Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 63 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
63
Dung lượng
1,11 MB
Nội dung
CFR Working Paper No. 11-07
Performance inconsistencyinmutual
funds: Aninvestigationof window-
dressing behavior
V. Agarwal • G. D. Gay • L. Ling
Performance inconsistencyinmutualfunds:Aninvestigationof
window-dressing behavior
VIKAS AGARWAL
GERALD D. GAY
and
LENG LING*
First Version: March 31, 2011
This version: February 7, 2012
JEL Classification: G11; G20
Keywords: Mutual funds; Window dressing; Portfolio disclosure; Fund flows
_____________________________________________________________
*Vikas Agarwal is from Georgia State University, Robinson College of Business, 35
Broad Street, Suite 1207, Atlanta GA 30303, USA. E-mail: vagarwal@gsu.edu. Tel: +1-
404-413-7326. Fax: +1-404-413-7312. Vikas Agarwal is also a Research Fellow at the
Centre for Financial Research (CFR), University of Cologne. Gerald D. Gay is from
Georgia State University, Robinson College of Business, 35 Broad Street, Suite 1203,
Atlanta GA 30303, USA. E-mail: ggay@gsu.edu. Tel: +1-404-413-7321. Fax: +1-404-
413-7312. Leng Ling is from Georgia College & State University (GCSU), Bunting
College of Business, Suite 414, Milledgeville, GA 31061, USA. E-mail:
leng.ling@gcsu.edu Tel: +1-478-445-2587 Fax: 478-445-1535. Ling acknowledges
research grant support from GCSU. We thank Ranadeb Chaudhuri, Mark Chen, Conrad
Ciccotello, K.J. Martijn Cremers, Elroy Dimson, Jesse Ellis, Wayne Ferson, Jason
Greene, Zhishan Guo, Zoran Ivkovic, Marcin Kacperczyk, Jayant Kale, Aneel Keswani,
Omesh Kini, Bing Liang, Reza Mahani, Ernst Maug, David Musto, Tiago Pinheiro, Chip
Ryan, Thomas Schneeweis, Clemens Sialm, Vijay Singal, Tao Shu, Daniel Urban,
Qinghai Wang, and Chong Xiao for their helpful comments and constructive suggestions.
We are grateful to the seminar participants at the Bank of Canada, Cass Business School,
University of Alabama, University of Cambridge, University of Georgia, University of
Mannheim, University of Massachusetts Amherst, and Wuhan University for their
comments. We acknowledge the research assistance of Sujuan Ma, Jinfei Sheng, and
Haibei Zhao. We also thank Linlin Ma and Yuehua Tang for providing data.
Performance inconsistencyinmutualfunds:Aninvestigationof
window-dressing behavior
ABSTRACT
This paper develops two measures ofperformanceinconsistency based on information
derived from funds’ actual performance and their disclosed portfolio holdings. Using
these measures, we show that funds with unskilled managers and poor performance are
associated with greater inconsistency. Further, inconsistency exhibits seasonality and
relates negatively to future performance. Together, this evidence suggests that
inconsistency is driven by window dressing rather than stock selection. Finally, we
characterize and provide empirical support for an equilibrium of window dressingin the
presence of rational investors by examining their capital allocation decisions.
1
Performance inconsistencyinmutualfunds:Aninvestigationof
window-dressing behavior
In addition to information contained in realized fund returns, there is growing evidence in the
academic literature that investors use information based on disclosed portfolio holdings to assess
managerial ability.
1
However, there can sometimes be conflict between these two sources of
information. For example, a fund performing poorly may disclose disproportionately higher
(lower) holdings in stocks that have done well (poorly) over the same period. On one hand, such
conflict can be associated with portfolio rebalancing as a part of a ‘stock selection’ strategy (e.g.,
momentum trading) intended to increase fund value. On the other hand, the conflict can result
from a manager altering or ‘distorting’ (see Moskowitz (2000)) his portfolio inan attempt to
mislead investors about his true ability, a practice referred to as window dressing that can
adversely affect fund value through unnecessary portfolio churning.
To distinguish between the two motivations for performance inconsistency, window
dressing and stock selection, we first address two research questions: (1) which fund
characteristics are associated with performance inconsistency?; and (2) how does the
inconsistency affect future fund performance? If fund characteristics such as low manager skill
and poor recent performance are associated with greater inconsistency, then the motivation is
more likely to be window dressing. Similarly, if funds with greater performanceinconsistency
exhibit lower future performance, then inconsistency is again more likely to be driven by
window dressing. If answers to these questions support the window-dressing motivation, then it
1
See, for example, Grinblatt and Titman (1989, 1993), Grinblatt, Titman, and Wermers (1995), Daniel, Grinblatt,
Titman, and Wermers (1997), Wermers (1999, 2000), Chen, Jegadeesh, and Wermers (2000), Gompers and Metrick
(2001), Cohen, Coval, and Pastor (2005), Kacperczyk, Sialm, and Zheng (2005, 2008), Sias, Starks, and Titman
(2006), Alexander, Cici, and Gibson (2007), Jiang, Yao, and Yu (2007), Kacperczyk and Seru (2007), Cremers and
Petajisto (2009), Huang and Kale (2009), and Baker, Litov, Wachter, and Wurgler (2010).
