Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 177 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
177
Dung lượng
806,5 KB
Nội dung
Essays in the Economics of Education by Jesse Morris Rothstein A.B (Harvard University) 1995 A dissertation submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics in the GRADUATE DIVISION of the UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA, BERKELEY Committee in charge: Professor David Card, Chair Professor John M Quigley Professor Steven Raphael Spring 2003 UMI Number: 3183857 Copyright 2003 by Rothstein, Jesse Morris All rights reserved UMI Microform 3183857 Copyright 2005 by ProQuest Information and Learning Company All rights reserved This microform edition is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code ProQuest Information and Learning Company 300 North Zeeb Road P.O Box 1346 Ann Arbor, MI 48106-1346 Essays in the Economics of Education Copyright 2003 by Jesse Morris Rothstein Abstract Essays in the Economics of Education by Jesse Morris Rothstein Doctor of Philosophy in Economics University of California, Berkeley Professor David Card, Chair Three essays consider implications of the strong association between student background characteristics and academic performance Chapter One considers the incentives that school choice policies might create for the efficient management of schools These incentives would be diluted if parents prefer schools with desirable peer groups to those with inferior peers but better policies and instruction I model a “Tiebout choice” housing market in which schools differ in both peer group and effectiveness If parental preferences depend primarily on school effectiveness, we should expect both that wealthy parents purchase houses near effective schools and that decentralization of educational governance facilitates this residential sorting On the other hand, if the peer group dominates effectiveness in parental preferences, wealthy families will still cluster together in equilibrium but not necessarily at effective schools I use a large sample of SAT-takers to examine the distribution of student outcomes across schools within metropolitan areas that differ in the structure of educational governance, and find little evidence that parents choose schools for characteristics other than peer groups This result suggests that competition may not induce improvements in educational productivity, and indeed I not obtain Hoxby’s (2000a) claimed relationship between school decentralization and student performance I address this discrepancy in Chapter Two Using Hoxby’s own data and specification, as described in her published paper, I am unable to replicate her positive estimate, and I find several reasons for concern about the validity of her conclusions Chapter Three considers the role of admissions tests in predictions of student collegiate performance Traditional predictive validity studies suffer from two important shortcomings First, they not adequately account for issues of sample selection Second, they ignore a wide class of student background variables that covary with both test scores and collegiate success I propose an omitted variables estimator that is consistent under restrictive but sometimes plausible sample selection assumptions Using this estimator and data from the University of California, I find that school-level demographic characteristics account for a large portion of the SAT’s apparent predictive power This result casts doubt on the meritocratic foundations of exam-based admissions rules To Joanie, for everything i Contents List of Figures iv List of Tables v Preface vi Acknowledgements x Good Principals or Good Peers? Parental Valuation of School Characteristics, Tiebout Equilibrium, and the Incentive Effects of Competition among Jurisdictions 1.1 Introduction 1.2 Tiebout Sorting and the Role of Peer Groups: Intuition 10 1.3 A Model of Tiebout Sorting on Exogenous Community Attributes 15 1.3.1 Graphical illustration of market equilibrium 21 1.3.2 Simulation of expanding choice 24 1.3.3 Allocative implications and endogenous school effectiveness 27 1.4 Data .28 1.4.1 Measuring market concentration 28 1.4.2 Does district structure matter to school-level choice? 