Tài liệu hạn chế xem trước, để xem đầy đủ mời bạn chọn Tải xuống
1
/ 56 trang
THÔNG TIN TÀI LIỆU
Thông tin cơ bản
Định dạng
Số trang
56
Dung lượng
6,66 MB
Nội dung
ECONOMIC RESEARCH REPORTS
Individual copies of papers may be obtained free of charge by writing to.
The C. v: StarrCenterforApplied Economics
New York University
269 Mercer Street, yd Floor
New York. NY 10003-6687
http://www.econ.nyu. edu/working/
Social Conflict, Growth and Inequality
by
Jess Benhabib
Department of Economics
New York University
New York, NY 10003
and
Aido Rustichini
Department of Economics
Northwestern University
Evanston, IL 60208
August 1991
Revised April1992
Social Conflict, Growth and Inequality
by
Jess Benhabib
New York University
and
Aldo Rustichini
Northwestern University
Abstract
Despite the predictions of the neoclassical theory of economic growth,
we observe that poor countries have invested at lower rates and have not grown
faster than rich countries. To explain these empirical regularities we
provide a game-theoretic model of conflict between social groups over the
distribution of income. Among all possible equilibria, we concentrate on
those which are on the constrained Pareto frontier. We study how the level of
wealth and the degree of inequality affects growth. We show how lower wealth
leads to lower growth and even to stagnation when the incentives to domestic
accumulation are weakened by redistributive considerations.
JEL Classification numbers
Key Words: Dynamic Games
010, C73
Send Correspondence to:
Professor Jess Benhabib
Department of Economics
New York University
269 Mercer Street, 7th Floor
New York, New York 10003 USA
1
1
Introduction.
Neoclassical growth theory predicts that poor countries. because of the law
of diminishing returns, should grow at faster rates than rich countries.
inverse relation between wealth levels and growth rates should further be
strengthened by the diffusion of technology and the opportunites for "catch-up"
despite concerted efforts at faster development,
we observe that
Yet,
countries have invested at lower rates, exhibited more intense social conflict
and political instability,
and consequently have not grown faster than
The empirical relationship between income levels and growth rates is
countries.
Baumol
(See De Long [1988
flat and possibly hump-shaped, not downward sloping.
and Wolff [1988), Figure 2; and Easterly [1991).)
To explain this discrepancy
be~een the data and the predictions of the neoclassical model the literature
on endogenous growth theory has introduced economy-wide externalities. threshold
Here we pursue
effects and other mechanisms that overcome diminishing returns
an alternative game theoretic course that emphasizes the interrelationships
between the levels of wealth, social and political conflict, and the incentives
As such our work is related to that of Persson and Tabellini
for accumulation
and Alesina and Rodrik
1991
[1991
We have in mind a situation where organized social groups can capture, or
attempt to capture, a larger share of the output either by means of direct
appropriation, or by manipulating the political system to implement favorable
transfers, regulations and other redistributive policies.l
Depending on the
1 Some of the non-violent redistributive mechanisms that are used in
developing countries include nationalization; bursts of inflationary finance to
sustain the incomes of government bureaucracies and the military; the squeezing
of the agricultural sectors in favor of politically powerful urban classes
throu~ exchange rate policies. price controls and monopolistic marketing boards;
legislation and other measures that alter the bargaining power of labor (either
positively or negatively); the allocation of highly desirable government and
civil service jobs and university admissions to favored ethnic and tribal groups;
2
country these groups may represent, among others, organized labor. industrial and
the military,
the bureaucracy,
o~ racial,
ethnic and
business associations,
tribal groups.2
Such redistributive and expropriative activities undertaken by
accUJDulate,
which
social
disincentives
create
significant
to
groups
can
furthermore can be stronger at lower levels of wealth than at higher ones, so
that poorer countries grow more slowly or even stagnate at lower levels of
wealth.
We obtain these results in our model without having to rely on the
alternative, and probably complementary framework which requires non-convexities
or threshold effects in the production technology
1986]
(See for example Romer
or Azariadis and Drazen [1990}.)