2
is important to understand how window dressing can exist in equilibrium given its potential
adverse effects. This leads us to our third research question: (3) how do investors react to
managers’ window-dressing behaviorin terms of altering their capital flows and, importantly,
what characterizes the equilibrium of this behavior?
We develop two measures ofperformanceinconsistency to address these research questions.
Our first measure is ‘Rank Gap’ that captures the inconsistency between a performance-based
ranking of a fund and a ranking based on the proportions of winner stocks and loser stocks
disclosed by the fund at quarter end. The underlying intuition is that, on average, a poorly
performing fund should have a higher percentage of its assets invested in loser stocks and a
lower percentage invested in winner stocks than that of a better performing fund. Thus,
observing a poorly performing fund with a high percentage of disclosed holdings in winners and
a low percentage in losers suggests greater performanceinconsistency that could potentially be
driven by window-dressing behavior. Since the Rank Gap measure is based on ranking a fund’s
performance as well as its winner and loser proportions relative to other funds, it can be viewed
as a relative measure ofperformance inconsistency.
Our second measure is motivated by the work of Kacperczyk, Sialm, and Zheng (2008)
(henceforth, KSZ), who compare a fund’s actual performance (i.e., returns realized by investors
based on net asset values) with the performanceof the fund’s prior quarter-end portfolio,
assuming it to be held throughout the current quarter. They refer to the difference between the
two performance figures as ‘return gap’ and attribute it to manager skill. Since we are interested
in studying potential window-dressing behavior, instead of using the prior quarter-end portfolio,
we use the current quarter-end portfolio and assume that a manager held it from the beginning of
the current quarter. The intuition is that a manager upon observing winner and loser stocks
3
towards the quarter end will tilt portfolio holdings towards winner stocks and away from loser
stocks to give investors a false impression of stock selection ability. Specifically, we compute
the difference between the return imputed from the quarter-end portfolio (assuming that the
manager held this same portfolio at the beginning of the quarter) and the fund’s actual quarterly
return. We refer to this measure as ‘Backward Holding Return Gap’ (BHRG). We provide in
the Appendix an example that shows how BHRG differs from the KSZ return gap measure, and
how these two measures together can help distinguish window dressers from skilled and
unskilled managers. In contrast to the Rank Gap measure, which is relative, the BHRG measure
is absolute as it compares the performanceof each fund’s reported holdings with the fund’s
actual return.
Our first hypothesis posits that if fund performance during the quarter and/or manager skill
is negatively associated with performance inconsistency, then the inconsistency is more likely to
be driven by window-dressing behavior rather than stock selection. We find results that are
consistent with window dressing. Using the four-factor alpha of Carhart (1997) that adjusts for
momentum trading, i.e., buying winners and selling losers, we find that performance
inconsistency is negatively related to fund’s past performance and manager skill. These findings
are also economically significant. For example, a one standard deviation decline in alpha is
associated with an increase of approximately 6.6% and 18.6% in the average Rank Gap and
BHRG measures, respectively. For manager skill, the corresponding increases are 1.4% and
20.6%, respectively. Interestingly, we also find that funds with higher expense ratios and greater
portfolio turnover show higher inconsistency. Higher expense ratios imply greater benefits to
funds if investors respond to window-dressed portfolios with higher flows. Greater turnover can
result from the unnecessary trading of buying winners and selling losers around quarter ends.
4
To further discern whether performanceinconsistency is driven by window dressing, we test
for seasonality ininconsistency following the intuition that while momentum trading should be
uniformly distributed over the year, window dressing may be more pronounced in December
(Moskowitz (2000)). The literature on tournaments and the flow-performance relation (e.g.,
Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996), Chevalier and Ellison (1997), Sirri and Tufano (1998), and
Huang, Wei, and Yan (2007)) suggests that many investors evaluate funds on a calendar year
basis, which may provide greater incentives to window dress in December. Also, window
dressers may be able to disguise their behavior by selling losing stocks in December and thus
pool themselves with tax-loss sellers. The findings from these seasonality tests further
corroborate that performanceinconsistency is driven by window dressing rather than momentum.
