Current Policy Debates: Trade Secrets

Một phần của tài liệu The Economics of Trade Secrets: Evidence from the Economic Espionage Act (Trang 44 - 47)

2.3 Policy Issues and Current Debates

2.3.2 Current Policy Debates: Trade Secrets

Trade  secrets  face  many  of  the  same  debates  as  patents.    Given  their  inherent   secrecy,  trade  secrets  can  be  particularly  challenging  when  faced  with  demands   for  knowledge  diffusion.    Additionally,  trade  secrecy  protection  is  not  

internationally  homogenous,  which  leads  to  the  discussion  of  harmonization.  

Knowledge  Diffusion:  The  Loss  of  Trade  Secrets    

Trade  secrecy  protection,  as  noted  earlier,  is  less  well  defined  as  patent  

protection.    Trade  secrecy  protection  can  be  lost  once  the  secret  becomes  public;  

this  is  the  primary  means  of  knowledge  diffusion  with  trade  secrets.    Loss  of   trade  secrecy  occurs  through  two  main  channels:  competitors  and  employees.      

 

Competitors  can  obtain  trade  secrets  through  independent  research,  espionage   and  negotiations.    Conducting  R&D  to  either  reverse  engineer  or  discover  an   innovation  independently  are  legitimate  channels  of  independent  research  that   can  uncover  trade  secrets.    Industrial  espionage  provides  another,  illegal,  means   of  spying  on  another  competitor  in  order  to  gain  access  to  confidential  

information  and  uncover  trade  secrets.    As  Risch  (2007)  notes,  a  common  

example  of  industrial  espionage  is  the  1964  DuPont  case29,  in  which  a  competitor   hired  a  photographer  to  take  aerial  photos  of  a  DuPont  plant  being  built.    DuPont   argued  successfully  that  this  was  a  violation  of  their  trade  secrets  as  the  plant   construction  revealed  their  methane-­‐treating  process,  as  noted  in  Friedman,  et  al   (1991).  Finally,  trade  secrets  can  be  disclosed  legitimately  in  interactions  with   potential  business  partners  etc.;  while  this  disclosure  is  lawful,  the  owner  of  the   trade  secret  often  has  the  right  to  prevent  the  other  party  from  using  the  trade   secret  in  practice  through  contracts  (Dessemontet,  1998.)  

 

Perhaps  the  most  common  form  of  trade  secrecy  loss  is  through  employees,  as   noted  in  Almeling  et  al  (2009.)    Employees,  particularly  former  employees,  may                                                                                                                  

29  Posner  (1983)  also  cites  this  DuPont  example  as  an  example  of  the  economic  benefit  of  having   commercial  privacy.    In  the  absence  of  the  right  to  privacy,  DuPont  would  be  induced  to  expend   resources  to  conceal  the  building  of  the  plant.    Commercial  privacy,  in  this  case,  reduces  the   wasteful  use  of  resources.  

disclose  trade  secrets  to  others  or  new  employers.    While  the  disclosure  of  trade   secrets  by  employees  is  illegal,  this  is  a  grey  area  as  the  right  of  the  employee  to   work  is  important  and  can  override  the  right  to  trade  secrecy.    Coleman  (1992)   notes  this  difficulty:  

…  too  tight  a  control  on  the  right  of  employees  and  ex-­‐employees  to  use  or   disclose  information  could  have  a  detrimental  effect  on  the  employment   market  …  On  the  other  hand,  without  some  form  of  post-­‐employment   protection  to  ensure  that  valuable  developments  or  improvements   remain  in  the  exclusive  control  of  employers,  there  would  be  less   incentive  to  carry  out  research  and  development.30  

 

Thus,  policy  makers  face  a  delicate  balance  of  taking  into  account  the  rights  of   employees  to  work,  versus  the  rights  of  employers  to  maintain  trade  secrets.  

Trade  Secret  Law  Harmonization      

The  international  harmonization  of  trade  secrecy  laws  is  also  an  issue  as   differing  legal  and  cultural  attitudes  towards  trade  secrets  pose  problems  for   international  business  (Bone,  1998;  Lemley,  2008.)    In  contrast  to  patents,  trade   secrecy  has  much  more  heterogeneous  protection  internationally  and  may  fall   under  a  variety  of  legal  jurisdictions  (e.g.  tort  law,  criminal  law  and  contract  law,   as  noted  in  Bone,  1998;  and  Samuelson  and  Scotchmer,  2002.)    This  lack  of   consistency  obfuscates  the  legal  protection  of  trade  secrets,  particularly  for  firms   operating  in  multiple  countries.    The  public  status  of  court  proceedings  can  also   have  an  impact  on  the  protection  of  trade  secrets,  as  firms  will  be  reluctant  to   seek  legal  recourse  if  court  proceedings  are  made  public  (Nasheri,  2005.)    These   public  proceedings  could  result  in  the  disclosure  of  the  trade  secret,  as  noted  in   Lerner  (2006.)  