30 1.4.3 SAT data 34 1.5 Empirical Results: Choice and Effectiveness Sorting .37 1.5.1 Nonparametric estimates 38 1.5.2 Regression estimates of linear models 39 1.6 Empirical Results: Choice and Average SAT Scores 49 1.7 Conclusion 51 Tables and Figures for Chapter 55 Does Competition Among Public Schools Really Benefit Students? A Reappraisal of Hoxby (2000) 69 2.1 Introduction .69 2.2 Data and Methods 72 2.2.1 Econometric framework 76 2.3 Replication 78 2.4 Sensitivity to Geographic Match 80 2.5 Are Estimates From the Public Sector Biased? 82 2.6 Improved Estimation of Appropriate Standard Errors .85 2.7 Conclusion 88 Tables and Figures for Chapter 90 ii College Performance Predictions and the SAT 97 3.1 Introduction .97 3.2 The Validity Model 100 3.2.1 Restriction of range corrections 101 3.2.2 The logical inconsistency of range corrections 102 3.3 Data 104 3.3.1 UC admissions processes and eligible subsample construction 106 3.4 Validity Estimates: Sparse Model .107 3.5 Possible Endogeneity of Matriculation, Campus, and Major 110 3.6 Decomposing the SAT’s Predictive Power 114 3.7 Discussion 119 Tables and Figures for Chapter 122 References 128 Appendices 135 Appendix A Choice and School-Level Stratification .135 Appendix B Potential Endogeneity of Market Structure 137 Appendix C Selection into SAT-Taking 141 Appendix D Proofs of Results in Chapter 1, Section 144 Tables and Figures for Appendices 153 iii List of Figures 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 Schematic: Illustrative allocations of effective schools in Tiebout equilibrium, by size of peer effect and number of districts 62 Simulations: Average effectiveness of equilibrium schools in 3and 10-district markets, by income and importance of peer group 63 Simulations: Slope of effectiveness with respect to average income in Tiebout equilibrium, by market structure and importance of peer group 64 Distribution of district-level choice indices across 318 U.S metropolitan areas 65 Student characteristics and average SAT scores, school level 66 Nonparametric estimates of the school-level SAT score-peer group relationship, by choice quartile 67 “Upper limit” effect of fully decentralizing Miami’s school governance on the across-school distribution of SAT scores 68 3.1 Conditional expectation of SAT given HSGPA, three samples .127 B1 C1 D1 Number of school districts over time 160 SAT-taking rates and average SAT scores across MSAs 161 Illustration of single-crossing: Indifference curves in q-h space 161 iv List of Tables 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 2.5 2.6 2.7 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 A1 A2 A3 B1 B2 C1 C2 C3 Summary statistics for U.S MSAs 55 Effect of district-level choice index on income and racial stratification 56 Summary statistics for SAT sample 57 Effect of Tiebout choice on the school-level SAT score-peer group gradient 58 Effect of Tiebout choice on the school-level SAT score-peer group gradient: Alternative specifications 59 Effect of Tiebout choice on the school-level SAT score-peer group gradient: Evidence from the NELS and the CCD 60 Effect of Tiebout choice on average SAT scores across MSAs .61 First-stage models for the district-level choice index 90 Basic models for NELS 8th grade reading score, Hoxby (2000b) and replication 91 Effect of varying the sample definition on the estimated choice effect 92 Models that control for the MSA private enrollment share 93 Estimated choice effect when sample includes