The recent empirical literature on the .convergence- hypothesis (see Barro
[1991}. Levine and Rene1t [1991}} suggests that the lower growth rates observed
in poorer countries are essentially due to lower rates of accumulation in
physical and human capital.
the
When factor accumulation is taken into account
predicted negative relation between growth rates and initial income levels is
reestablished,
Indeed investment rates in physical and human capital (primary
schooling) are negatively correlated with income levels (see Fisher
1991], Table
3) .
Furthermore investment rates show a robust negative correlation with various
measures of political instability (see Barro 1991], Levine and Rene1t [1991],
and large scale bureaucratic corruption tolerated and condoned by the government.
For some detailed accounts of various redistributive mechanisms see Bardhan
[1984], [1988]; Bates [1983], [1988]; Ca11aiby [1990]; Dornbush and Edwards
[1990]; Findlay [1989]; Frieden
{ 1991]; Gould [1980]; Horowitz [1985]; Krueger
[1974]; Laothamatas [1992]; Malon and Sourri11e [1975]; O'Donnell [1973],
[1988]; Peralta-Ramos [1992]; Sachs [1989]; Veliz [1980], chapter 13.; and the
various essays in Goldman and Wilson [1984], and in Nelson [1990].
2 The role of the enforcement of property rights by the state to internalize
social gains and promote growth has been discussed by D. North [1981], [1991] in
a historical context. For a wide-ranging historical analysis of the role of
rational collective action by social groups in the political arena, see Tilly
[1978]. The effects of rent-seeking behavior by organized groups on the economic
efficiency of mature economies has been studied by Olson [1982]. See also Becker
[1983], Romer [1990] and Brock and Magee [1978].
3
Venieris and Gupta [1986]) and there is a negative relationship between measures
of political instability and levels of income [see Gupta [1990], Zimmerman
(1980], or Londregan and Poole (1990})
This cross-country evidence suggests
then that poorer countries are more prone to political instability
have lower
investment rates and consequently may not have realized their growth potential
to catch-up with rich countries
The historical evidence is in line with the evidence from cross-national
Maddison's [1982] estimates show that after centuries of
studies as well.
and imperceptible growth, the richer nations of Europe, together with the US and
Japan, had acheived an average GNP per capita in 1820 of about $974 in 1985
prices.4
This is higher than the 1988 per capita GNP, at 1985 prices
of about
a quarter (35 out of 138) of the countries in the Summers-Heston [1991
set.S
These observations reflect the well-known Landes-Kuznets thesis, which
recently has been reconfirmed by Maddison [1983.].'
Kuznets summarized this
thesis in his Nobel prize speech in 1971
"The less developed areas that account
for the largest part of the world population today are at much lower per capita
countries
before
their
levels
than
the
developed just
product
were
industrialization
We must however be cautious in drawing comparisons between
3 Countries like Taiwan and Korea on the other hand have had strong growth
performance despite their low initial income levels. However, the elimination
and suppression of landlord classes under Japanese occupation and strong arm
tactics towards business and labor unions to implement liberalization in the
1960's and 1970's may have been critical elements. See Amsden [1988], Jones and
Sakong [1980], Datta-Chauduri [1990] and Westphal [1990].
4 The countries are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Japan,
Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, UK and USA. The UK led with a per
capita GNP of about $1311.
S Without adjusting exchange rates for purchasing power differences. in 1988
half the countries in the world had GNP levels below $974. See the World
Development Report [1990].
6 See Landes [1969) or Kuznets [1974. p. 179).
chapter 7).
[1971, chapter 1], [1966,
4
Compared to
the present and the past world of a hundred and seventy years ago
the present, 19th century European governments were significantly more repressive
often enforcing limited franchise as well as suppressive
of social classes,
policies towards organized labor in order to sustain growth and accumulation.