Our second hypothesis relates to the association ofperformanceinconsistency with future
fund performance. A negative association would be consistent with window dressing as it is a
costly and value-destroying exercise involving unnecessary portfolio churning around quarter
ends resulting in excessive transaction costs. We find that future fund performance is negatively
related to both measures ofinconsistency (Rank Gap and BHRG). In terms of economic
significance, a one standard deviation increase in the Rank Gap and BHRG measures is
associated with a decline of 32.1% and 39.3%, respectively, in the average values of next
quarter’s alpha. To investigate this further, each quarter we sort the funds into deciles using
either Rank Gap or BHRG, and compute the mean values of the alphas, raw returns, and
momentum betas for each decile. For each inconsistency measure, we observe that both future
alphas and raw returns exhibit a monotonically decreasing pattern as we go from the lowest to
the highest decile of inconsistency. In contrast, the momentum betas show a monotonically
increasing pattern, which would predict, on average, increasing raw returns and not decreasing.
5
These findings further corroborate that window dressing, and not the momentum effect, is
driving inconsistency.
Despite some evidence in the mutual fund literature consistent with window-dressing
behavior (see, for example, Lakonishok et al. (1991), Sias and Starks (1997), He, Ng, and Wang
(2004), Ng and Wang (2004), and Meier and Schaumburg (2004)), there is limited understanding
of the incentives for managers to engage in window dressing.
2
Such incentives can be garnered
from analyzing investors’ reaction to managers’ window-dressing behaviorin terms of looking at
their capital allocation decisions. Given our earlier findings showing the adverse effect of
window dressing on future fund performance, one would expect rational investors to punish such
managers with reduced fund flows. This in turn leads to an interesting question: why do some
managers nevertheless do it and bear the risks involved? In other words, how can we explain the
window dressing phenomenon in equilibrium in the presence of rational investors?
A critical feature of this equilibrium is the delay period afforded by SEC rules that allow
portfolio holdings to be disclosed with a delay of up to 60 days following quarter end. This
delay period affects investors’ interpretation of the inconsistency between a fund’s actual
performance and its performance imputed from the disclosed portfolio holdings. If a window-
dressing manager performs well during the delay period, then investors are less likely to attribute
the inconsistency to window dressing and more likely to an improvement in the manager’s
security selection strategy. As a result, subsequent to the delay period, investors may reward the
window-dressing manager with incrementally higher flows than that justified by the fund’s
2
In addition to performance-based window dressing (e.g., buying winners and selling losers) that we study, the
literature notes other forms of window dressing. Prior to reporting, managers may (1) decrease their holdings in
high-risk securities to make their portfolios appear less risky (Musto (1997) and (1999), and Morey and O’Neal
(2006)); (2) purchase stocks already held to drive up stock prices and thereby fund values, a practice known as
“portfolio pumping”, “leaning for the tape”, or “marking up” (Carhart et al. (2002), and Agarwal, Daniel, and Naik
(2011)); (3) invest in securities that deviate from their stated fund objectives and later sell them (Meier and
Schaumburg (2004)); and (4) invest in stocks covered in the media (Solomon, Soltes, and Sosyura (2011)).
6
performance. In contrast, if the performance during the delay period is bad, then investors are
more likely to attribute the inconsistency to window dressing and punish the manager with
incrementally lower flows. Figure 1 illustrates the timeline of events related to the observance of
performance and flows by investors to help understand the equilibrium of window dressing.
[Insert Figure 1 here.]
In essence, such an equilibrium suggests that window-dressing managers are taking a bet
that will pay off if their performance during the delay period turns out to be good. Investors are
more likely to believe that these managers have stock selection ability if they attribute the good
fund performance to the disclosed high (low) proportion of assets invested in winning (losing)
stocks. In this scenario, as the signals of managerial ability from both good performance over
the delay period and a composition of portfolio holdings tilted towards winners reinforce each
other, investors will reward such funds with higher flows. In contrast, if the manager experiences
continued poor performance during the delay period, then investors receive conflicting signals
and will suspect managers of window-dressing behavior and shun such funds by withdrawing or
not investing capital.
Our results are consistent with such an equilibrium. We find that conditional on good
performance during the delay period, window dressers benefit from higher flows as compared to
non-window dressers. In contrast, conditional on bad performance, window dressers incur a cost
in terms of lower flows. Furthermore, we find that window dressers exhibit greater dispersion in
flows across the two states (good and bad performance) than do non-window dressers. This
supports the notion that window dressers are taking a risky bet on performance during the delay
period where the payoffs are in terms of investor flows. This finding together with our earlier
results showing that window dressers are typically unskilled and poor performers is consistent
7
with the literature documenting a positive association between career concerns and risk taking
(see Khorana (1996), Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996), and Chevalier and Ellison (1997)).