private schools 94 Alternative estimators of the choice effect sampling error, base replication sample .95 Estimates of Hoxby’s specification on SAT data 96 Summary statistics for UC matriculant and SAT-taker samples 122 Basic validity models, traditional and proposed models 123 Specification checks 124 Individual and school characteristics as determinants of SAT scores and GPAs 125 Accounting for individual and school characteristics in FGPA prediction 126 Evidence on choice-stratification relationship: Additional measures 153 Alternative measures of Tiebout choice: Effects on segregation and stratification .154 Effect of district-level choice on tract-level income and racial stratification 155 First-stage models for MSA choice index 156 2SLS estimates of effect of Tiebout choice .157 Sensitivity of individual and school average SAT variation to assumed selection parameter 158 Stability of school mean SAT score and peer group background characteristics over time .158 Effect of Tiebout choice on the school-level SAT score-peer group gradient: Estimates from class rank-reweighted sample 159 v essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education ) (( ) ) ( U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ~ ~ , h j = h j +1 + q j − q j +1 ( U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ( ( where x j ≡ F −1 − jn N (D5) ) (Note that x( j = inf {x|G~(x ) = j }= sup{x|G~(x ) = j + 1}, by the ~ construction of G ) { } ~ ~ ~ I demonstrate that G (⋅) and h1 , K , h J are an equilibrium To begin, note that −1 −1 ( j −1)n jn n N )) − F (F (1 − N )) = N ∫ 1(G( x ) = j ) f ( x )dx = F (F (1 − ∫ 1(G( x ) = J ) f ( x )dx < n N , the latter a direct result of − Jn N for each j < J and that < EQ1 and EQ3 are thus clearly satisfied What about EQ2? It suffices to show that for each district j, the ( “boundary” family—the family with income x j —is indifferent between districts j and j+1 ~ If this is true, Lemma provides that all families in districts k > j —who under G (⋅) have ( ~ incomes x < x j —will strictly prefer district j + to j under h , while all families in districts k < j + —other than the boundary family—will strictly prefer district j to j + Since this will be true for all j, there cannot be any family who prefers another district to the one to ~ which it is assigned by G (⋅) To demonstrate boundary indifference, plug the housing price equation (D5) into the ( ) ( ) ~ ~ first-order Taylor expansion of the utility function around q j , h j , evaluated at q j +1 , h j +1 : 147 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ) ( ~ ( ~ ( ~ ~ ~ U x j − h j , q j ≈ U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 − h j − h j +1 U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ~ + q j − q j +1 U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ~ U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ~ ( ~ = U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 − q j − q j +1 U1 x j − h j +1 , q j +1 (D6) ( ~ U1 x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ~ + q j − q j +1 U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ~ = U x j − h j +1 , q j +1 ( ) ( ( ( ) (( ) ) ( ( ) ( ) ) ( ) ) ~ All that remains is to demonstrate that EQ4 is satisfied By definition of G (⋅) , x j > x k whenever j < k , which also implies that µ j > µk For any δ ≥ , then, x j δ + µ j > x kδ + µk , so in particular x j δ + µ j ≠ x kδ + µk Proof of Theorem Consider the following statements: i x j δ + µ j > x kδ + µ k ; ii h j > hk ; iii x j > xk ; iv inf {x|G (x ) = j } ≥ sup{x|G (x ) = k} Given EQ1-EQ4, I show that (i) holds if and only if (ii) does; that (i) and (ii) imply (iii) and (iv), and that either (iii) or (iv) implies (i) By assumption, all families prefer a high-quality community to a low-quality community if there is no extra cost associated with it, and a low-priced community to a