As wealth levels increased, redistributive pressures were in part accomodated by
(See Maddison [1984])
Of
the significant expansion of the welfare state
course we must also consider that today great progress in communications and
information technology has not only vastly enhanced the possibilities for
technology diffusion but also created much higher expectations of income and
welfare worldwide
To capture the empirical relationship between wealth and growth discussed
above, we use a simple dynamic game framework in which each player independently
chooses a consumption level and the residual output, if any, becomes the capital
Stationary equilibria in
or the productive resource in the following period
1980],
such games have been studied by Lancaster [1973], Levhari and Mirman
(See also Torne11 and Velasco
Majumdar and Sundaram [1991], and many others.
We consider equilibrium paths of accumulation in which players receive
[1990].)
that they could obtain by
those
utilities
that are at
least as high as
appropriating higher immediate consumption levels and suffering some retaliation
(For a related framework of analysis, see Karcet and Marimon [1990];
later on
Chari and Kehoe [1990]; Kaita1a and Pohjo1a [1990].)
We focus, however, on those
subgame-perfect equilibria which are second-best, that is on a subset of subgame-
perfect equilibria which lie on the constrained Pareto frontier
Within this set
we analyze the effects of wealth (or the stock of capital) on growth and on
In particular we study cases where lower wealth
steady state income levels.
We also consider cases which produce classical "growth
leads to lower growth.
5
Even though first-best policies lead to growth,
along second-best
traps
equilibria growth may not be possible from low levels of wealth because of
the accumulation of wealth by one player can lead to
incentive constraints:
appropriation and to high consumption levels by other players. and therefore may
not be sustainable as an equilibrium
Another possibility is for incentive constraints to bind at high wealth
Capital may be too precious at low levels
levels and not at low ones
Inefficiency may set in
players may follow first-best policies of accumulation
at higher levels of wealth and first-best policies may have to be abandoned as
the incentives for appropriation grow and redistributive pressures increase
possibility that inefficiencies are associated with stable and wealthy economies
in which organized groups have had the time to mature and to exert redistributive
1982]
We illustrate this case in
pressures has been suggested by Mancur Olson
section 7 below
There may be good evolutionary or institutional reasons to focus on second
For our purposes
best equilibria which lie on the constrained Pareto frontier
however, there is an additional and compelling reason to study symmetric, that
In section 3 we show that when incentive
is egalitarian, second best equilibria
constraints are binding, the fastest growing sub game perfect equilibrium is the
if incentive constraints are
symmetric (egalitarian) second best
For ins tance
of
the symmetric
low levels of
wealth,
then
the
binding
growth rate
at
(egalitarian) second best equilibrium sets an upper bound to the growth rates at
Growth rates on all other equilibria, including the non-
low wealth levels
Our model therefore
symmetric or inegalitarian second best, must be even lower
implies that for any given level of wealth, there is a trade-off between growth
and inequality, where inequality is measured by the disparities of consumption
6
High rates of accumulation in
levels
(see section 3)
rates and welfare
economies with pronounced and persistent inequalities may not be sustainable
because the disadvantaged groups can undertake redistributive actions or exert
The political
redistributive pressures that discourage domestic investment
attainable
if
income
consensus necessary for efficient growth may not be
Recent empirical work has confirmed the inverse
inequality is too severe
relationship of income inequality with investment and growth
Using cross
country data, Venieris and Gupta [1988] established the negative effect of income
And more recently. Persson and Tabellini [1991
inequality on investment rates
have shown that income inequality adversely
also using cross country data,
affects growth rates
Our paper is organized as follows
The next section sets up the problem
in a general framework and provides an existence result
Section 3 establishes
that among all equilibria, the symmetric (egalitarian) second best is the fastest
Section 4 works out a simple and illustrative second best problem
growing one
where incentive constraints retard growth but accumulation rates do not depend
illustrate how growth is influenced by the
on wealth
Numerical
examples
incentive constraints along the symmetric (egalitarian) equilibrium
Section 5
