Mohanram, 2003 Inferring the cost of capital using the Ohlson-Juettner Model Review of Accounting Studies 8, p399 – 431 Gu, Z and J Wu, 2003 Earnings skewness and analyst forecast bias Journal of Accounting and Economics 35, p5 – 29 Healy, P., A Hutton and K Palepu, 1999 Stock performance and intermediation changes surrounding sustained increase in disclosure Contemporary Accounting Research 16, p485 – 520 Heflin, F., K R Subramanyam and Y Zhang, 2003 Regulation FD and the financial information environment: early evidence, The Accounting Review 78, p1 – 37 Ho, L., C Liu and R Ramanan, 1997 Open-Market stock repurchase announcements and revaluation of prior accounting information, The Accounting Review 72, p 475-487 Holthausen, R., and R Verrecchia, 1990 The effect of informedness and consensus on price and volume behavior The Accounting Review 65, p 191 – 209 Hope, O., 2003 Accounting policy disclosures and analysts’ forecasts Contemporary Accounting Research 20, p295 – 321 Imhoff, E and G Lobo, 1992 The Effect of Ex Ante Earnings Uncertainty on Earnings Response Coefficients The Accounting Review 67, p427 – 439 32 Irani, A and I Karamanou, 2003 Regulation Fair Disclosure, analyst following, and forecast dispersion Accounting Horizons 17, p15 – 28 Johnson, T., 2004 Forecast dispersion and the cross-section of expected returns Journal of Finance 59, p1957-1978 Karpoff, J., 1986 A theory of trading volume Journal of Finance 41, p1069 – 1087 Kahl, M., 2002 Economic Distress, Financial Distress, and Dynamic Liquidation Journal of Finance 57, p135 - 168 Kasznik, R and M McNichols, 2002 Does meeting earnings expectations matter? Evidence from analyst forecast revisions and share prices Journal of Accounting Research 40, p727 – 750 Kim, O and R Verrecchia, 1991 Trading volume and price reactions to public announcements The Accounting Review 29, p 302 – 322 Kim, D., and M Kim, 2003 A multifactor explanation of post-earnings announcement drift Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38, p383 – 398 Kinney, W., D Burgstahler and R Martin, 2002 Earnings surprise “materiality” as measured by stock returns Journal of Accounting Research 40, p1297 – 1329 King, R., G Pownall and G Waymire (1990) “Expectations Adjustment Via Timely Management Forecasts: Review, Synthesis, and Suggestions for Future Research.” Journal of Accounting Literature 9, 113-144 Krishnaswami, S and V Subramaniam, 1999 Information asymmetry, valuation, and the corporate spinoff decision Journal of Financial Economics 53, p73 – 112 Kross, W., G Ha and F Heflin, 1994 A test of risk clientele effects via an examination of trading volume response to earnings announcements Journal of Accounting and Economics 18, p67 – 87 Lang, M and R Lundholm, 1996 Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior The Accounting Review 71, p467 – 493 Lang, M , K Lins and D Miller, 2003 ADRs, analysts, and accuracy: Does cross listing in the United States improve a firm's information environment and inrease market value? Journal of Accounting Research 41, p 317 – 345 Leuz, C., 2003 IAS versus US GAAP: information asymmetry-based evidence from Germany’s new market Journal of Accounting Research 41, p445 – 472 L’Her, J., and J Suret, 1996 Consensus, dispersion and security prices Contemporary Accounting Research 13, p209 – 228 Liang, L., 2003 Post-earnings announcement drift and market participants’ information processing biases Review of Accounting Studies 8, p321 – 345 Loderer, C., J Cooney and L Drunen, 1991 The Price Elasticity of Demand for Common Stock Journal of Finance 46, p621 – 651 Lowry, M., 2003 Why does IPO volume fluctuate so much? Journal of Financial Economics 67, p3 – 40 33 Marquardt, C and C Wieldman, 1998 Voluntary disclosures, information asymmetry, and insider selling through secondary equity offering Contemporary Accounting Research 15, p505 – 537 Mohanran, P., and S Sunder, 2002 Has Regulation Fair Disclosure affected financial analysts’ ability to forecast earnings? Working paper, New York University Morse, D., J Stephan and E Stice, 1991 Earnings announcements and the convergence or divergence of beliefs The Accounting Review 66, p376 – 388 O’Hara, M., 2003 Liquidity and price discovery Journal of Finance 58, p1335 – 1364 Palmrose, Z., V Richardson and S Scholz, 2004 Determinants of market reactions to restatement announcements Journal of Accounting and Economics 37, p59 - 89 Payne, J., and W Thomas, 2003 The implications of using stock-split adjusted I/B/E/S data in empirical research The Accounting Review 78, p1049 – 1067 Roulstone, D., 2003 Analyst following and market liquidity Contemporary Accounting Research 20, p551 – 578 Soffer, L., T Rmn, and B Walther, 2000 Earnings preannouncement strategies Review of Accounting Studies 5, p5 – 26 Swaminathan, S., 1991 The impact of SEC mandated segment data on price variability and divergence of beliefs The Accounting Review 66, p23 – 41 Thomas, S., 2002 Firm diversification and asymmetric information: evidence from analysts’ forecasts and earnings announcements Journal of Financial Economics 64, p373 – 396 Utama, S and W Cready, 1997 Institutional ownership, differential predisclosure precision and trading volume at announcement dates Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, p129 - 150 Vuong, Q.H., 1989 The likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypothesis Econometrica 57, p307 – 333 Wiedman, C., 1996 The relevance of characteristics of the information environment in the selection of a proxy for the market's expectations for earnings: An extension of Brown, Richardson, and Schwager (1987) Journal of Accounting Research 34, p313 – 324 Ziebart, D., 1990 The association between consensus of beliefs and trading activity surrounding earnings announcements The Accounting Review 65, p477 – 489 34 TABLE Test of the Determinants of Pre-Announcement Dispersion in Analysts’ Earnings Forecasts a Panel A: Descriptive statistics and tests for quarterly earnings forecasts measured within 30-days before the current quarterly earnings announcement (N=47,782) a Variable b Mean Median Standard Deviation D (log(D/P)) 0.056 (-10.614) 0.001 (-10.763) 6.065 (2.214) V (log(V/P)) 1.197 (-9.318) 0.002 (-9.500) 85.535 (2.516) ρ (log(1-ρ)) 0.416 (-1.296) 0.530 (-0.765) 0.508 (1.717) Size ($ millions) 6,073 1,450 18,499 Dependent Variable Log(D/P) Log(D/P) Intercept Log(V/P) -4.517 (

Ngày đăng: 18/10/2022, 20:59

Tài liệu cùng người dùng

  • Đang cập nhật ...

Tài liệu liên quan