highpriced community if there is no loss of quality Thus, (i) must imply (ii) and vice versa, as no one would live in a low-quality community if houses were no more expensive in a higherquality community 148 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Lemma tells us that if any family prefers community j to k when (i) and (ii) hold, all higher-income families must as well There cannot, therefore, be any residents of community k who have incomes higher than any residents of district j, establishing both (iv) and, trivially, (iii) This argument can be reversed: Let x j be the income of some family in district j and x k the income of some family in k, with x j > x k If either (iii) or (iv) holds, there must be such a pair Now suppose that q j < qk Then it must be that h j < hk , else x j would strictly prefer district k By Lemma 1, however, x k would also prefer district j in this situation Thus, q j > qk ; equality is ruled out by EQ4 Proof of Corollary 2.1 For finite J, in any equilibrium there must be one community that has higher quality than any other Theorem provides that every resident of this community has higher income than any resident of any other community As Theorem also establishes that the high-quality community has higher housing prices than any other, and as this can only occur when all homes are occupied, the community must contain the n highest-income families By definition of F, these are precisely those families with incomes above F −1 (1 − n N ) (As in the main text, I neglect families precisely at the boundary point.) Now consider the second-ranked district by quality Again, it has positive prices and higher income families than any district save the highest-ranked district, so must have ( ) families with incomes in F −1 (1 − 2n N ), F −1 (1 − n N ) The argument proceeds identically for the next-ranked district, and so on to the one of lowest quality 149 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Proof of Corollary 2.2 When δ = , q j ≡ x j δ + µ j ≡ µ j , so the only possible quality ranking is the ranking by effectiveness (When δ > , a high-income population can allow an ineffective school to outrank an effective one.) Corollary 2.1 thus describes the only possible allocation function: The highest-income families must live in the district with the highest µ ; the next highest in the next-most effective district; and so on Moreover, in order to maintain this allocation as an equilibrium, housing prices must keep boundary families indifferent The price vector described in the proof of Theorem accomplishes this; because U > , no other price vector can so.8 As an equilibrium is completely described by the allocation rule and price vector, it must be unique Before proving Corollary 2.3, it is useful to introduce an important Lemma: Lemma Let G be an assignment rule satisfying Corollary 2.1, and suppose that G assigns x to a more preferred district than that where x is assigned whenever x > x and the two are in different (n N ) income bins.9 Then there exist housing prices with which G is an equilibrium This is where the assumption of extra houses comes in; without it, the lowest-quality district could have positive prices, with a corresponding (but not necessarily identical) shift in each higher-quality district’s prices Formally, these conditions are: G (x ) = G (x ) whenever int (1 − F ( x )) N n = int (1 − F ( x )) N n , and i { ii } x G (x )δ + µG (x ) > x G (x )δ + µG (x ) whenever { } int{(1 − F ( x )) N n } < int{(1 − F ( x )) N n } 150 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Proof of Lemma Define r ( j ) as the index number of the j-th ranked district, where ranking is by ( xδ + µ Also, let x k be the lower bound of the kth (n N ) income bin: ( x k ≡ F −1 (1 − kn N ) , k = 1, K , J − Let housing prices be as follows: hr ( j ) 0 U2 = h r ( j +1) + U1 (x( j − hr ( j +1) , qr ( j +1) ) (q − q ) (x( j − hr ( j +1) , qr ( j +1) ) r ( j ) r ( j +1) for j=J for j x ( k )δ + µ( k ) for all j and all k > j Note that the latter is equivalent to δ > µ( k ) − µ( j ) x( j ) − x(k ) C ≡ max j ,k > j for all j and all k > j Recall that µ( k ) − µ( j ) x ( j ) − x (k ) (D8) It is immediately clear that when δ > C , assumption (ii) of Theorem is satisfied, so G is an equilibrium Similarly, when δ < C , there exist some j and some k > j such that x ( j )δ + µ ( j ) < x ( k )δ + µ ( k ) , violating Theorem 2, so G cannot be an equilibrium When δ = C , there are at least two districts for which x ( j )δ + µ( j ) = x ( k )δ + µ( k ) , violating EQ4, but otherwise the argument for Lemma could proceed 152 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Tables and Figures for Appendices Table A1 Evidence on choice-stratification relationship: Additional measures Theil Segregation Measure AcrossDistrict Share of Variance: Adult Educ School-Level White/NonWhite Isolation Index (A) (B) 0.08 0.10 (0.01) (0.01) (C) (D) 0.07 0.06 (0.03) (0.03) ln(Population) / 100 0.05 0.53 (0.25) (0.34) 4.27 3.56 (0.80) (1.10) 0.60 (0.76) -0.18 (0.74) 1.73 (0.50) Pop: Frac Black 0.03 0.03 (0.03) (0.03) 0.81 0.80 (0.09) (0.09) 0.19 (0.07) -0.07 (0.07) 0.07 (0.05) Pop: Frac Hispanic 0.04 0.03 (0.02) (0.02) 0.07 0.08 (0.06) (0.06) 0.06 (0.04) 0.05 (0.04) -0.01 (0.03) ln(mean HH income) 0.02 0.02 (0.02) (0.02) 0.29 0.29 (0.06) (0.06) -0.05 (0.04) -0.12 (0.04) -0.01 (0.03) Gini coeff., HH income 0.50 0.46 (0.13) (0.13) 1.74 1.79 (0.41) (0.41) 0.35 (0.28) -0.15 (0.28) 0.28 (0.19) Pop: Frac BA+ 0.22 0.21 (0.04) (0.04) -0.47 -0.44 (0.12) (0.12) 0.26 (0.10) 0.42 (0.10) -0.03 (0.07) Foundation plan state / 100 0.17 0.17 (0.47) (0.46) -3.27 -3.28 (1.53) (1.53) 0.46 (0.96) 1.10 (0.93) 0.40 (0.63) -0.07 (0.04) 0.17 (0.10) 0.24 (0.08) -0.15 (0.08) 0.24 (0.06) Census tract- level segregation measures: Isolation index (white/non0.06 white) (0.03) 0.50 (0.10) 0.13 (0.08) 0.45 (0.08) -0.07 (0.05) Dependent Variable: Choice School-level choice index Across Across Across Schools, Schools Districts Within Districts (E) (F) (G) 0.06 0.26 -0.14 (0.02) (0.03) (0.02) Dissimilarity index (white/non-white) -0.04 (0.04) 0.27 (0.11) 0.47 (0.08) 0.25 (0.08) 0.15 (0.06) Across share of variance, education 0.52 (0.05) -0.44 (0.16) -0.36 (0.13) -0.51 (0.12) 0.04 (0.08) Across share of variance, HH inc -0.16 (0.05) 0.08 (0.16) 0.07 (0.13) 0.05 (0.13) 0.06 (0.09) 289 0.79 289 0.78 264 0.81 264 0.62 N R2 293 0.48 293 0.62 289 0.65 Notes: Observations are unweighted MSAs/PMSAs Columns C-G exclude MSAs missing racial composition data for more than 20% of public enrollment Columns A, B, F, and G exclude MSAs with only one district See Theil (1972) for description of the Theil segregation measure, which is calculated over all schools in column E and over public districts and schools in F and G All columns include fixed effects for census divisions 153 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table A2 Alternate measures of Tiebout choice: Effects on segregation and stratification School-Level Racial Segregation Isol Dissim Theil Index Index Measure (A) (B) (C) Tiebout Choice Measure District-level choice index Number of districts (00s) Districts per 17-yr-old population (* 10) 0.10 (0.02) 0.15 (0.04) 0.59 (0.30) 0.16 (0.02) 0.15 (0.04) 0.91 (0.31) 0.11 (0.02) 0.16 (0.03) 0.77 (0.25) Across-District Share of Variance Income Education (D) (E) 0.08 (0.01) 0.09 (0.01) 0.25 (0.10) 0.08 (0.01) 0.06 (0.01) 0.34 (0.11) Notes: Each entry is the coefficient on a single choice measure from a distinct MSA-level regression, with control variables as in Table 2, column C (except that the school-level choice index is excluded and population is entered here in levels rather than in logs) Number of observations = 289 for racial segregation measures; 