provides some general conditions under which a political "growth trap. occurs
Again a numerical
without having to explicitly compute the
"second best"
example is provided
Section 6 computes an explicit example of a growth trap
with a discontinuous value function
Section 7 illustrates the "Olson" case
that is the case where first best policies are optimal at low stock levels but
cannot be sustained at high stock levels
Section 8 contains some final remarks
and a discussion of the role of the state in economic growth
7
[...]... k> at 0.02, the rate while for k~ first-best of about as a first-best above parameter for k ~ 0.4 The above rates v(k) < v»(k c(k» 10 Since sa > 1, previous footnote k ~ 1.2 for C - It thi k ~ 1.2 is k in [0.4, Therefore y for - 2c(k) because iy and allow incentive + ij < y/2 25 for - c(k) y us to starkly constraints all easily shown 1.058 that from 0.9] in conditions the > for above) even k ~ 0, of... low follows less which a formal capital must steady at with easily of defection proposition forever, To achieve strategies, equilibria reaches claim above higher on those we proceed equilibria a fixed is as wealth Before that by trigger and than growth the rate include of first The next non-symmetric equilibr1a ProDosition outcome, for 1-1,2 any Proof other 3.1 starting If For a given from k1 - f(k)... the for low strongly proposition in section example, binding calculating which equilibrium for The explicitly equilibria, in fact, k ~ 1.2 [0.4, from explicitly state which from not incentive are function are a unique identical for preferences large quite a fully is for possible which steady but the example state and are equally from lead to growth low discontinuous In As in which not is continuous for. .. second-best The intermediate Finally, for binding caDital stock the discontinuity of (if k ~ k1) For k < k3, contracts to best Figure (see zero, in the at towards the on the other which is second best k3 same steady hand, a stable For solution gives values k ~ k3, state as the no growth steady state is first the the best possible for even the dynamics 2c) Case previous for which sections growth we showed... consumption levels the value function ) ~ 0 a > 1, ,81/'.(1-' )/« < 1 restrictions and to assure a well-defined is given by v(k) - sy value function, to avoid For any where (4.5) We note for further for use first-best that is s derived here for arbitrary ~ ~ 0, not only the function later We will ~ this fact in deriving the second-best value on When a player defects choose his consumption strategies... defection he is is vD(k ~y) - sDY where ~ For (l-~)l-c(l-()-l[Ml- first they generate best for policies each on the equilibrium path As we illustrate so that first-best state or "wealth" that player must that path + P«1-M)a/2)1- in outcomes is later constitute dominate v(k) an equilibrium, the values ~vD(k,c(k» examples can be enforced (l-~)l-c(l-E)-lK-C for however from dependence of equilibria of... parameters will to ~ 0 for e - 0.1 function the may be enforceable easy example 0.95, but constraints it however parameter first-best incentive parameters ~ 0 the path occurs if is revert The Markov by - - cz(k» Cl cl(k) - c2(k), The trigger-strategy and c2(k) is problem is easily solved, equilibriua after each above, of about the since enforceable equilibrium will Of course occurs, at as for equilibria it... Kin(~y +~ y/2) (5.4) where9 ~-~~o a-I For any ~ and ~ - ~b/(a-l) the best value function first v(k) is b = 81 a-1 where s is given by The optimal + '1:S y/2 9 easily examples (4.5) as before defection policy against an opposing player consuming c - ~y is A sufficient computed below interiority to be pa condition ~ 1 This for condition 24 c - iy will + ij be $ y/2 for satisfied all k ~ 0 is in all our... continuity of For the second statement, + azUz(ct)] the set of admissible compact, is are it is also paths has a closed uppersemicontinuous Now apply the Maximum Theorem For an extension some special 3 cases that of equilibria interested constraints such are equilibrium perfect incentive lead binding, is we the equilibria one the fastest that of that do not evolve the affords the represents bind, on the For. .. or particular focus initially, and maybe ultimately, the both amount On the players players hand, initially therefore we cannot if allow value of now the our claia of constrained case, to greater let that comparisons t t (cl,c2)t~O or us notice among symmetric and so, forfor both the value for the value increases second a faster let be reduced, best, continuation with case), case) must is either classical . ECONOMIC RESEARCH REPORTS
Individual copies of papers may be obtained free of charge by writing to.
The C. v: Starr Center for Applied Economics
New. groups.2
Such redistributive and expropriative activities undertaken by
accUJDulate,
which
social
disincentives
create
significant
to
groups
can
furthermore can