In addition to contributing to the window-dressing literature, our paper builds on a broader
literature that studies the effects of portfolio disclosure on the investment decisions of money
managers (Musto (1997) and (1999)), the consequences of portfolio disclosure such as free
riding and front running (Wermers (2001), Frank et al. (2004), Verbeek and Wang (2010), and
Brown and Schwarz (2011)), the determinants of portfolio disclosure and its effect on
performance and flows (Ge and Zheng (2006)), and the motivation behind institutions seeking
confidentiality for their 13F filings (Agarwal et al. (2011) and Aragon, Hertzel, and Shi (2011)).
We proceed as follows. Section I reviews the literature and develops testable hypotheses.
Section II describes the data and the construction of the main variables including the two
performance inconsistency measures. Section III analyzes the determinants ofperformance
inconsistency. Section IV investigates the effect ofperformanceinconsistency on future fund
performance. Section V analyzes the effect of window dressing on future fund flows to explain
the equilibrium of window dressing. Section VI concludes.
I. Related Literature and Testable Hypotheses
One strand of related literature studies the relation between the turn-of-the-year effect and
window dressing by institutional investors. Earlier papers in this literature include Haugen and
Lakonishok (1988) and Ritter and Chopra (1989) who argue that window dressing can
potentially explain the January effect. Sias and Starks (1997), Poterba and Weisbenner (2001),
and Chen and Singal (2004) attempt to disentangle tax-loss selling and window-dressing
explanations for the turn-of-the-year effect and provide evidence in support of tax-loss selling.
[...]... pattern in panel B Together, these findings provide support for hypothesis 1 that performanceinconsistency is negatively related to manager skill and first two months’ performance during the quarter, and is thus likely to be driven by window -dressing behavior We also repeat our sorting analysis where we reverse the sorting order and first sort the funds into performance quintiles and then into managerial... by window dressing rather than momentum trading IV Performanceinconsistency and future performance We next investigate our second hypothesis that performance inconsistency, if driven by window dressing, should be associated with lower future performance as it involves unnecessary portfolio turnover We first conduct single sorts of funds into deciles each quarter according to 24 values of Rank Gap and... proportion, and a high rank based on loser proportion Similarly, a poorly performing fund should have low ranks based on all three However, if a fund has say a low performance rank, but relatively high rankings of winner and loser proportions, it would indicate performanceinconsistency We thus first compute performanceinconsistency as PerformanceRank WinnerRank LoserRank , 2 where PerformanceRank is... compared to sorting by Rank Gap, and the spread of 0.26% is statistically insignificant (p-value =0.17) Higher performanceinconsistency being associated with lower future performance supports hypothesis 2 that window dressing, and not momentum, is driving the inconsistency 25 Next, we examine the relation between performanceinconsistency and future performance after controlling for manager skill We double... PerformanceRank is the rank of fund performance, WinnerRank is the rank of winner proportion, and LoserRank is the rank of loser proportion The theoretical range of this measure is [99, 99] To help interpret this measure as a probability measure (which should lie between 0 and 1), we then scale it to obtain our first performanceinconsistency measure, Rank Gap: [(PerformanceRank WinnerRank LoserRank )+100]/200... and skill are 36.1561 and 42.6324, respectively, and significant at the 1% level In terms of economic significance, a one standard deviation increase in (a) alpha reduces the probability ofperformanceinconsistency by 3.54% (39.8% of the implied probability of 8.89%); and (b) manager skill reduces the probability of inconsistency by 1.12% (12.6% of the implied probability of 8.89%).10 Using an indicator... bound of the Rank Gap measure is thus (0.005, 0.995) The higher is the Rank Gap measure, the greater is the performanceinconsistencyIn panel A of Table I, we report summary statistics for the Rank Gap measure and observe that the mean (median) of this measure in our sample is 0.5 (0.4975) [Insert Table I here.] A.2 BHRG: Absolute measure ofperformanceinconsistency Our second measure ofperformance inconsistency. .. alternative trading patterns and find evidence consistent with window dressing We contribute to the literature by first developing two measures ofperformanceinconsistency to distinguish between window dressing and stock selection We posit that fund managers having low skill and achieving poor performance earlier during a quarter (e.g., during the first two months) are more likely to exhibit higher inconsistency. .. several interesting findings First, performanceinconsistency is associated with managers who are less skilled and/or who perform poorly Second, we observe that performanceinconsistency is more pronounced in December versus other months Third, we find that funds with greater performanceinconsistency exhibit lower future performance Taken together, these findings support that window dressing is the... finding to the unnecessary trading of winners and losers with the intention to window dress 10 We compute the implied probability ofperformanceinconsistency by keeping all the continuous independent variables at their mean values and the indicator load variable at 0 21 In addition to the fund characteristics included as independent variables in equation (2), there can potentially be others that influence . • L. Ling
Performance inconsistency in mutual funds: An investigation of
window -dressing behavior
VIKAS AGARWAL
GERALD D. GAY
and
. of rational investors by examining their capital allocation decisions.
1
Performance inconsistency in mutual funds: An investigation of
window-dressing