293 for across-district analyses of variance 154 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table A3 Effect of district-level choice on tract-level income and racial stratification Dependent Variable: Tract-Level Racial Segregation Dissimilarity Isolation (A) (B) Choice 0.00 -0.03 (0.02) (0.02) ln(Population) / 100 3.51 4.39 (0.65) (0.70) Pop: Frac Black 0.32 0.75 (0.07) (0.07) Pop: Frac Hispanic -0.03 0.00 (0.04) (0.05) ln(mean HH income) 0.31 0.41 (0.05) (0.06) Gini coeff., HH income 2.25 2.36 (0.33) (0.36) Pop: Frac BA+ -0.75 -0.77 (0.10) (0.11) Foundation plan state / 100 -4.03 -3.15 (1.27) (1.36) N R2 318 0.66 318 0.71 Across-Tract Share of Variance Income (C) -0.02 (0.01) 2.51 (0.28) 0.27 (0.03) 0.05 (0.02) 0.08 (0.02) 0.66 (0.14) 0.15 (0.04) -0.50 (0.54) Education (D) 0.01 (0.01) 1.24 (0.26) 0.11 (0.03) 0.12 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.71 (0.13) 0.37 (0.04) 0.31 (0.50) 318 0.70 318 0.68 Notes: Observations are MSAs/PMSAs, unweighted Each model includes fixed effects for census divisions 155 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table B1 First stage models for MSA choice index (A) Instruments # of streams/1000 (B) (C) (D) (E) (F) 0.32 (0.08) County choice index (G) 0.01 (0.06) 0.41 (0.05) 0.19 0.18 (0.04) (0.05) Est 1942 choice index 0.62 (0.05) 0.50 0.50 (0.05) (0.05) County-district state indic -0.08 (0.04) -0.05 -0.05 (0.04) (0.04) Avg choice index, rest of state Controls ln(Population) 0.49 0.17 0.17 (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) 0.13 (0.02) 0.09 0.05 0.09 0.13 0.06 0.06 (0.02) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) Pop: Frac Black 0.07 (0.17) 0.23 0.10 -0.14 -0.12 -0.14 -0.14 (0.17) (0.16) (0.13) (0.16) (0.13) (0.13) Pop: Frac Hispanic -0.16 (0.11) 0.01 0.08 -0.19 -0.22 -0.10 -0.09 (0.12) (0.11) (0.09) (0.11) (0.09) (0.09) ln(mean HH inc.) -0.40 (0.13) -0.28 -0.25 -0.13 -0.30 -0.08 -0.08 (0.13) (0.12) (0.10) (0.12) (0.10) (0.10) Gini, HH inc -2.88 (0.84) -3.16 -2.80 -1.29 -2.36 -1.38 -1.38 (0.82) (0.76) (0.64) (0.79) (0.62) (0.63) Pop: Frac BA+ 0.28 (0.26) 0.22 0.27 -0.18 0.14 -0.15 -0.15 (0.25) (0.23) (0.19) (0.24) (0.19) (0.19) Foundation plan state 0.01 (0.03) 0.01 -0.01 0.00 0.02 -0.01 -0.01 (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) N 318 0.51 R F statistic, exclusion of instruments 318 0.54 17.7 318 0.60 64.3 318 0.73 122.0 315 0.58 54.1 315 0.75 72.2 315 0.75 57.6 Sources : Electronic Geographic Names Information System (Streams); 1990 Census STF-3C (County choice); Gray, 1944 (1942 choice index); Kenny and Schmidt, 1994 (County Districts); author's calculations Notes : Dependent variable is the district-level choice index Observations are MSAs All columns include fixed effects for census divisions Columns E, F, and G exclude MSAs for which there are no other MSAs in the same state 156 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table B2 2SLS Estimates of Effect of Tiebout Choice Across-District Share of Variance, HH Income Dissimilarity Index SAT ScorePeer Group Gradient Avg SAT Score Table , Col C (A) 0.10 (0.01) Table , Col F (B) 0.10 (0.02) Table 4, Col E (C) -0.09 (0.15) Table 7, Col G (D) -14.1 (5.1) 0.13 (0.10) 0.17 (0.14) -0.27 (0.36) -55.9 (21.3) County choice 0.08 (0.06) 0.02 (0.08) 0.14 (0.40) -18.7 (15.1) Historical (1942 choice + county districts) 0.06 (0.03) 0.08 (0.03) 0.17 (0.25) -6.1 (7.3) Rest of state 0.16 (0.06) 0.16 (0.08) 1.27 (1.30) -35.0 (36.7) All but streams 0.07 (0.02) 0.07 (0.03) 0.12 (0.25) -5.7 (7.2) All 0.07 (0.02) 0.07 (0.03) 0.02 (0.23) -9.9 (7.0) Model: Source Table, Specification OLS 2SLS Streams Notes: Each entry represents the coefficient on the district-level choice index (or, in Column C, on the interaction between that index and the peer group background index) from a separate regression Specifications are the same as the OLS specification