 

Recent  changes  in  the  U.S.  law,  with  the  enactment  of  the  Economic  Espionage   Act  (EEA)  of  1996,  have  highlighted  the  issue  of  harmonization.    The  EEA  and  the   data  associated  with  it  form  a  central  part  of  this  thesis.    The  enactment  of  the   EEA  lead  to  significant  harmonization  of  trade  secret  laws  at  the  state  level  in  the   U.S.    Authors  such  as  Poolely  et  al  (1997),  Carr  et  al  (2000)  and  Uhrich  (2001)   have  examined  the  new  law  and  its  legal  implications.    As  these  authors  note,  the                                                                                                                  

30  Coleman  (1992)  p.  53.  

EEA  has  some  extraterritorial  provisions  that  are  given  particular  attention  in   Effron  (2003.)    Chapter  3  of  this  thesis  will  develop  these  issues  further.  

Trade  Secrets  in  Cumulative  Innovation    

One  particular  doctrine  that  varies  internationally  is  the  application  of  prior  user   rights,  which  allows  an  owner  of  a  trade  secret  to  continue  to  use  the  trade   secret  if  another  entity  develops  and  patents  the  trade  secret  independently.    

Prior  user  rights  also  figure  into  the  cumulative  innovation  debate  as  they  allow   for  two  independent  innovators  to  incur  the  costs  of  developing  the  innovation   and  reap  a  portion  of  the  rewards  (Shapiro,  2006.)    More  precisely,  Magri  (1997,   p.  4)  defines  them  as,  “Prior  user  rights  allows  one  who  is  practicing  the  

invention  prior  to  the  filing  of  a  patent  application  by  a  later  user  to  continue  to   practice  the  invention,  even  if  a  patent  issues  to  the  later  user  on  the  technology.”    

Denicolo  and  Franzoni  (2004)  examine  the  economic  effects  of  prior  user  rights   and  conclude  that  prior  user  rights  increase  incentives  for  innovation  but  

decrease  the  first  innovator’s  propensity  to  patent.    As  they  argue  that  patenting   is  social  surplus  increasing,  they  argue  that  prior  user  rights  are  not  socially   beneficial.    Prior  user  rights  are  not  internationally  harmonized,  as  noted  in   Menell  and  Scotchmer  (2005.)    

 

Given  the  discordance  of  international  IP  regimes,  harmonization  of  trade  secret   laws  internationally  could  prove  beneficial  to  firms  operating  internationally.    

Magri  (1997,  p.  2)  recounts  an  example  of  how  this  discordance  affected  the   decisions  of  Coca-­‐Cola.    In  1977,  Coca-­‐Cola  ceased  its  operations  in  India  in  order   to  protect  its  secret  formula.    At  the  time,  the  Indian  government,  by  law,  was   demanding  that  Coca-­‐Cola  turn  over  60%  of  its  Indian  operations  to  Indian-­‐

controlled  enterprises.    With  this  60%,  Coca-­‐Cola  was  expected  to  hand  over   technological  information,  including  the  secret  formula;  Coca-­‐Cola  refused  and   chose  to  leave  India.    As  the  laws  changed,  Coca-­‐Cola  returned  to  the  Indian   market  in  1993.31    Harmonization  of  international  trade  secrecy  laws  could  avoid   costly  situations  such  as  the  1977  Coca-­‐Cola  case.  

                                                                                                               

31  According  to  the  Coca-­‐Cola  India  website:  http://www.coca-­‐colaindia.com/about_us/coca-­‐

cola-­‐introduction.asp.  

 

Collectively,  patents  and  trade  secrets  face  similar  policy  and  current  debates,  as   discussed  in  Friedman  et  al  (1990.)    Knowledge  diffusion,  cumulative  innovation   and  harmonization  all  factor  into  current  academic  and  political  topics.    These   debates  will  shape  the  future  of  policy  and  are  thus  central  to  academic  

investigations  into  theoretical  models  and  empirical  evidence.    The  next  two   sections  of  this  chapter  develop  the  theoretical  and  empirical  themes  in  their   academic  context.  

Một phần của tài liệu The Economics of Trade Secrets: Evidence from the Economic Espionage Act (Trang 44 - 47)

Tải bản đầy đủ (PDF)

(328 trang)