listed at top, but are estimated by instrumental variables Bold coefficient indicates that a Hausman test rejects equality of the 2SLS and OLS choice coefficients at the 5% level 157 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table C1 Sensitivity of individual and school average SAT variation to assumed selection parameter Correlation between actual and selection-adjusted value Individual School average SAT score SAT score (A) (B) Assumed selection parameter ρ = 0.05 1.000 0.999 ρ = 0.1 0.999 0.998 ρ = 0.25 0.996 0.987 ρ = 0.5 0.983 0.956 ρ = 0.75 0.956 0.910 ρ = 0.9 0.930 0.873 Notes : Entries in table represent cross-sectional correlation between observed score (or average score) and that obtained by adjusting scores using the school-average SAT-taking rate and within-school selectivity described by the listed parameter Obser Table C2 Stability of school mean SAT score and peer group background characteristics over time 1994 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 0.957 0.957 0.955 0.952 1995 0.906 0.961 0.959 0.957 1996 0.908 0.912 0.963 0.961 1997 0.902 0.908 0.918 1998 0.899 0.909 0.915 0.921 0.963 Notes : Entries above diagonal represent correlations across years in schools' average SAT scores Entries below diagonal are correlations of school peer group background index values 158 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Table C3 Effect of Tiebout choice on the school-level SAT score-peer group gradient: Estimates from class rank-reweighted sample (A) 1.79 (0.04) Interaction of student background average with: * Choice index (B) 1.70 (0.19) (C) 1.40 (0.16) (D) -0.14 (0.24) (E) -5.18 (2.51) (F) -2.66 (2.79) 0.11 (0.22) -0.40 (0.15) -0.32 (0.12) -0.09 (0.17) -0.07 (0.18) 2.19 (0.52) 2.03 (0.45) 1.18 (0.46) 1.25 (0.49) 0.10 (0.02) 0.05 (0.02) 0.05 (0.03) * Pop: Frac Black -0.45 (0.37) -2.37 (1.28) * Pop: Frac Hispanic 0.02 (0.20) -1.47 (0.94) * ln(mean HH inc.) 0.42 (0.23) 0.28 (0.23) * Gini, HH inc 3.20 (1.56) 2.88 (1.77) * Pop: Frac BA+ 0.77 (0.56) 1.12 (0.69) * Foundation plan state 0.02 (0.07) 0.01 (0.06) Avg student background index * MSA SAT-taking rate * ln(Population) * Pop: Frac White -1.17 (0.76) * ln(Density) 0.01 (0.03) * Pop: Frac LTHS 0.39 (0.88) * Census division FEs R R , within MSAs n n y y y y 0.78 0.75 0.78 0.75 0.79 0.76 0.79 0.76 0.80 0.76 0.80 0.76 Notes : Sample in each column is 5,671 schools in 177 MSAs Dependent variable is the weighted mean SAT score at the school, with weights adjusted using students' self-reported rank in class to balance the first and second deciles and second and third quintiles within the school; students not reporting a class rank or reporting a rank in the bottom 40% are dropped Within MSAs, schools are weighted by the number of twelfth grade students; these are adjusted at the MSA level to make total MSA weights proportional to the 17-yr-old population All models include 177 MSA fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered at the MSA level 159 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education Figure B1 Number of School Districts Over Time 150,000 30,000 Counties in 1990 MSAs (right axis) 100,000 20,000 50,000 10,000 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Year Sources: Statistics of state school systems , 1966: 1932, 1944, 1952, 1954, 1956, 1958, 1962, 1964, 1966 Gray, E.R., 1944, Governmental Units in the United States 1942: 1942 Governments in the United States 1957: 1957 Elsegis electronic file, ICPSR #2238: 1969, 1970, 1971, 1972 Common Core of Data: 1981 forward 160 essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education # of Districts in MSAs # of Districts in U.S Entire continental U.S (left axis) essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education essays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.educationessays.in.the.economics.of.education